To bring destabilizing competition among dairy farmers under
control, the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 (Act)
authorizes the Secretary of Agriculture (Secretary) to issue milk
market orders setting the minimum prices that handlers (those who
process dairy products) must pay to producers (dairy farmers) for
their milk products. Pursuant to this authority, the Secretary
issued market orders under which handlers are required to pay for
"reconstituted milk" (milk manufactured by mixing milk powder with
water) the minimum price for Class II milk (raw milk used to
produce such products as dry milk powder), rather than the higher
price covering Class I milk (raw milk processed and bottled for
fluid consumption). The orders assume that handlers will use the
reconstituted milk to manufacture surplus milk products, but for
any portion of reconstituted milk not so used, handlers must make a
"compensatory payment" equal to the difference between Class I and
Class II milk product prices. Respondents -- three individual
consumers of fluid dairy products, a handler regulated by the
market orders, and a nonprofit organization -- brought suit in
Federal District Court, contending that the compensatory payment
requirement makes reconstituted milk uneconomical for handlers to
process. The District Court held,
inter alia, that the
consumers had no standing to challenge the orders. The Court of
Appeals disagreed, holding that the consumers had suffered
injury-in-fact, their injuries were redressable, and they were
within the zone of interests protected by the Act, and that the
Act's structure and purposes did not reveal the type of "clear and
convincing evidence of congressional intent needed to overcome the
presumption in favor of judicial review."
Held: The individual consumers may not obtain judicial
review of the milk market orders in question. Pp.
467 U. S.
345-353.
(a) It is clear from the structure of the Act that Congress
intended that judicial review of market orders ordinarily be
confined to suits by handlers in accordance with the provisions of
the Act expressly entitling them to such review in a federal
district court after exhausting their administrative remedies.
Allowing consumers to sue the Secretary would severely disrupt the
Act's complex and delicate administrative scheme. Pp.
467 U. S.
345-348.
Page 467 U. S. 341
(b) The presumption favoring judicial review of administrative
action does not control in cases such as this one, where the
congressional intent to preclude consumer suits is "fairly
discernible" in the detail of the legislative scheme. The Act
contemplates a cooperative venture among the Secretary, producers,
and handlers; consumer participation is not provided for or desired
under that scheme.
Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.
S. 288, distinguished. Pp.
467 U. S.
348-352.
225 U.S.App.D.C. 387, 698 F.2d 1239, reversed.
O'CONNOR, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which all
other Members joined, except STEVENS, J., who took no part in the
decision of the case.
JUSTICE O'CONNOR delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case presents the question whether ultimate consumers of
dairy products may obtain judicial review of milk market orders
issued by the Secretary of Agriculture (Secretary) under the
authority of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937
(Act), ch. 296, 50 Stat. 246, as amended, 7 U.S.C. § 601
et seq. We conclude that consumers may not obtain judicial
review of such orders.
I
A
In the early 1900's, dairy farmers engaged in intense
competition in the production of fluid milk products.
See Zuber
v. Allen, 396 U. S. 168,
396 U. S.
172-176 (1969). To bring this destabilizing competition
under control, the 1937 Act authorizes the Secretary to issue milk
market orders setting the minimum prices that handlers (those who
process dairy products)
Page 467 U. S. 342
must pay to producers (dairy farmers) for their milk products. 7
U.S.C. § 608c. The "essential purpose [of this milk market
order scheme is] to raise producer prices," S.Rep. No. 1011, 74th
Cong., 1st Sess., 3 (1935), and thereby to ensure that the benefits
and burdens of the milk market are fairly and proportionately
shared by all dairy farmers.
See Nebba v. New York,
291 U. S. 502,
291 U. S.
517-518 (1934).
Under the scheme established by Congress, the Secretary must
conduct an appropriate rulemaking proceeding before issuing a milk
market order. The public must be notified of these proceedings and
provided an opportunity for public hearing and comment.
See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(3). An order may be issued only
if the evidence adduced at the hearing shows "that [it] will tend
to effectuate the declared policy of this chapter with respect to
such commodity." 7 U.S.C. § 608c(4). Moreover, before any
market order may become effective, it must be approved by the
handlers of at least 50% of the volume of milk covered by the
proposed order and at least two-thirds of the affected dairy
producers in the region. 7 U.S.C. §§ 608c(8),
608c(5)(B)(i). If the handlers withhold their consent, the
Secretary may nevertheless impose the order. But the Secretary's
power to do so is conditioned upon at least two-thirds of the
producers consenting to its promulgation and upon his making an
administrative determination that the order is "the only practical
means of advancing the interests of the producers." 7 U.S.C. §
608c(9)(B).
