The federal Agricultural Fair Practices Act of 1967 (AFPA) was
enacted to enable individual farmers and other producers of
agricultural commodities to join together voluntarily in
cooperative associations in order to protect their marketing and
bargaining position as against large and powerful agricultural
processors. The AFPA makes it unlawful for "handlers" defined to
include both processors and producers' associations -- to coerce
any producer "in the exercise of his right to join . . . or to
refrain from joining" a producers' association, 7 U.S.C. §
2303(a), or to coerce any producer to enter into or terminate a
marketing contract with a producers' association or a contract with
a handler, § 2303(e). The Michigan Agricultural Marketing and
Bargaining Act (Michigan Act) includes the same prohibitions as the
AFPA, but goes beyond it by establishing a state-administered
system by which producers' associations are organized and certified
as exclusive bargaining agents for all producers of a particular
commodity. Under this system, if an association's membership
constitutes more than 50% of the producers of a particular
commodity and its members' production accounts for more than 50% of
the commodity's total production, the association may be accredited
as the exclusive bargaining agent for all producers of that
commodity. Upon accreditation of the association, all producers of
the commodity, regardless of whether they have chosen to become
members of the association, must pay a service fee to the
association, and must abide by the contracts the association
negotiates with processors. The Michigan Agricultural Cooperative
Marketing Association (MACMA), a producers' association accredited
under the Michigan Act, is the sole sales and bargaining
representative for asparagus producers in the State. After the
MACMA had negotiated contracts on behalf of Michigan asparagus
growers to sell the asparagus crop for a certain year, appellant
asparagus growers and association of asparagus processors sued
MACMA in state court seeking a declaratory judgment that the
provisions of the Michigan Act requiring service fees and mandatory
adherence to an association-negotiated contract are preempted by
the AFPA. The Michigan Supreme Court rejected appellants' claim,
holding that the
Page 467 U. S. 462
AFPA prohibited only processor misconduct, whereas the
challenged provisions of the Michigan Act regulated producers'
activities.
Held: The challenged provisions of the Michigan Act are
preempted by the AFPA. Pp.
467 U. S. 469-478.
(a) This is a case where the basis for preemption is that
Congress, while not displacing state regulation entirely, has
preempted state law to the extent that it conflicts with federal
law and "stands as an obstacle to the accomplishment and execution
of the full purposes and objectives of Congress."
Hines v.
Davidowitz, 312 U. S. 52,
312 U. S. 67.
Pp.
467 U. S.
469-470.
(b) The AFPA's theme of voluntariness is carried through to the
provisions defining the prohibited practices. By defining the term
"handler" to include producers' associations as well as processors,
the AFPA prohibits interference by the former to the same extent
that it prohibits interference by the latter. Just as the AFPA
forbids processors to interfere in a producer's decision to become
or remain affiliated with an association, it also forbids a
producers' association to interfere in that decision by coercing
producers to belong to, or participate in a marketing contract
with, the association. Pp.
467 U. S. 470-471.
(c) Congress' intent to shield producers from coercion by both
processors and producers' associations is confirmed by the AFPA's
legislative history, which reveals that the question of the
producer's free choice was a central focus of congressional
attention during passage of the Act. Despite the fact that the
Michigan Act and the AFPA share the goal of augmenting the
producer's bargaining power, the Michigan Act conflicts with the
AFPA by establishing "accredited" associations that wield the power
to coerce producers to sell their products according to terms
established by the association, and to force producers to pay a
service fee for the privilege. Pp.
467 U. S.
471-477.
(d) The Michigan Act empowers producers' associations to do
precisely what the AFPA forbids them to do. In effect, an
association accredited under the Michigan Act may coerce a producer
to enter into a marketing contract with a producers' association --
a clear violation of § 2303(c). In addition, although the
Michigan Act does not compel a producer to join an association, it
binds him to the association's marketing contracts, forces him to
pay fees to the association, and precludes him from marketing his
goods himself, and thus, in practical effect, imposes on the
producer the same incidents of association membership with which
Congress was concerned in enacting § 2303(a). Pp.
467 U. S.
477-478.
416 Mich. 706,
332 N.W.2d
134, reversed.
BRENNAN, J., delivered the opinion for a unanimous Court.
