The respondent -- an investor-owned public utility operating in
the petitioner States -- and other utilities and natural gas
purchasers filed suit in the District Court against a pipeline
company and five gas producers under § 4 of the Clayton Act,
which authorizes any person injured by a violation of the antitrust
laws to sue for treble damages. The utilities alleged that the
defendants had unlawfully conspired to inflate the price of gas
that they supplied to the utilities and sought treble damages for
both the amount overcharged and the decrease in sales to customers
caused by the overcharge. The petitioner States filed separate
§ 4 actions in the District Court against the same defendants
for the alleged antitrust violation, asserting,
inter alia,
parens patriae claims on behalf of all natural persons
residing in the States who had purchased gas from any utility at
inflated prices. The court consolidated all of the actions and
granted the utilities partial summary judgment with respect to the
defendants' defense that, since the utilities had passed through
all of the alleged overcharge to their customers, the utilities
lacked standing because they had suffered no antitrust injury as
required by § 4. In light of its conclusion that, under
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Machinery Corp.,
392 U. S. 481, and
Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.
S. 720, the utilities had suffered antitrust injury as
direct purchasers but their customers, as indirect purchasers, had
not, the court dismissed the States'
parens patriae
claims. The Court of Appeals affirmed the dismissals.
Held: When suppliers violate antitrust laws by
overcharging a public utility for natural gas, and the utility
passes on the overcharge to its customers, only the utility has a
cause of action under § 4, because it alone has suffered
antitrust injury. Pp.
497 U. S.
206-219.
1. Three rationales underlie the indirect purchaser rule adopted
in
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick: (1)
establishing the amount of an overcharge shifted to indirect
purchasers would normally prove insurmountable in light of the wide
range of considerations influencing a company's pricing decisions;
(2) a pass-on defense would reduce the effectiveness of § 4
actions by diminishing the recovery available to any potential
plaintiff; and (3) allowing suits by indirect purchasers would risk
multiple liability
Page 497 U. S. 200
because the alleged antitrust violators could not use a pass-on
defense in an action by the direct purchasers. Pp.
497 U. S.
206-208.
2. The aforesaid rationales compel the conclusion that no
exception to the indirect purchaser rule should be made for suits
involving regulated public utilities that pass on all of their
costs to their customers. Pp.
497 U. S.
208-218.
(a) Allowing indirect suits in such cases might necessitate
complex cost apportionment calculations, since a utility bears at
least some portion of a passed-on overcharge to the extent that it
could have sought and gained state permission to raise its rates in
the absence of the overcharge,
cf. Hanover Shoe, supra,
392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493,
and n. 9, and since various factors, such as the need to seek
regulatory approval, may delay the passing on process and thereby
require the utility, in the interim, to bear some of the
overcharge's costs in the form of lower earnings. Here, the
certified question leaves unclear whether the respondent could have
raised its prices prior to the overcharge, whether it had passed on
"most or all" of its costs at the time of its suit, and even the
means by which the pass through occurred. Proof of these
preliminary issues, which are irrelevant to the defendants'
liability, would turn upon the intricacies of state law, and, if it
were determined that respondent had borne some of the costs, would
require the adoption of an apportionment formula, the very
complexity that
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick
sought to avoid. Moreover, creating an exception in such cases
would make little sense when, in light of all its difficulty, its
practical significance is diminished by the fact that some States
require utilities to pass on at least some of the recovery obtained
in a § 4 suit to their customers. Pp.
497 U. S.
208-212.
(b) Even if the risk of multiple recoveries would be eliminated
by allowing the petitioners to recover only the amount of the
overcharge and the respondent to recover only damages for its lost
sales in a single lawsuit, the additional complexity thereby
introduced into a case that already has become quite complicated
argues strongly for retaining the indirect purchaser rule.
See
Illinois Brick, supra, 431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 731,
n. 11. Pp.
497 U. S.
212-213.
(c) Allowing indirect suits by utility customers would not
better promote the goal of vigorous enforcement of the antitrust
laws. Petitioners' argument that utilities lack incentives to sue
overcharging suppliers is unpersuasive, since utilities may bring
§ 4 actions in some instances for fear that regulators will
not allow them to shift known and avoidable overcharges on to their
customers; since there is no authority indicating that utilities,
which may have to pass on § 4 damages recovered, would also
have to pay the entire exemplary portion of these damages to
customers; and since utilities, in fact, have an established
record
Page 497 U. S. 201
of diligent and successful antitrust enforcement. On the other
hand, indirect purchaser actions might be ineffective because
consumers may lack the expertise and experience necessary to detect
improper pricing by a utility's suppliers, while state attorneys
general may hesitate to exercise the
parens patriae device
in cases involving smaller, more speculative harm to consumers,
and, in any event, may sue only on behalf of resident natural
persons, leaving nonresidents and small businesses to fend for
themselves. Pp.
497 U. S.
214-216.
(d) Although the rationales of
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick may not apply with equal force in all
instances, ample justifications exist for the Court's stated
decision not to carve out exceptions to the indirect purchaser rule
for particular types of markets.
Illinois Brick, supra, at
431 U. S.
744-745. Even assuming that any economic assumptions
underlying the rule might be disproved in a specific case, it would
be an unwarranted and counterproductive exercise to litigate a
series of exceptions. Pp.
497 U. S.
216-217.
3. The suggestion in
Hanover Shoe, supra, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 494,
and
Illinois Brick, supra, 431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 736,
that a departure from the indirect purchaser rule may be necessary
when such a purchaser buys under a preexisting cost-plus contract
does not justify an exception in this case, since the respondent
did not sell gas to its customers under such a contract. Even if an
exception could be created for situations that merely resemble
those governed by such contracts, that exception could not be
applied here, since there is no certainty that the respondent has
borne no portion of the overcharge and otherwise suffered no
injury. Pp.