The Secretary currently has some 45 milk market orders in
effect.
See 7 CFR pts. 1001-1139 (1984). Each order covers
a different region of the country, and collectively they cover
most, though not all, of the United States. The orders divide dairy
products into separately priced classes based on the uses to which
raw milk is put.
See 44 Fed.Reg. 65990 (1979). Raw milk
that is processed and bottled for fluid consumption is termed
"Class I" milk. Raw milk that is used to
Page 467 U. S. 343
produce milk products such as butter, cheese, or dry milk powder
is termed "Class II" milk. [
Footnote 1]
For a variety of economic reasons, fluid milk products would
command a higher price than surplus milk products in a perfectly
functioning market. Accordingly, the Secretary's milk market orders
require handlers to pay a higher order price for Class I products
than for Class II products. To discourage destabilizing competition
among producers for the more desirable fluid milk sales, the orders
also require handlers to submit their payments for either class of
milk to a regional pool. Administrators of these regional pools are
then charged with distributing to dairy farmers a weighted average
price for each milk product they have produced, irrespective of its
use.
See 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5)(B)(ii).
In particular, the Secretary has regulated the price of
"reconstituted milk" -- that is, milk manufactured by mixing milk
powder with water -- since 1964.
See 29 Fed.Reg. 9002,
9010 (1964);
see also 34 Fed.Reg. 16548, 16551 (1969). The
Secretary's orders assume that handlers will use reconstituted milk
to manufacture surplus milk products. Handlers are therefore
required to pay only the lower Class II minimum price.
See
44 Fed.Reg. 65989, 65990 (1979). However, handlers are required to
make a "compensatory payment" on any portion of the reconstituted
milk that their records show has not been used to manufacture
surplus milk products. 7 CFR §§ 1012.44(a)(5)(i),
1012.60(e) (1984). The compensatory payment is equal to the
difference between the Class I and Class II milk product prices.
Handlers make these payments to the regional pool, from which
moneys are then distributed to producers of fresh fluid milk in the
region where the reconstituted milk was manufactured and sold.
§ 1012.71(a)(1).
Page 467 U. S. 344
B
In December, 1980, respondents brought suit in District Court,
contending that the compensatory payment requirement makes
reconstituted milk uneconomical for handlers to process. [
Footnote 2] Respondents, as plaintiffs
in the District Court, included three individual consumers of fluid
dairy products, a handler regulated by the market orders, and a
nonprofit organization. The District Court concluded that the
consumers and the nonprofit organization did not have standing to
challenge the market orders. In addition, it found that Congress
had intended by the Act to preclude such persons from obtaining
judicial review. The District Court dismissed the milk handler's
complaint because he had failed to exhaust his administrative
remedies.
The Court of Appeals affirmed in part and reversed in part, and
remanded the case for a decision on the merits. 225 U.S.App.D.C.
387, 698 F.2d 1239 (1983). The Court of Appeals agreed that the
milk handler and the nonprofit organization had been properly
dismissed by the District Court. But the court concluded that the
individual consumers had standing: they had suffered an
injury-in-fact,
Page 467 U. S. 345
their injuries were redressable, and they were within the zone
of interests arguably protected by the Act. The Court also
concluded that the statutory structure and purposes of the Act did
not reveal
"the type of clear and convincing evidence of congressional
intent needed to overcome the presumption in favor of judicial
review."
Id. at 400, and n. 75, 698 F.2d at 1252, and n. 75. The
Court of Appeals expressly refused to follow the decision of the
Ninth Circuit in
Rasmussen v. Hardin, 461 F.2d 595,
cert. denied sub nom. Rasmussen v. Butz, 409 U.S. 933
(1972), which had held consumers precluded by statute from seeking
judicial review.
We granted certiorari to resolve the conflict in the Circuits.
464 U.S. 991 (1983). We now reverse the judgment of the Court of
Appeals in this case.