Page 467 U. S. 463
JUSTICE BRENNAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
A perceived need to help the American farmer in his economic
relations with large and powerful agricultural processors has moved
Congress and various States to enact laws designed to bolster the
farmer's bargaining power when bringing his goods to market. This
case involves two such laws: the federal Agricultural Fair
Practices Act of 1967 and the State of Michigan's Agricultural
Marketing and Bargaining Act (Michigan Act). The question presented
is whether certain provisions of the Michigan Act, which accord
agricultural cooperative associations exclusive bargaining
authority for the sale of agricultural products, are preempted by
the federal Act. The Supreme Court of Michigan held that the
Michigan Act is not preempted. 416
Page 467 U. S. 464
Mich. 706,
332 N.W.2d
134 (1982). W e noted probable jurisdiction, 464 U.S. 912
(1983), and now reverse.
I
A
The federal Agricultural Fair Practices Act (AFPA), 82 Stat. 93,
7 U.S.C. § 2301
et seq., protects the right of
farmers and other producers [
Footnote 1] of agricultural commodities to join
cooperative associations through which to market their products.
[
Footnote 2] Responding to "the
growing concentration of power in the hands of fewer and larger
buyers [of agricultural products]," S.Rep. No. 474, 90th Cong., 1st
Sess., 2-3 (1967), Congress enacted the AFPA to rectify a perceived
imbalance in bargaining position between producers and processors
of such products. Although the Act's principal purpose is to
protect individual producers from interference by processors when
deciding whether to belong to a producers' association, the Act
also protects the producer from coercion by associations of
producers. The AFPA thus provides that it is unlawful for either a
processor or a producers' association to engage in practices that
interfere with a producer's freedom to choose whether to bring his
products to market himself or to sell them through a producers'
cooperative association. 7 U.S.C. § 2303. Specifically, §
2303(a) forbids "handlers" --
Page 467 U. S. 465
defined to include both processors and producers' associations
[
Footnote 3] -- to
"coerce any producer in the exercise of his right to join and
belong to or to refrain from joining or belonging to an association
of producers."
Similarly, § 2303(c) forbids handlers to
"coerce or intimidate any producer to enter into, maintain,
breach, cancel, or terminate a membership agreement or marketing
contract with an association of producers or a contract with a
handler. [
Footnote 4] "
Page 467 U. S. 466
The Michigan Act, Mich.Comp.Laws § 290.701
et seq.
(1984), also designed to facilitate collective action among
producers, includes the same prohibitions as the federal Act. It
goes beyond the federal statute, however, by extensively regulating
the activities of producers' associations. Most importantly, the
Michigan Act establishes a state-administered system by which
producers' associations are organized and certified as exclusive
bargaining agents for all producers of a particular commodity.
§§ 290.703, 290.707. Under Michigan's system, if an
association's membership constitutes more than 50% of the producers
of a particular commodity, and its members' production accounts for
more than 50% of the commodity's total production, the association
may apply to the state Agricultural Marketing and Bargaining Board
for accreditation as the exclusive bargaining agent for all
producers of that particular commodity. § 290.707(c).
[
Footnote 5] When the
Page 467 U. S. 467
Board accredits an association as the agent for the producers of
a particular commodity, all producers of that commodity, regardless
of whether they have chosen to become members
Page 467 U. S. 468
of the association, must pay a service fee to the association
and must abide by the terms of the contracts the association
negotiates with processors. §§ 290.710(1), 290.713(1).
[
Footnote 6] Thus, the Michigan
Act creates an "agency shop" arrangement among agricultural
producers whenever there is majority support for such an
arrangement among the producers of a particular commodity.
B
The Michigan Agricultural Cooperative Marketing Association,
Inc. (MACMA), a producers' association accredited under the
Michigan Act, is the sole sales and bargaining representative for
asparagus producers in the State. [
Footnote 7] In 1974, as permitted by the Michigan Act,
MACMA negotiated contracts on behalf of Michigan asparagus growers
to sell the 1974 asparagus crop. In response, appellants Dukesherer
Farms and Ferris Pierson, asparagus growers that would be bound by
the contract, along with the Michigan Canners & Freezers
Association, Inc., an association of asparagus processors,
[
Footnote 8] sued MACMA in
state court seeking a declaratory judgment that those provisions of
the Michigan Act requiring service fees and mandatory adherence to
an association-negotiated contract are preempted by the AFPA. The
Supreme Court of Michigan rejected appellants' claim, holding that
the Michigan Act operated in an area that the federal
Page 467 U. S. 469
Act did not regulate. 416 Mich. 706,
332 N.W.2d
134 (1976). Specifically, the Michigan court held that the
federal Act prohibited only processor misconduct, whereas the
challenged portions of the Michigan Act regulated producers'
activities. We disagree.