497 U. S.
217-218.
4. Section 4C of the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements
Act of 1976 -- which authorizes States to bring
parens
patriae actions on behalf of resident natural persons to
secure monetary relief for property injury sustained by reason of
certain antitrust violations -- does not authorize the petitioners
to sue on behalf of consumers notwithstanding the consumers' status
as indirect purchasers. Section 4G did not establish any new
substantive liability, but simply created a new procedural device
to enforce existing rights of recovery under § 4 of the
Clayton Act,
Illinois Brick, supra, at
431 U. S. 734,
n. 14, which rights belong to the respondent in this case. Pp.
497 U. S.
218-219.
866 F.2d 1286 (CA 10 1989), affirmed.
KENNEDY, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
REHNQUIST, C.J., and STEVENS, O'CONNOR, and SCALIA, JJ., joined.
WHITE, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which BRENNAN, MARSHALL,
and BLACKMUN, JJ., joined,
post, p.
497 U. S.
219.
Page 497 U. S. 203
Justice KENNEDY delivered the opinion of the Court.
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 731,
as amended,
15 U.S.C. § 15, authorizes any person injured by a violation
of
Page 497 U. S. 204
the antitrust laws to sue for treble damages, costs, and an
attorney's fee. We must decide who may sue under § 4 when, in
violation of the antitrust laws, suppliers overcharge a public
utility for natural gas and the utility passes on the overcharge to
its customers. Consistent with
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United
Shoe Machinery Corp., 392 U. S. 481
(1968), and
Illinois Brick, Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.
S. 720 (1977), we hold that only the utility has the
cause of action, because it alone has suffered injury within the
meaning of § 4.
I
The respondent, Utilicorp United, Inc., an investor-owned public
utility operating in Kansas and Western Missouri, purchased natural
gas from a pipeline company for its own use and for resale to its
commercial and residential customers. Together with a second
utility and several other gas purchasers, the respondent sued the
pipeline company and five gas production companies in the United
States District Court for the District of Kansas. The utilities
alleged that the defendants had conspired to inflate the price of
their gas in violation of the antitrust laws. They sought treble
damages, pursuant to § 4 of the Clayton Act, for both the
amount overcharged by the pipeline company and the decrease in
sales to their customers caused by the overcharge.
The petitioners, the States of Kansas and Missouri, initiated
separate § 4 actions in the District Court against the same
defendants for the alleged antitrust violation. Acting as
parens patriae, the petitioners asserted the claims of all
natural persons residing within Kansas and Missouri who had
purchased gas from any utility at inflated prices. They also
Page 497 U. S. 205
asserted claims as representatives of state agencies,
municipalities, and other political subdivisions that had purchased
gas from the defendants. The District Court consolidated all of the
actions.
The defendants, in their answer, asserted that the utilities
lacked standing under § 4. They alleged that, pursuant to
state and municipal regulations and tariffs filed with state
regulatory agencies, the utilities had passed through the entire
wholesale cost of the natural gas to their customers. As a result,
the defendants contended, the utility customers had paid 100
percent of the alleged overcharge, and the utilities had suffered
no antitrust injury as required by § 4.
The utilities moved for partial summary judgment with respect to
this defense, and the District Court granted their motion. The
court ruled that our decisions in
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick controlled its interpretation of § 4.
It read these cases to hold that a direct purchaser from an
antitrust violator suffers injury to the full extent of an illegal
overcharge, even if it passes on some or all of the overcharge to
its customers. The District Court concluded that utilities, as
direct purchasers, had suffered antitrust injury, but that their
customers, as indirect purchasers, had not.
In light of its ruling, the District Court chose to treat the
partial summary judgment motion as a motion to dismiss the
petitioners'
parens patriae claims. It then granted this
motion, but allowed the petitioners to take an interlocutory appeal
under 28 U.S.C. § 1292(b). It certified the following question
to the Court of Appeals:
"In a private antitrust action under 15 U.S.C. § 15
involving claims of price fixing against the producers of natural
gas, is a State a proper plaintiff as
parens patriae for
its citizens who paid inflated prices for natural gas, when the
lawsuit already includes as plaintiffs those public utilities who
paid the inflated prices upon direct purchase from the producers
and who subsequently passed on most or all of the price increase to
the citizens
Page 497 U. S. 206
of the State?"
In re Wyoming Tight Sands Antitrust
Cases, 695 F.
Supp. 1109,
1120
(Kan.1988). The Court of Appeals answered the question in the
negative. It agreed with District Court that
Hanover Shoe
and
Illinois Brick required dismissal of the
parens
patriae claims.
See In re Wyoming Tight Sands Antitrust
Cases, 866 F.2d 1286, 1294 (CA10 1989). We granted certiorari
to resolve a conflict between this decision and
Illinois ex
rel. Hartigan v. Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line Co., 852 F.2d 891
(CA7 1988) (en banc). 493 U.S. 1041 (1989). We now affirm.
II
Section 4 of the Clayton Act provides in full:
"[A]ny person who shall be injured in his business or property
by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue
therefor in any district court of the United States in the district
in which the defendant resides or is found or has an agent, without
respect to the amount in controversy, and shall recover threefold
the damages by him sustained, and the cost of suit, including a
reasonable attorney's fee."
15 U.S.C. § 16(a). As noted by the District Court and the
Court of Appeals, we have applied this section in two cases
involving allegations that a direct purchaser had passed on an
overcharge to its customers.
In
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Machinery Corp.,
supra, Hanover alleged that United had monopolized the shoe
manufacturing machinery industry in violation of § 2 of the
Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209,
as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 2.