II
Respondents filed this suit under the Administrative Procedure
Act (APA), 5 U.S.C. § 701
et seq. The APA confers a
general cause of action upon persons "adversely affected or
aggrieved by agency action within the meaning of a relevant
statute," 5 U.S.C. § 702, but withdraws that cause of action
to the extent the relevant statute "preclude[s] judicial review," 5
U.S.C. § 701(a)(1). Whether and to what extent a particular
statute precludes judicial review is determined not only from its
express language, but also from the structure of the statutory
scheme, its objectives, its legislative history, and the nature of
the administrative action involved.
See Southern R. Co. v.
Seaboard Allied Mining Corp., 442 U.
S. 444,
442 U. S.
454-463 (1979);
Morris v. Gressette,
432 U. S. 491,
432 U. S.
499-507 (1977);
see generally Note, Statutory
Preclusion of Judicial Review Under the Administrative Procedure
Act, 1976 Duke L.J. 431, 442-449. Therefore, we must examine this
statutory scheme
"to determine whether Congress precluded all judicial review,
and, if not, whether Congress nevertheless foreclosed review to the
class to which the [respondents]
Page 467 U. S. 346
belon[g]."
Barlow v. Collins, 397 U. S. 159,
397 U. S. 173
(1970) (opinion of BRENNAN, J.,);
see also Data Processing
Service v. Camp, 397 U. S. 150,
397 U. S. 156
(1970).
It is clear that Congress did not intend to strip the judiciary
of all authority to review the Secretary's milk market orders. The
Act's predecessor, the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933, 48
Stat. 31, contained no provision relating to administrative or
judicial review. In 1935, however, Congress added a mechanism by
which dairy handlers could obtain review of the Secretary's market
orders. 49 Stat. 760. That mechanism was retained in the 1937
legislation, and remains in the Act as § 608c(15) today.
Section 608c(15) requires handlers first to exhaust the
administrative remedies made available by the Secretary. 7 U.S.C.
§ 608c(15)(A);
see 7 CFR §§ 900.50-900.71
(1984). After these formal administrative remedies have been
exhausted, handlers may obtain judicial review of the Secretary's
ruling in the federal district court in any district "in which
[they are] inhabitant[s], or ha[ve their] principal place[s] of
business." 7 U.S.C. § 608c(15)(B). These provisions for
handler-initiated review make evident Congress' desire that some
persons be able to obtain judicial review of the Secretary's market
orders.
The remainder of the statutory scheme, however, makes equally
clear Congress' intention to limit the classes entitled to
participate in the development of market orders. The Act
contemplates a cooperative venture among the Secretary, handlers,
and producers the principal purposes of which are to raise the
price of agricultural products and to establish an orderly system
for marketing them. Handlers and producers -- but not consumers --
are entitled to participate in the adoption and retention of market
orders. 7 U.S.C. §§ 608c(8), (9), (16)(B). The Act
provides for agreements among the Secretary, producers, and
handlers, 7 U.S.C. § 608(2), for hearings among them,
§§ 608(5), 608c(3), and for votes by producers and
handlers, §§ 608c(8)(A), (9)(B), (12),
Page 467 U. S. 347
608c(19). Nowhere in the Act, however, is there an express
provision for participation by consumers in any proceeding. In a
complex scheme of this type, the omission of such a provision is
sufficient reason to believe that Congress intended to foreclose
consumer participation in the regulatory process.
See Switchmen
v. National Mediation Board, 320 U. S. 297
305-306 (1943);
cf. United States v. Erika, Inc.,
456 U. S. 201,
456 U. S. 208
(1982).
To be sure, the general purpose sections of the Act allude to
general consumer interests.
See 7 U.S.C. §§
602(2), (4). But the preclusion issue does not only turn on whether
the interests of a particular class like consumers are implicated.
Rather, the preclusion issue turns ultimately on whether Congress
intended for that class to be relied upon to challenge agency
disregard of the law.
See Barlow v. Collins, supra, at
397 U. S. 167.
The structure of this Act indicates that Congress intended only
producers and handlers, and not consumers, to ensure that the
statutory objectives would be realized.