II
Federal law may preempt state law in any of three ways. First,
in enacting the federal law, Congress may explicitly define the
extent to which it intends to preempt state law.
E.g., Shaw v.
Delta Air Lines, Inc., 463 U. S. 85,
463 U. S. 95-96
(1983). Second, even in the absence of express preemptive language,
Congress may indicate an intent to occupy an entire field of
regulation, in which case the States must leave all regulatory
activity in that area to the Federal Government.
E.g., Fidelity
Federal Savings & Loan Assn. v. De la Cuesta, 458 U.
S. 141,
458 U. S. 153
(1982);
Rice v. Santa Fe Elevator Corp., 331 U.
S. 218,
331 U. S. 230
(1947). Finally, if Congress has not displaced state regulation
entirely, it may nonetheless preempt state law to the extent that
the state law actually conflicts with federal law. Such a conflict
arises when compliance with both state and federal law is
impossible,
Florida Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc. v.
Paul, 373 U. S. 132,
373 U. S.
142-143 (1963), or when the state law "stands as an
obstacle to the accomplishment and execution of the full purposes
and objectives of Congress."
Hines v. Davidowitz,
312 U. S. 52,
312 U. S. 67
(1941).
See also Fidelity Federal Savings & Loan Assn.,
supra, at
458 U. S.
153.
It is the last basis of preemption that applies in this case.
The AFPA contains no preemptive language; nor does it reflect a
congressional intent to occupy the entire field of agricultural
product marketing. Indeed, the Act states that it "shall not be
construed to change or modify existing State law." 7 U.S.C. §
2305(d). [
Footnote 9] And, as
this Court has recognized,
Page 467 U. S. 470
"the supervision of the readying of foodstuffs for market has
always been deemed a matter of peculiarly local concern."
Florida Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc., supra, at
373 U.S. 144.
Appellants contend that the service fee and mandatory
representation provisions of the Michigan Act frustrate the purpose
and objective of the AFPA by imposing on unwilling producers an
exclusive bargaining arrangement with associations. In their view,
although Congress' chief interest in enacting the AFPA was to
facilitate the growth of agricultural cooperative associations, an
equally important congressional objective was to preserve the free
choice of producers to join associations or to remain independent.
The Michigan Act, appellants contend, deprives producers of that
choice and allows associations, in effect, to coerce producers into
association affiliation. [
Footnote 10]
A
We turn first to the wording of the AFPA. The Act begins with a
finding that
"the marketing and bargaining position of individual farmers
will be adversely affected unless
Page 467 U. S. 471
they are free to join together
voluntarily in
cooperative organizations as authorized by law."
§ 2301 (emphasis added). More significantly, however, the
theme of voluntariness is carried through to the provisions of the
Act that define those practices that are prohibited. Thus, in
addition to forbidding various practices that could discourage
producers from joining associations, the Act explicitly makes
unlawful the coercion of a producer "in the exercise of his right .
. .
to refrain from joining or belonging to an association
of producers," and the coercion of a producer to "
enter into
[or] maintain . . . a membership agreement or marketing
contract with an association of producers." §§ 2303(a)
and (c) (emphasis added). Moreover, by defining the term "handler"
to include producers' associations as well as processors of
agricultural products,
see supra at
467 U. S.
464-465, the Act prohibits interference by the former to
the same extent that it prohibits interference by the latter. In
short, just as the Act forbids processors to interfere in a
producer's decision to become or remain affiliated with an
association, it also forbids an association of producers to
interfere in that decision by coercing producers to belong to, or
participate in a marketing contract with, the association.
B
Congress' intent to shield producers from coercion by both
processors and producers' associations is confirmed by the
legislative history of the AFPA, which reveals that the question of
the producer's free choice was a central focus of congressional
attention during the passage of the Act. Although the AFPA began as
a bill aimed solely at the threat of processor coercion, its
orientation shifted as it progressed through Congress to one of
sheltering the producer from coercion in either direction.