It sought treble damages under § 4 of the Clayton Act for
overcharges paid in leasing certain machinery from United. United
defended, in part, on the ground that Hanover had passed on the
overcharge to its customers and, as a result, had suffered no
injury. We rejected the defense for two reasons. First, noting that
a wide range of considerations may influence a company's pricing
decisions, we concluded that
Page 497 U. S. 207
establishing the amount of an overcharge shifted to indirect
purchasers "would normally prove insurmountable." 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493.
Second, we reasoned that a pass-on defense would reduce the
effectiveness of § 4 actions by diminishing the recovery
available to any potential plaintiff.
See id. at
392 U. S.
494.
In
Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.
S. 720 (1977), we applied these considerations to reach
a similar result. The State of Illinois sued Illinois Brick and
other concrete block manufacturers for conspiring to raise the cost
of concrete blocks in violation of § 1 of the Sherman Act, 26
Stat. 209,
as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 1. We ruled that
the State had suffered no injury within the meaning of § 4
because Illinois Brick had not sold any concrete blocks to it. The
company, instead, had sold the blocks to masonry subcontractors,
who in turn had sold them to the State's general contractors. We
decided that, because Illinois Brick could not use a pass-on
defense in an action by direct purchasers, it would risk multiple
liability to allow suits by indirect purchasers.
See 431
U.S. at
431 U. S.
730-731. We declined to overrule
Hanover Shoe
or to create exceptions for any particular industries.
See
id. at
431 U. S.
735-736,
431 U. S.
744-745.
Like the State of Illinois in
Illinois Brick, the
consumers in this case have the status of indirect purchasers. In
the distribution chain, they are not the immediate buyers from the
alleged antitrust violators. They bought their gas from the
utilities, not from the suppliers said to have conspired to fix the
price of the gas. Unless we create an exception to the direct
purchaser rule established in
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick, any antitrust claim against the defendants
is not for them, but for the utilities to assert.
The petitioners ask us to allow them to press the consumers'
claims for three reasons. First, they assert that none of the
rationales underlying
Hanover Shoe or
Illinois
Brick exist in cases involving regulated public utilities.
Second, they argue that we should apply an exception, suggested
in
Page 497 U. S. 208
Illinois Brick for actions based upon cost-plus
contracts. Third, they maintain that § 4C of the
Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, 90 Stat.
1394-1396,
as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 15c, authorizes
them to assert claims on behalf of utility customers even if the
customers could not assert any claims themselves. Affirming the
Court of Appeals, we reject each of these contentions in turn.
III
The petitioners assert that we should allow indirect purchaser
suits in cases involving regulated public utilities that pass on
100 percent of their costs to their customers. They maintain that
our concerns in
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick
about the difficulties of apportionment, the risk of multiple
recovery, and the diminution of incentives for private antitrust
enforcement would not exist in such cases. We disagree. Although
the rationales of
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick
may not apply with equal force in all instances, we find it
inconsistent with precedent and imprudent in any event to create an
exception for regulated public utilities.
A
The direct purchaser rule serves, in part, to eliminate the
complications of apportioning overcharges between direct and
indirect purchasers.
See Hanover Shoe, supra, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493;
Illinois Brick, supra, 431 U.S. at
431 U. S.
740-742;
Blue Shield of Virginia v. McCready,
457 U. S. 465,
457 U. S. 475,
n. 11 (1982). The petitioners find the rule unnecessary, in this
respect, when a utility passes on its costs to its customers
pursuant to state regulations or tariffs filed with a utility
commission. In such cases, they assert, the customers pay the
entire overcharge, obviating litigation over its apportionment.
They maintain that they can prove the exact injury to the
residential customers whom they represent, because the respondent
made periodic public filings showing the volume and price of gas
that it sold to these consumers. They ask us to allow them to sue
for
Page 497 U. S. 209
the entire amount of the overcharge and to limit the
respondent's recovery to damages for its lost business.
The petitioners have oversimplified the apportionment problem in
two respects. First, an overcharge may injure a utility, apart from
the question of lost business, even if the utility raises its rates
to offset its increased costs. As we explained in
Hanover
Shoe:
"The mere fact that a price rise followed an unlawful cost
increase does not show that the sufferer of the cost increase was
undamaged. His customers may have been ripe for his price rise
earlier; if a cost rise is merely the occasion for a price increase
a businessman could have imposed absent the rise in his costs, the
fact that he was earlier not enjoying the benefits of the higher
price should not permit the supplier who charges an unlawful price
to take those benefits from him without being liable for damages.
This statement merely recognizes the usual principle that the
possessor of a right can recover for its unlawful deprivation
whether or not he was previously exercising it."
392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493,
n. 9. In other words, to show that a direct purchaser has borne no
portion of an overcharge, the indirect purchaser would have to
prove, among other things, that the direct purchaser could not have
raised its rates prior to the overcharge.
In
Hanover Shoe, however, we decided not to allow proof
of what the direct purchaser might have done because of the "nearly
insuperable difficulty" of the issue.
Id. at
392 U. S. 493.
The petitioners assume that the presence of state regulation would
make the proof less difficult here. We disagree. The state
regulation does not simplify the problem, but instead imports an
additional level of complexity. To decide whether a utility has
borne an overcharge, a court would have to consider not only the
extent to which market conditions would have allowed the utility to
raise its rates prior to the overcharge, as in the case of an
unregulated business, but also what the state regulators would have
allowed. In particular,
Page 497 U. S. 210
to decide that an overcharge did not injure a utility, a court
would have to determine that the State's regulatory schemes would
have barred any rate increase except for the amount reflected by
cost increases. Proof of this complex preliminary issue, one
irrelevant to the liability of the defendant, would proceed on a
case-by-case basis, and would turn upon the intricacies of state
law.
From the certified question in this case, we do not know whether
the respondent could have raised its prices prior to the
overcharge. Its customers may have been willing to pay a greater
price, and the Kansas and Missouri regulators may have allowed a
rate increase based on factors other than strict costs.
See
Midwest Gas Users Assn. v. State Corporation Comm'n, 5
Kan.App.2d 653, 661, 623 P.2d 924, 931 (1981);
State ex rel.
Associated Natural Gas Co. v. Public Service
Comm'n, 706 S.W.2d
870, 879-880 (Mo.App.1985). To the extent that the respondent
could have sought and gained permission to raise its rates in the
absence of an overcharge, at least some portion of the overcharge
is being borne by it; whether by overcharge or by increased rates,
consumers would have been paying more for natural gas than they had
been paying in the past. Because of this potential injury, the
respondent must remain in the suit. If we were to add indirect
purchasers to the action, we would have to devise an apportionment
formula. This is the very complexity that
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick sought to avoid.
Second, difficult questions of timing might necessitate
apportioning overcharges if we allowed indirect suits by utility
customers. Even if, at some point, a utility can pass on 100
percent of its costs to its customers, various factors may delay
the passing-on process. Some utilities must seek approval from the
governing regulators prior to raising their rates. Other utilities,
pursuant to Purchase Gas Adjustment clauses (PGAs) filed with state
regulators, may adjust their rates to reflect changes in their
wholesale costs according to prearranged formulas without seeking
regulatory approval in
Page 497 U. S. 211
each instance. Yet even utilities that use PGAs often encounter
some delay.
See Brief for State of Illinois as
Amicus
Curiae 9, n. 11 (describing the various time-lags under a
typical PGA between the increase in a utility's wholesale costs and
the rise in consumer rates). During any period in which a utility's
costs rise before it may adjust its rates, the utility will bear
the costs in the form of lower earnings.
See S. Breyer,
Regulation and its Reform 48-49 (1982). Even after the utility
raises its rates, moreover, the pass-through process may take time
to complete. During this time, the utility and its customers each
would pay for some of the increased costs.
In this case, we could not deprive the respondent of its §
4 action without first determining that the passing on process in
fact had allowed it to shift the entire overcharge to its
customers. The certified question, however, leaves unclear whether
the respondent had passed on "most or all" of its costs at the time
of the suit. In addition, even the means by which the pass-through
occurred remain unsettled. The petitioners allege that, pursuant to
formulas in PGAs filed with the Kansas Corporation Commission and
the Missouri Public Service Commission, the respondent
"automatically" adjusted some of its rates to reflect increases in
the wholesale cost of gas. Brief for Petitioners 5, n. 5. The
respondent, however, maintains that PGAs did not govern all of its
sales.
See Brief for Respondent 17. The difficulties posed
by issues of this sort led us to adopt the direct purchaser rule,
and we must decline to create an exception that would require their
litigation. As we have stated before,
"the task of disentangling overlapping damages claims is not
lightly to be imposed upon potential antitrust litigants, or upon
the judicial system."
McCready, 457 U.S. at
457 U. S. 475,
n. 11.
In addition to these complications, the regulation of utilities
itself may make an exception to
Illinois Brick
unnecessary. Our decisions in
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick often deny relief to consumers who have
paid inflated prices
Page 497 U. S. 212
because of their status as indirect purchasers.
See 2
P. Areeda & D. Turner, Antitrust Law § 337e, pp. 193-194
(1978); Harris & Sullivan, Passing on the Monopoly Overcharge:
A Comprehensive Policy Analysis, 128 U.Pa.L.Rev. 269, 342 (1979).
Although one might criticize
Illinois Brick for this
consequence in other circumstances, the criticism may have less
validity in the context of public utilities. Both the Court of
Appeals in this case and the Seventh Circuit in
Illinois ex
rel. Hartigan v. Panhandle Eastern Pipeline Co., 852 F.2d 891
(CA7 1988), have suggested that state regulators would require the
utilities to pass on at least some of the recovery obtained in a
§ 4 suit.
See Wyoming Tight Sands, 866 F.2d at 1291;
Panhandle Eastern, supra, at 895. State regulators have
followed this approach elsewhere.
See, e.g., In re: Petition of
LP & L for Order Relating to Disposition of Proceeds Against
Gas Supplier, 1989 La. PUC LEXIS 3, 31-32 (Nos. U-17906,
U-12636, and U-17649) (requiring Louisiana Power & Light Co.,
which won a $190 million judgment against United Gas Pipe Line Co.,
to flow the proceeds back to ratepayers through reduced rates over
a 5-year period). If Kansas and Missouri impose similar
requirements, then, even if the customers cannot sue the alleged
antitrust violators, they may receive some of the compensation
obtained by the respondent. Creating an exception to allow
apportionment in violation of
Illinois Brick would make
little sense when, in light of all its difficulty, its practical
significance is so diminished.
B
The
Illinois Brick rule also serves to eliminate
multiple recoveries.
See Illinois Brick, 431 U.S. at
431 U. S.
730-731;
McCready, supra, 457 U.S. at
457 U. S. 474.
The petitioners assert that no risk of multiple recovery would
exist here if we allowed them to sue, because the direct and
indirect purchasers would be seeking different, not duplicative,
damages; the petitioners would recover the amount of the overcharge
and the utilities would recover damages for their lost sales.
Leaving
Page 497 U. S. 213
aside the apportionment issue, we reject the argument in this
case, just as we did in
Illinois Brick. Bringing all
classes of direct and indirect purchasers together in a single
lawsuit may reduce the risk of multiple recovery, but the reduction
comes at too great a cost.
See Illinois Brick, supra, 431
U.S. at
431 U. S. 731
n. 11.