The bill originally introduced in the Senate, S. 109, 89th
Cong., 1st Sess. (1965), did not explicitly protect the producer's
right to remain independent from an association, and for that
reason provoked considerable criticism in the hearings that
followed. Critics of the bill offered several reasons for
Page 467 U. S. 472
prohibiting association coercion to the same extent as processor
coercion. First, some producers stated that they preferred to
remain independent because they believed they could earn more money
if they marketed their products themselves. [
Footnote 11] Second, processors testified that,
unless associations were also prohibited from pressuring producers,
there would be a serious risk that the associations would attain a
bargaining position of monopoly proportion, to the detriment of not
only the processor but the consumer as well. [
Footnote 12] Third, witnesses testified that a
prohibition on interference by producers' associations would
promote competition on the merits among associations seeking
membership. [
Footnote 13]
Fourth, many handlers testified that they would be disadvantaged in
the quality of the product they could buy as well as the price they
would have to pay if producers' associations were permitted
substantially to diminish the ranks of the independent producer.
[
Footnote 14] Finally,
witnesses testified that the producer's right to remain independent
of an association was simply "a basic American right" deserving of
protection. [
Footnote
15]
Page 467 U. S. 473
In response to these concerns, the Senate passed an amended bill
that prohibited coercion by both processors and associations,
thereby protecting the producer's right to remain independent. The
new bill opened with a legislative finding that
"the marketing and bargaining position of individual farmers
will be adversely affected unless they are free to join together
or not join together in cooperative organizations as
authorized by law."
113 Cong.Rec. 21410 (1967) (emphasis added). The bill went on to
provide:
"
It shall be unlawful for any handler or
association of producers knowingly to engage . . . in the
following practices:"
"(a)
To coerce any producer in the exercise of his
right to join and belong to or
to refrain from joining or
belonging to an association of producers . . . ; or"
"
* * * *"
"(c) To coerce or intimidate any producer or other person
to
enter into [or] maintain . . . a membership agreement or
Page 467 U. S. 474
marketing contract with an association of producers or a
contract with a handler. . . ."
Ibid. (emphasis added). [
Footnote 16] The Senate Report explaining these
provisions of the bill stated:
"The objective of the bill is to protect the producer in the
exercise of a free choice. Many witnesses suggested that the bill
did not fully accomplish this purpose, because it protected the
producer only from improper pressure not to join an association. To
protect his free choice, he should also be protected from improper
pressure in the other direction, that is, improper pressure to join
an association. The committee did not have before it any testimony
to indicate that producers were being subjected to any improper
pressure to join associations, but was convinced by the logic of
the situation that, if the objective is to protect the producer and
afford him a free choice, the bill should protect him from pressure
in either direction."
S.Rep. No. 474, 90th Cong., 1st Sess., 5 (1967). Similarly, when
Senator Aiken introduced the bill on the floor of the Senate, he
stated that the bill
"is designed to protect the agricultural producer's right to
decide, free from improper pressures, whether or not he wishes to
belong to a marketing or bargaining association."
113 Cong.Rec. 21411 (1967).
Page 467 U. S. 475
The Senate bill was next referred to the House Committee on
Agriculture,
ibid., which heard testimony from producers'
associations opposed to their inclusion in the prohibited practices
section of the bill. [
Footnote
17] The Committee rejected their plea, however, and declined to
adopt a proposed amendment to the bill that would have limited its
application to processors. H.R.Rep. No. 824, 90th Cong., 1st Sess.,
4-5 (1967). Ultimately, the House deleted the explicit reference to
associations of producers from the prohibited practices section of
the bill, 114 Cong.Rec. 7449 (1968), and it amended the legislative
findings and declaration of policy to read:
"the marketing and bargaining position of individual farmers
will be adversely affected unless they are free to join together
voluntarily in cooperative organizations as authorized by
law."
Id. at 7469 (emphasis added). [
Footnote 18] In so doing, however, the House
indicated that it did not intend to alter the substance of the
bill. Representative Sisk explained:
"Since the bill already makes clear that associations of
producers are not excluded from the term 'handler,' the phrase
['association of producers' in the prohibited practices section] is
redundant, and could be misconstrued as unfairly pointing the
finger of accusation to associations of producers. This is not the
intent; and while my amendments do not change the purpose or basic
meaning of the bill, they make misinterpretation more
difficult."