This case already has become quite complicated. It involves
numerous utilities and other companies operating in several states
under federal, state, and municipal regulation and, in some
instances, under no rate regulation at all. Even apart from gas
sold to customers, the utilities seek damages for lost sales and
for gas purchased for their own use. The petitioners, in addition
to their
parens patriae claims, are asserting direct
claims on behalf of numerous state agencies. Other direct
purchasers also seek several measures of damages. Allowing the
petitioners to proceed on behalf of consumers would complicate the
proceedings further. Even if they could represent consumers
residing in Kansas and Missouri, they could not represent
industrial and commercial purchasers or consumers from other
states.
See 15 U.S.C. § 15c(a)(1) (extending
parens patriae representation only to resident natural
persons). These unrepresented consumers might seek intervention and
further delay the prompt determination of the suit. The expansion
of the case would risk the confusion, costs, and possibility of
error inherent in complex litigation. At the same time, however, it
might serve little purpose, because, as noted above, state
regulatory law may provide appropriate relief to consumers even if
they cannot sue under § 4. As in
Illinois Brick, we
continue to believe that
"even if ways could be found to bring all potential plaintiffs
together in one huge action, the complexity thereby introduced into
treble-damages proceedings argues strongly for retaining the
Hanover Shoe rule."
431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 731,
n. 11.
Page 497 U. S. 214
C.
We have maintained throughout our cases that our interpretation
of § 4 must promote the vigorous enforcement of the antitrust
laws.
See Hanover Shoe, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493;
Illinois Brick supra, 431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 746;
McCready, supra, 457 U.S. at
457 U. S. 475,
n. 11;
California v. ARC America Corp., 490 U. S.
93,
490 U. S. 102,
n. 6 (1989). If we were convinced that indirect suits would secure
this goal better in cases involving utilities, the argument to
interpret § 4 to create the exception sought by the
petitioners might be stronger. On balance, however, we do not
believe that the petitioners can prevail in this critical part of
the case. The petitioners assert that utilities, such as the
respondent, lack the incentive to prosecute § 4 cases for two
reasons. First, they state that utilities, by law, may pass on
their costs to customers. Second, they surmise that utilities might
have to pass on damages recovered in a § 4 action. In other
words, according to the petitioners, utilities lose nothing if they
do not sue, and gain nothing if they do sue. In contrast, the
petitioners maintain, the large aggregate claims of residential
consumers will give state attorneys general ample motivation to sue
in their capacity as
parens patriae.
The petitioners' argument does not persuade us that utilities
will lack incentives to sue overcharging suppliers. Utilities may
bring § 4 actions in some instances for fear that regulators
will not allow them to shift known and avoidable overcharges on to
their customers.
See Kan.Stat.Ann. § 66-128a (1985)
(allowing the state commission to "review and evaluate the
efficiency or prudence of any actions . . . of any public utility
or common carrier for the purpose of establishing fair and
reasonable rates"); Mo.Rev.Stat. § 393.150 (1986) (interpreted
in
State ex rel. Associated Natural Gas Co. v. Public Service
Comm'n, 706 S.W.2d
870, 879-880 (Mo.App.1985), to give regulators "considerable
discretion" in setting gas rates). In addition, even if state law
would require a utility to reimburse its customers for recovered
overcharges, a utility may seek treble damages in a § 4
action.
Page 497 U. S. 215
The petitioners have cited no authority indicating that a
victorious utility would have to pay the entire exemplary portion
of these damages to its customers.
Utilities, moreover, have an established record of diligent
antitrust enforcement, having brought highly successful § 4
actions in many instances. The well-known group of actions from the
1960s involving overcharges for electrical generating equipment
provides an excellent example. In these cases, which involved
"a series of horizontal price-fixing conspiracies characterized
as the most shocking in the history of the Sherman Act, plaintiff
utilities . . . recover[ed] in unprecedented sums"
even though some of the utilities "passed on to their own
customers whatever higher costs they incurred as a consequence of
the alleged conspiracies." Pollock, Standing to Sue, Remoteness of
Injury, and the Passing-On Doctrine, 32 A.B.A. Antitrust L.J. 5,
10-11 (1966). The courts in these suits, even before the
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois Brick decisions,
considered the pass-on issue and held that the causes of action
were for the utilities to assert.
See, e.g., Commonwealth
Edison Co. v. Allis-Chalmers Mfg. Co., 335 F.2d 203, 208 (CA7
1964);
Ohio Valley Electric Corp. v. General Electric
Co., 244 F.
Supp. 914, 949-951 (SDNY 1965). Various factors may have
prompted these and other utility actions. For example, in addition
to the reasons stated above, the respondent asserts that, like any
business, an investor-owned utility has an interest in protecting
its market. But whatever the motivation for their § 4 suits,
this history makes us quite hesitant to take from the utilities the
responsibility for enforcing the antitrust laws.
Relying on indirect purchaser actions in utility cases might
fail to promote antitrust enforcement for other reasons. Consumers
may lack the expertise and experience necessary for detecting
improper pricing by a utility's suppliers.
See Landes
& Posner, The Economics of Passing On: A Reply to Harris and
Sullivan, 128 U.Pa.L.Rev. 1274, 1278-1279 (1980). Although state
attorneys general have greater expertise,
Page 497 U. S. 216
they may hesitate to exercise the
parens patriae device
in cases involving smaller, more speculative harm to consumers.
See Landes & Posner, Should Indirect Purchasers Have
Standing to Sue Under the Antitrust Laws? An Economic Analysis of
the Rule of
Illinois Brick 46 U.Chi.L.Rev. 602, 613
(1979).
See also Illinois Brick, 431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 745
(stating that, in indirect actions, "the uncertainty of how much of
an overcharge could be established . . . [and] the uncertainty of
how that overcharge would be apportioned . . . would further reduce
the incentive to sue"). And even when state attorneys general
decide to bring
parens patriae actions, they may sue only
on behalf of resident natural persons.
See 15 U.S.C.
§ 15c(a)(1). All others, including nonresidents and small
businesses, might fail to enforce their claims because of the
insignificance of their individual recoveries. For these reasons,
we remain unconvinced that the exception sought by the petitioners
would promote antitrust enforcement better than the current
Illinois Brick rule.
D
The preceding conclusions bring us to a broader point. The
rationales underlying
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois
Brick will not apply with equal force in all cases. We
nonetheless believe that ample justification exists for our stated
decision not to "carve out exceptions to the [direct purchaser]
rule for particular types of markets."
Illinois Brick, 431
U.S. at
431 U. S. 744.
The possibility of allowing an exception, even in rather
meritorious circumstances, would undermine the rule. As we have
stated:
"[T]he process of classifying various market situations
according to the amount of pass-on likely to be involved and its
susceptibility of proof in a judicial forum would entail the very
problems that the
Hanover Shoe rule was meant to avoid.
The litigation over where the line should be drawn in a particular
class of cases would inject the same 'massive evidence and
complicated theories'
Page 497 U. S. 217
into treble-damages proceedings, albeit at a somewhat higher
level of generality."
Id. at
431 U. S.
744-745. In sum, even assuming that any economic
assumptions underlying the
Illinois Brick rule might be
disproved in a specific case, we think it an unwarranted and
counterproductive exercise to litigate a series of exceptions.
Having stated the rule in
Hanover Shoe, and adhered to it
in
Illinois Brick, we stand by our interpretation of
§ 4.
III
The suggestion in
Hanover Shoe and
Illinois
Brick that a departure from the direct purchaser rule may be
necessary when an indirect purchaser buys under a preexisting
cost-plus contract does not justify an exception in this case. In
Hanover Shoe, we stated:
"We recognize that there might be situations -- for instance,
when an overcharged buyer has a preexisting 'cost-plus' contract,
thus making it easy to prove that he has not been damaged -- where
the considerations requiring that the passing-on defense not be
permitted in this case would not be present."
392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 494.
We observed further in
Illinois Brick:
"In [a cost-plus contract] situation, the [direct] purchaser is
insulated from any decrease in its sales as a result of attempting
to pass on the overcharge because its customer is committed to
buying a fixed quantity regardless of price. The effect of the
overcharge is essentially determined in advance, without reference
to the interaction of supply and demand that complicates the
determination in the general case."
431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 736.
The petitioners argue that the regulations and tariffs requiring
the respondent to pass on its costs to the consumers place this
case within the cost-plus contract exception. We disagree.
Page 497 U. S. 218
The respondent did not sell the gas to its customers under a
preexisting cost-plus contract. Even if we were to create an
exception for situations that merely resemble those governed by
such a contract, we would not apply the exception here. Our
statements above show that we might allow indirect purchasers to
sue only when, by hypothesis, the direct purchaser will bear no
portion of the overcharge and otherwise suffer no injury. That
certainty does not exist here.
The utility customers made no commitment to purchase any
particular quantity of gas, and the utility itself had no guarantee
of any particular profit. Even though the respondent raised its
prices to cover its costs, we cannot ascertain its precise injury
because, as noted above, we do not know what might have happened in
the absence of an overcharge. In addition, even if the utility
customers had a highly inelastic demand for natural gas,
see
Panhandle Eastern, 852 F.2d at 895, the need to inquire into
the precise operation of market forces would negate the simplicity
and certainty that could justify a cost-plus contract exception.
See Illinois Brick, supra, 431 U.S. at 742; P. Areeda
& H. Hovencamp, Antitrust Law § 337.3c, pp. 323-324
(Supp.1988). Thus, although we do not alter our observations about
the possibility of an exception for cost-plus contracts, we decline
to create the general exception for utilities sought by the
petitioners.
IV
The petitioners, in their final argument, contend that § 4C
of the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, 90
Stat. 1394,
as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 15c, authorizes
them to sue on behalf of consumers even though the consumers, as
indirect purchasers, have no cause of action of their own. Section
4C(a)(1) provides in relevant part:
"Any attorney general of a State may bring a civil action in the
name of such state as
parens patriae on behalf of natural
persons residing in such State . . . to secure monetary relief as
provided in this section for injury sustained
Page 497 U. S. 219
by such natural persons to their property by reason of any
violation of sections 1 to 7 of this title."
15 U.S.C. § 15c(a)(1). Because the Act, in their view, has
the clear purpose of protecting consumers,
see Kintner,
Griffin, & Goldston, The Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust
Improvements Act of 1976: An Analysis, 46 Geo.Wash.L.Rev. 1, 23
(1977), the petitioners contend that it must allow the States to
sue on behalf of consumers notwithstanding their status as indirect
purchasers.
We have rejected this argument before. We stated in
Illinois
Brick that § 4C did not establish any new substantive
liability. Instead,
"[i]t simply created a new procedural device --
parens
patriae actions by States on behalf of their citizens -- to
enforce existing rights of recovery under § 4 [of the Clayton
Act.]"
431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 734,
n. 14. Section 4, as noted above, affords relief only to a person
"injured in his business or property by reason of anything
forbidden in the antitrust laws." 15 U.S.C. § 15(a). State
attorneys general may bring actions on behalf of consumers who have
such an injury.
See, e.g., Pennsylvania v. Mid-Atlantic Toyota
Distributors, Inc., 704 F.2d 125, 128 (CA4 1983) (suit on
behalf of consumers injured by an alleged conspiracy to fix the
price of cars). But here the respondent is the injured party under
the antitrust laws, and the predicate for a
parens patriae
action has not been established. We conclude that the petitioners
may not assert any claims on behalf of the customers.
Affirmed.
Justice WHITE, with whom Justice BRENNAN, Justice MARSHALL, and
Justice BLACKMUN join, dissenting.
I dissent from the Court's opinion and judgment because it is
inappropriate for the Court to deny standing to sue under § 4
of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15, to customers of a
regulated utility in circumstances such as those presented in this
case. By its plain language, § 4 reflects an "
expansive
remedial
Page 497 U. S.