Id. at 7464.
Page 467 U. S. 476
Similarly, in reference to the proposed amendment,
Representative Latta stated that
"I want the record to clearly show that our farmers under the
present language of this bill . . . have the right not to join
these associations if they so choose."
Id. at 7449. In response to Representative Latta,
Representative Poage, Chairman of the House Committee on
Agriculture, stated:
"It was clearly the opinion of the entire committee that there
was not any intention or desire to give anybody the right to
discriminate against anybody else because of his failure to join
any of these associations."
"
* * * *"
"I cannot see that the amendments do anything more than to make
the matter read a little differently and a little more
satisfactorily, to certain groups, without changing in one iota, so
far as I can see, the legal effect of the legislation."
"
* * * *"
"I do not think taking out the words in numerous places --
'associations of producers' -- will in anywise change the legal
effect."
Id. at 7449-7450. Finally, highlighting its intent to
prohibit coerced affiliation with associations, the House amended
the definition of the term "handler" to include any association
"contracting or negotiating contracts or other arrangements,
written or oral, with
or on behalf of producers or
associations of producers."
Id. at 7465, 7469 (emphasis added). [
Footnote 19]
Page 467 U. S. 477
The Senate agreed to the House amendments without debate.
Id. at 8419. Hence, in passing S. 109, both the House and
the Senate unequivocally expressed an intent to prohibit producers'
associations from coercing a producer to agree to membership or any
other agency relationship that would impinge on the producer's
independence. It would appear, therefore, that despite the fact
that the Michigan Act and the AFPA share the goal of augmenting the
producer's bargaining power, the Michigan Act nonetheless conflicts
with the AFPA by establishing "accredited" associations that wield
the power to coerce producers to sell their products according to
terms established by the association and to force producers to pay
a service fee for the privilege.
C
The Michigan Supreme Court held that,
"[w]hile § 2303 makes it unlawful for a handler to coerce a
producer to 'join or belong to' an association, it does not forbid
a state from requiring exclusive representation of individual
producers where a producer majority sees fit."
416 Mich., at 719, 332 N.W.2d at 139. The Michigan Act, however,
empowers producers' associations to do precisely what the federal
Act
Page 467 U. S. 478
forbids them to do. Once an association reaches a certain size
and receives its accreditation, it is authorized to bind
nonmembers, without their consent, to the marketing contracts into
which it enters with processors. In effect, therefore, an
accredited association operating under the Michigan Act may coerce
a producer to "enter into [or] maintain . . . a marketing contract
with an association of producers or a contract with a handler" -- a
clear violation of § 2303(c). [
Footnote 20] In addition, although the Michigan Act does
not compel a producer to join an association, it binds him to the
association's marketing contracts, forces him to pay fees to the
association, and precludes him from marketing his goods himself.
See n 6,
supra. In practical effect, therefore, the Michigan Act
imposes on the producer the same incidents of association
membership with which Congress was concerned in enacting §
2303(a).
In conclusion, because the Michigan Act authorizes producers'
associations to engage in conduct that the federal Act forbids, it
"stands as an obstacle to the accomplishment and execution of the
full purposes and objectives of Congress."
Hines v.
Davidowitz, 312 U.S. at
312 U. S. 67.
[
Footnote 21] To that
extent, therefore, the Michigan Act is preempted by the AFPA, and
the judgment of the Supreme Court of Michigan is reversed.
It is so ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
Title 7 U.S.C. § 2302(b) defines the term "producer" to
mean
"a person engaged in the production of agricultural products as
a farmer, planter, rancher, dairyman, fruit, vegetable, or nut
grower."
[
Footnote 2]
Under § 1 of the Capper-Volstead Act, 7 U.S.C. § 291,
and § 6 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 17, most
activities of agricultural cooperatives were already exempt from
the antitrust laws. Thus, producers already had a legal right to
belong to such associations. The AFPA went further than the prior
Acts by protecting the right against economic coercion.
The term "association of producers," also referred to herein as
"producers' associations," is defined to mean
"any association of producers of agricultural products engaged
in marketing, bargaining, shipping, or processing as defined in
section 1141(j) of title 12, or in section 291 of this title."