220
purpose.'" Blue Shield of Virginia v. McCready,
457 U. S. 465,
457 U. S. 472
(1982) (citation omitted). It does not distinguish between classes
of customers, but rather grants a cause of action to "any person
who shall be injured in his business or property by reason of
anything forbidden in the antitrust laws. . . ." 15 U.S.C. §
15(a). In enacting § 4, Congress sought to ensure that victims
of anticompetitive conduct receive compensation. Blue Shield,
supra, at 472; Pfizer, Inc. v. India, 434 U.
S. 308, 434 U. S. 314
(1978).
In
Illinois Brick Co. v. Illinois, 431 U.
S. 720 (1977), we held that certain indirect purchasers
of concrete block lacked standing to challenge the manufacturer's
business practices under the antitrust laws because they could not
be deemed to have suffered injury from the alleged illegal conduct.
This suit, however, is very different from
Illinois Brick.
That case involved a competitive market where concrete block
manufacturers sold to masonry contractors who, in turn, sold to
general contractors, who, in turn, sold to the
Illinois
Brick respondents; this case involves a highly regulated
market where utilities possessing natural monopolies purchase gas
from natural gas suppliers and then sell the gas to residential
customers.
Illinois Brick did not hold that, in all
circumstances, indirect purchasers lack § 4 standing. Indeed,
just last Term we observed that, under
Illinois Brick,
"indirect purchasers might be allowed to bring suit in cases in
which it would be easy to prove the extent to which the overcharge
was passed on to them."
California v. ARC America Corp., 490 U. S.
93,
490 U. S. 102,
and n. 6 (1989).
See also Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe
Machinery Corp., 392 U. S. 481,
392 U. S. 494
(1968).
The issue in this case is whether
Illinois Brick bars a
suit by retail customers to whom the utilities have passed on the
entire cost of the gas sold to them, including any illegal
overcharge. Before the District Court, the utilities moved to
dismiss the States as
parens patriae, arguing that the
States lacked standing because they represented indirect
purchasers.
Page 497 U. S. 221
In response, the States contended that the indirect purchasers
were proper plaintiffs because the utilities had passed through the
entire overcharge to their residential customers. The District
Court found it unnecessary "to wait upon evidence establishing the
degree to which the utilities passed on the overcharge,"
In re
Wyoming Tight Sands Antitrust Cases, 695 F.
Supp. 1109, 1116 (Kan. 1988), for, even accepting the State's
position that there had been a total pass-on, decisions of this
Court were thought to bar the suit. Likewise, in affirming the
District Court, the Court of Appeals presumed a "perfect and
provable pass-on of the allegedly illegal overcharge."
In re
Wyoming Tight Sands Antitrust Cases, 866 F.2d 1286, 1293 (CA10
1989). Indeed, the Vice President and General Counsel of one of the
respondent utilities is on record as stating that the utility's
customers "pay
all of any increases in the cost of natural
gas [Kansas Power & Light] must purchase to serve them."
Affidavit of David S. Black, Vice President and General Counsel of
the Kansas Power & Light Company, Record, Doc. No. 485, Exhibit
D (emphasis in original). Rather than embarking, as the Court does,
on what amounts to a factfinding mission, which the courts below
eschewed, about the fact and probability of this pass-on, we should
decide this case on the basis that there has been a complete
pass-through of the overcharge. On that basis, it is evident that
the concerns underlying the decision in
Illinois Brick do
not support the judgment below. Rather, we should follow the plain
intent of § 4 that the victims of anticompetitive conduct be
allowed the remedy provided by the section.
Illinois Brick barred indirect purchaser suits chiefly
because we feared that permitting the use of pass-on theories under
§ 4 would transform these treble-damages actions into massive
and inconclusive efforts to apportion the recovery among all
potential plaintiffs that could have absorbed part of the
overcharge -- from direct purchasers to middlemen to ultimate
consumers. 431 U.S. at
431 U. S. 737.
As Judge Posner has
Page 497 U. S. 222
written,
"[t]he optimal adjustment by an unregulated firm to the
increased cost of the input will always be a price increase smaller
than the increase in input cost, and this means that the increased
cost will be divided between the two tiers, the direct and the
indirect purchasers -- but in what proportion will often be hard to
determine, even by sophisticated techniques of economic analysis.
This is a central insight of the
Illinois Brick
decision."
Illinois ex rel. Hartigan v. Panhandle Eastern Pipe Line
Co., 852 F.2d 891, 894 (CA7 1988).
In this case, however, it is regulation, rather than market
forces, that determines the amount of overcharge that the utility
passes through to its residential customers. The rates of utilities
are determined by law and are set at a level designed to allow a
fair return on a rate base that includes the cost of furnishing the
service, plainly including in this case the cost of gas purchased
from the pipelines and resold to customers. It is fanciful, at
least unrealistic, to think that a utility entitled to pass on to
its customers the cost of gas that it has purchased will not do so
to the maximum extent permitted by law. Furthermore, petitioners
assert that, in this case, the applicable law requires that such
cost be passed on to consumers. And, as we have said, the Tenth
Circuit opinion reflects the likelihood of a perfect and provable
pass-on.
Of course, to recover in a case like this, the plaintiff must
prove that the utility paid the pipelines an illegally high price,
and must demonstrate the amount of the overcharge. That amount is
included in the rates charged by the utility, and hence is passed
through to the consumer. The result is that determining the injury
inflicted on consumers involves nothing more than reading their
utility bills, which reveal the amount of gas purchased by them at
a price which includes the amount of the illegal overcharge passed
through to them. Where it is clear that the entire overcharge is
passed through, there can be no claim that indirect purchasers
cannot
Page 497 U. S. 223
prove the extent of their damage caused by a rate calculated on
a rate base inflated by an illegal price paid for gas.