7 U.S.C. § 2302(c).
[
Footnote 3]
The term "handler" generally refers to buyers and processors of
agricultural products. As the AFPA evolved through the legislative
process, however, and Congress decided to apply most of its
prohibitions to producers' associations as well as to handlers,
Congress expanded the definition of "handler" to include
associations of producers. Thus 7 U.S.C. § 2302(a)
provides:
"The term 'handler' means any person engaged in the business or
practice of (1) acquiring agricultural products from producers or
associations of producers for processing or sale; or (2) grading,
packaging, handling, storing, or processing agricultural products
received from producers or associations of producers; or (3)
contracting or negotiating contracts or other arrangements, written
or oral, with or
on behalf of producers or associations of
producers with respect to the production or marketing of any
agricultural product; or (4) acting as an agent or broker for a
handler in the performance of any function or act specified in
clause (1), (2), or (3) of this paragraph."
(Emphasis added.) In addition, 7 U.S.C. § 2302(d) provides
that "the term
person' includes individuals, partnerships,
corporations, and associations" (emphasis added).
The term "processor" is used herein to refer to all "handlers"
under the federal Act except producers' associations acting in
their capacity as marketing representatives of producers.
[
Footnote 4]
Section 2303 provides in full:
"It shall be unlawful for any handler knowingly to engage or
permit any employee or agent to engage in the following
practices:"
"(a) To coerce any producer in the exercise of his right to join
and belong to or to refrain from joining or belonging to an
association of producers, or to refuse to deal with any producer
because of the exercise of his right to join and belong to such an
association; or"
"(b) To discriminate against any producer with respect to price,
quantity, quality, or other terms of purchase, acquisition, or
other handling of agricultural products because of his membership
in or contract with an association of producers; or"
"(c) To coerce or intimidate any producer to enter into,
maintain, breach, cancel, or terminate a membership agreement or
marketing contract with an association of producers or a contract
with a handler; or"
"(d) To pay or loan money, give any thing of value, or offer any
other inducement or reward to a producer for refusing to or ceasing
to belong to an association of producers; or"
"(e) To make false reports about the finances, management, or
activities of associations of producers or handlers; or"
"(f) To conspire, combine, agree, or arrange with any other
person to do, or aid or abet the doing of, any act made unlawful by
this chapter."
[
Footnote 5]
Section 290.707 provides in pertinent part:
"An association shall be accredited upon determination by the
board that the association meets all of the following:"
"
* * * *"
"(c) The association has marketing and bargaining contracts for
the current or next marketing period with more than 50% of the
producers of an agricultural commodity who are in the bargaining
unit and these contracts cover more than 50% of the quantity of
that commodity produced by producers in the bargaining unit. The
board may determine the quantity produced by the bargaining unit
using information on production in prior marketing periods, current
market information, and projections on production during the
current market periods. The board shall exclude from that quantity
any quantity of the agricultural commodity contracted by producers
with producer owned and controlled processing cooperatives and any
quantity produced by handlers. An association whose main purpose is
bargaining but which processes a surplus into a form which is not
the subject of bargaining is not a processing cooperative. The
contracts with members shall specify the agricultural commodity and
that the members have appointed the association as their exclusive
agent in negotiations with handlers for prices and other terms of
trade with respect to the sale and marketing of the agricultural
commodity and obligate them to dispose of their production or
holdings of the agricultural commodity through or at the direction
of the association."
The Michigan Act also provides a mechanism whereby producers of
various commodities are divided into "bargaining units" so that,
once an association is accredited, it represents essentially 100%
of the production of the commodity produced by its members. Thus,
§ 290.706 provides:
"(1) The board shall determine whether a proposed bargaining
unit is appropriate. This determination shall be made upon the
petition of an association representing not less than 10% of the
producers of the commodity eligible for membership in the proposed
bargaining unit as defined by the association. An association with
an overlapping definition of bargaining unit may, upon the
presentation of a petition by not less than 10% of the producers
eligible for membership in the overlapping bargaining unit, contest
the proposed bargaining unit. . . ."
"(2) In making its determination, the board shall define as
appropriate the largest bargaining unit in terms of the quantity of
the agricultural commodity produced, the definition of the
agricultural commodity, geographic area covered and number of
producers included as is consistent with the following
criteria:"
"(a) The community of interest of the producers included;"
"(b) The potential serious conflicts of interests among members
of the proposed unit;"
"(c) The effect of exclusions on the capacity of the association
to effectively bargain for the bargaining unit as defined;"
"(d) The kinds, types and subtypes of products to be classed
together as agricultural commodity for which the bargaining unit is
proposed;"
"(e) Whether the producers eligible for membership in the
proposed bargaining unit meet the definition of 'producer' for the
agricultural commodity involved;"
"(f) The wishes of the producers;"
"(g) The pattern of past marketing of the commodity."
[
Footnote 6]
Although the Michigan Act does not explicitly prohibit a
producer represented by an accredited association from negotiating
directly with a processor, it does prohibit the processor from
negotiating with such a producer. § 290.704(1)(h). The
Michigan Act thus effectively eliminates direct dealing between a
producer that is represented by an accredited association and a
processor.
[
Footnote 7]
The bargaining unit for which MACMA is accredited includes all
Michigan farmers who produced a certain minimum quantity of
asparagus during a defined marketing period.
[
Footnote 8]
The Michigan Canners & Freezers Association, Inc., is an
association of fruit and vegetable processors whose members process
asparagus. Dukesherer Farms, Inc. is a corporation engaged in
asparagus farming. And Ferris Pierson is an individual engaged in
asparagus farming.
[
Footnote 9]
Appellee MACMA argues that this provision eliminates the
preemptive effect the AFPA might otherwise have on the Michigan
Act, despite the fact that the Michigan Act was enacted after the
enactment of the AFPA. Brief for Appellee MACMA 8-14. MACMA
contends that, at the time of the passage of the AFPA, California's
Agricultural Prorate Act, upheld by this Court in
Parker v.
Brown, 317 U. S. 341
(1943), contained provisions "similar" to the provisions of the
Michigan Act. Even if we were to accept MACMA's interpretation of
§ 2305(d), however, this argument is unpersuasive. The
California Prorate Act bears no relevant similarity to the Michigan
Act. The California Act provides for the orderly marketing of
certain commodities by imposing marketing plans that restrict the
quantity of a commodity that farmers may produce, regulate the flow
of commodities to market, and establish grade and quality
requirements. The basic goal of the California Act, as identified
in
Parker v. Brown, is to minimize the adverse effects of
a market surplus. 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
355.
[
Footnote 10]
Appellants argue that the AFPA accords processors the right to
deal with producers individually, and that the Michigan Act
deprives processors of that right. This conflict, they contend,
provides an additional basis upon which to decide that the Michigan
Act is preempted. In light of our disposition of appellants'
primary claim, however, we need not address that question.
[
Footnote 11]
See, e.g., Agricultural Producers Marketing Act:
Hearings on S. 109 before a Subcommittee of the Senate Committee on
Agriculture and Forestry, 90th Cong., 1st Sess., 144 (statement of
Earl W. Kintner, National Tax Equality Association), 173-183
(statement of Paul L. Phillips) (1967) (hereinafter cited as 1967
Senate Hearings).
[
Footnote 12]
See, e.g., Discrimination Against Members of Farmer
Cooperatives: Hearings on S. 109 before the Subcommittee of the
Senate Committee on Agriculture and Forestry, 89th Cong., 2d Sess.,
135 (1966) (statement of A. Starke Taylor Jr., Independent Cotton
Industries Association) (hereinafter cited as 1966 Senate
Hearings); 1967 Senate Hearings, at 110, 113-114 (statement of W.
W. Holding III, American Cotton Shippers Association), 151
(statement of Earl W. Kintner, National Tax Equality Association),
196 (statement of Irving Isaacson, Maine Poultry Associates).
[
Footnote 13]
See, e.g., 1966 Senate Hearings at 187 (statement of
Harry L. Graham, National Grange).
[
Footnote 14]
See, e.g., 1967 Senate Hearings at 69 (statement of
Edward Brown Williams, National Association of Frozen Food
Packers), 91-92 (statement of G. Ted Cameron, National Broiler
Council).
[
Footnote 15]
1967 Senate Hearings at 10-11 (statement of Sen. Williams).
See, e.g., 1966 Senate Hearings at 146 (statement of
Donald G. Smith, Texas Independent Ginners Association), 196-197
(statement of Edward Dunkelberger, National Canners
Association).
In addition, much of the testimony focused on the case of
vertically integrated producers' associations that process their
members' products. As several witnesses explained, because such
associations compete in the processing market, the one-sided
orientation of the bill provided these associations with an unfair
competitive advantage over other processors. Indeed, many of these
processors feared that the bill would, for that reason, drive them
entirely out of business.