The Court contends that the apportionment problem is not so
simple. It maintains that, even where a utility raises its rates to
compensate for the overcharge and passes the overcharge through to
the indirect purchasers, an apportionment problem still exists
because
"to show that a direct purchaser has borne no portion of an
overcharge, the indirect purchaser would have to prove, among other
things, that the direct purchaser could not have raised its rates
prior to the overcharge."
Ante at
497 U. S. 209.
The problem identified by the majority is not peculiar to indirect
purchaser suits. In antitrust cases where suppliers increase their
prices, courts frequently must separate the price increase
attributable to anticompetitive conduct (
i.e., the
"overcharge") from the price increase attributable to legitimate
factors. This type of calculation
"has to be done in every case where the plaintiff claims to have
lost sales because of the defendant's unlawful conduct and the
defendant argues that the loss was due partly or entirely to other
factors."
Panhandle Eastern, supra, at 897;
see Bigelow v.
RKO Radio Pictures, Inc., 327 U. S. 251
(1946). The problem identified in
Illinois Brick was
entirely different: there we were concerned that it would unduly
complicate litigation to require courts to separate the portion of
the overcharge absorbed by the direct purchaser from the portion of
the overcharge passed onto the indirect purchaser. As argued above,
this difficulty is not a concern in the present case.* It is at
least very doubtful that a utility that is
Page 497 U. S. 224
in position to secure a rate increase on grounds having nothing
to do with the price paid for its gas would fail to request a rate
increase that included, as well, the entire amount paid for gas
purchased from pipelines and sold to consumers.
Illinois Brick also observed that granting standing to
the indirect purchasers in that case would lead to the
under-enforcement of the antitrust laws. 431 U.S. at
431 U. S.
745-747. In the cases where there is "a perfect and
provable pass-through," however, the opposite is true for two
reasons. First, because the pass-through of the overcharge is
complete and easily demonstrated, the indirect purchasers -- and
the States in their
parens patriae capacity -- may readily
discover their injury. Second, although the utility could sue to
recover lost profits resulting from lost sales due to the illegally
high price, its injury is not measured by the amount of the illegal
overcharge that it has passed on, and hence the utility would have
no incentive to seek such a recovery.
The majority suggests that, even where a utility passes the
entire overcharge through to the indirect customers, the utility
nonetheless might actively prosecute antitrust claims because the
state regulatory commission may allow the utility to keep any
damages that the utility recovers. But the utility commissions
cannot allow an antitrust recovery forbidden by federal law. Given
a pass-through, the customer, not the utility, suffers the
antitrust injury, and it is the customer or the state on their
behalf that is entitled to recover treble damages. In any event, it
seems to me that the majority conjures up a very strange utility
commission, the possible existence of which the court fails to
document.
A third consideration prompting our decision in
Illinois
Brick was our belief that permitting indirect purchaser suits
might subject antitrust defendants to multiple liability. 431 U.S.
at
431 U. S.
730-731. Again however, where there is a "perfect and
provable" pass-through, there is no danger that both the utilities
and the indirect purchasers will recover damages for the same
anticompetitive conduct, because the utilities
Page 497 U. S. 225
have not suffered any overcharge damage: the petitioners will
sue for the amount of the overcharge, while the utilities will sue
for damages resulting from their lost sales.
The majority argues that, even "[l]eaving aside the
apportionment issue" (
i.e., assuming that there is no
apportionment difficulty, as the Tenth Circuit did in affirming
summary judgment), the multiple recovery problem identified in
Illinois Brick still exists.
Ante at
497 U. S.
212-213. I disagree.
Illinois Brick
"focused on the risk of duplicative recovery engendered by
allowing every person along a chain of distribution to claim
damages arising from a single transaction that violated the
antitrust laws."
Blue Shield, 457 U.S. at
457 U. S.
474-475. The danger of multiple recoveries does not
exist aside from the apportionment difficulty; rather, it stems
from it. If only defensive use of a pass-through defense were
barred, or if it were extremely difficult to ascertain the
percentage of an overcharge that the utility passed through, then
the supplier of natural gas might potentially have to pay
overlapping damages to successive purchasers at different levels in
the distribution chain. But where there is no apportionment
difficulty, there is no comparable risk.
In sum, I cannot agree with the rigid and expansive holding
that, in no case, even in the utility context, would it be possible
to determine in a reliable way a pass-through to consumers of an
illegal overcharge that would measure the extent of their damage.
There may be cases, as the Court speculates, where there would be
insuperable difficulties. But we are to judge this case on the
basis that the pass-through is complete and provable. There have
been no findings below that this is not the fact. Instead, the
decision we review is that consumers may not sue even where it is
clear and provable that an illegal overcharge has been passed on to
them and that they, rather than the utility, have to that extent
been injured.
None of the concerns that caused us to bar the indirect
purchaser's suit in
Illinois Brick exist in this case. For
that
Page 497 U. S. 226
reason, rather than extending the
Illinois Brick
exception to § 4's grant of a cause of action to persons
injured through anticompetitive conduct, I would hold that the
petitioners in this case have standing to sue. This result would
promote the twin antitrust goals of ensuring recompense for injured
parties and encouraging the diligent prosecution of antitrust
claims.
* The majority also suggests that
"difficult problems of timing might necessitate apportioning
overcharges if we allowed indirect suits by utility customers. Even
if, at some point, a utility can pass on 100 percent of its costs
to its customers, various factors may delay the passing on
process."
Ante at
497 U. S. 210.
This suggestion, as suggested by the words "might" and "may," is
quite speculative. It is much more realistic to believe that,
sooner or later, the customer will foot the cost of overpriced gas.
If timing was such a problem, the Tenth Circuit would not have
assumed a "perfect and provable" pass-through.