See, e.g., id. at 135 (statement
of A. Starke Taylor, Jr., Independent Cotton Industries
Association), 138140 (statement of Paul L. Courtney, National
Association of Wholesalers); 1967 Senate Hearings, at 122-123
(statement of Herman Eubank, Texas Independent Ginners
Association). The Michigan Act, however, effectively excludes
vertically integrated associations from the accreditation process.
In calculating the representational strength of an association
seeking accreditation, the Michigan Act provides that
"[t]he board shall exclude from [the total quantity of a
commodity produced] any quantity of the agricultural commodity
contracted by producers with producer owned and controlled
processing cooperatives and any quantity produced by handlers."
§ 290.707(c).
See n 5,
supra.
[
Footnote 16]
§ 4 Section 4(d), which addresses the provision of
"inducements and rewards" to producers, applies only to those
seeking to have a producer refuse or cease to belong to an
association, an approach that was ultimately adopted in the AFPA.
See 7 U.S.C. § 2303(d). The Senate Report explained
that
"[t]he association of producers should not be prohibited from
offering inducements to producers to belong to an association,
since it is quite proper for an association to pursue vigorously
the voluntary organization of farmers in its attempt to secure a
better bargaining position for farmers."
S.Rep. No. 474, 90th Cong., 1st Sess., 6 (1967).
[
Footnote 17]
Agricultural Fair Trade Practices: Hearings on S. 109 before the
House Committee on Agriculture, 90th Cong,. 1st Sess., 66-67
(statement of Harry L. Graham, National Grange), 79 (statement of
Tony T. Dechant, National Farmers Union), 89-90 (statement of
Robert N. Hampton, National Council of Farmer Cooperatives),
109-110 (statement of Ralph B. Bunje, California Canning Peach
Association) (1967).
[
Footnote 18]
The Senate bill had stated that
"the marketing and bargaining position of individual farmers
will be adversely affected unless they are free to join together
or not join together in cooperative organizations as
authorized by law."
113 Cong.Rec. 21410 (1967) (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 19]
Indeed, throughout the legislative debate on S. 109, an interest
in protecting the producer from coercion by either processors or
producers was frequently expressed. For example, Representative
Poage, Chairman of the House Committee on Agriculture, stated:
"In the House, we felt it could be just as offensive to have
discrimination against producers because of their lack of
membership as to have discrimination against them because of their
membership. It was basically that we wanted to make this bill apply
in both directions -- to make of it a two-way street -- to make of
it a protector of the right of the producer to determine for
himself whether he cared to or did not care to become a member of a
cooperative."
". . . We made of the original legislation a two-way proposal
which would actually assure to any producer the right to belong or
not to belong to a cooperative."
114 Cong.Rec. 7451 (1968). Similarly, Representative May
stated:
"There was no one on the committee, either in testimony or in
our discussion, that in any way wanted to confuse anyone about the
farmer's right not to join an organization when he did not wish to
do so. Actually that is spelled out in the prohibited practices . .
. of the bill . . . when we say: to coerce any producer in the
exercise of his right to join and belong to or to refrain from
joining or belonging to an association of producers."
Id. at 7450. And Representative Latta stated that
"the farmers of this Nation will still have the right . . . to
say to an association, 'I do not want to join your association, and
you cannot force me into it.'"
Ibid.
[
Footnote 20]
Appellees attempt to draw an analogy between this case and cases
covered by the "state action exemption" to the federal antitrust
laws. Brief for Appellee Agricultural Marketing and Bargaining
Board 26-36, Brief for Appellee MACMA 22-31. The state action
exemption, however, is based on an interpretation of the antitrust
laws, and therefore has no direct application here.
See, e.g.,
Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341
(1943). Moreover, the Michigan Act does not provide for the type of
active state involvement in the market that the state action
exemption would require even if it were applicable.
[
Footnote 21]
Because the Michigan Act is cast in permissive, rather than
mandatory, terms -- an association
may, but need not, act
as exclusive bargaining representative -- this is not a case in
which it is impossible for an individual to comply with both state
and federal law.
See Florida Lime & Avocado Growers, Inc.
v. Paul, 373 U. S. 132,
373 U. S.
142-143 (1963).