Respondents would have us believe that, while Congress
unequivocally directed handlers first to complain to the Secretary
that the prices set by milk market orders are too high, it was
nevertheless the legislative judgment that the same challenge, if
advanced by consumers, does not require initial administrative
scrutiny. There is no basis for attributing to Congress the intent
to draw such a distinction. The regulation of agricultural products
is a complex, technical undertaking. Congress channeled disputes
concerning marketing orders to the Secretary in the first instance,
because it believed that only he has the expertise necessary to
illuminate and resolve questions about them. Had Congress intended
to allow consumers to attack provisions of marketing orders, it
surely would have required them to pursue the administrative
remedies provided in § 608c(15)(A) as well. The restriction of
the administrative remedy to handlers strongly suggests that
Congress intended a similar restriction of judicial review of
market orders.
Page 467 U. S. 348
Allowing consumers to sue the Secretary would severely disrupt
this complex and delicate administrative scheme. It would provide
handlers with a convenient device for evading the statutory
requirement that they first exhaust their administrative remedies.
A handler may also be a consumer and, as such, could sue in that
capacity. Alternatively, a handler would need only to find a
consumer who is willing to join in or initiate an action in the
district court. The consumer or consumer-handler could then raise
precisely the same exceptions that the handler must raise
administratively. Consumers or consumer-handlers could seek
injunctions against the operation of market orders that "impede,
hinder, or delay" enforcement actions, even though such injunctions
are expressly prohibited in proceedings properly instituted under 7
U.S.C. § 608c(15). Suits of this type would effectively
nullify Congress' intent to establish an
"equitable and expeditious procedure for testing the validity of
orders, without hampering the Government's power to enforce
compliance with their terms."
S.Rep. No. 1011, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., 14 (1935);
see also
United States v. Ruzicka, 329 U. S. 287,
329 U. S.
293-294, and n. 3 (1946). For these reasons, we think it
clear that Congress intended that judicial review of market orders
issued under the Act ordinarily be confined to suits brought by
handlers in accordance with 7 U.S.C. § 608c(15).
III
The Court of Appeals viewed the preclusion issue from a somewhat
different perspective. First, it recited the presumption in favor
of judicial review of administrative action that this Court usually
employs. It then noted that the Act has been interpreted to
authorize producer challenges to the administration of market order
settlement funds,
see Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.
S. 288 (1944), and that no legislative history or
statutory language directly and specifically supported the
preclusion of consumer suits. In these circumstances, the Court of
Appeals reasoned that the Act could not fairly be
Page 467 U. S. 349
interpreted to overcome the presumption favoring judicial review
and to leave consumers without a judicial remedy.
See 225
U.S.App.D.C. at 400, and n. 75, 698 F.2d at 1252, and n. 75. We
disagree with the Court of Appeals' analysis.
The presumption favoring judicial review of administrative
action is just that -- a presumption. This presumption, like all
presumptions used in interpreting statutes, may be overcome by
specific language or specific legislative history that is a
reliable indicator of congressional intent.
See, e.g., Southern
R. Co. v. Seaboard Allied Milling Corp., 442 U.S. at
442 U. S.
454-463;
Schilling v. Rogers, 363 U.
S. 666,
363 U. S.
670-677 (1960). The congressional intent necessary to
overcome the presumption may also be inferred from contemporaneous
judicial construction barring review and the congressional
acquiescence in it,
see, e.g., Ludecke v. Watkins,
335 U. S. 160
(1948), or from the collective import of legislative and judicial
history behind a particular statute,
see, e.g., Heikkila v.
Barber, 345 U. S. 229
(1953). More important for purposes of this case, the presumption
favoring judicial review of administrative action may be overcome
by inferences of intent drawn from the statutory scheme as a whole.
See, e.g., Morris v. Gressette, 432 U.
S. 491 (1977);
Switchmen v. National Mediation
Board, 320 U. S. 297
(1943). In particular, at least when a statute provides a detailed
mechanism for judicial consideration of particular issues at the
behest of particular persons, judicial review of those issues at
the behest of other persons may be found to be impliedly precluded.
See Barlow v. Collins, 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 168,
and n. 2, 175, and n. 9 (opinion of BRENNAN, J.);
Switchmen v.
National Mediation Board, supra, at
320 U. S.
300-301;
cf. Associated General Contractors of
California, Inc. v. Carpenters, 459 U.
S. 519,
459 U. S. 542
(1983).
A case that best illustrates the relevance of a statute's
structure to the Court's preclusion analysis is
Morris v.
Gressette, supra. In that case, the Court held that the
Attorney General's failure to object to a change in voting
Page 467 U. S. 350
procedures was an unreviewable administrative determination
under the Voting Rights Act of 1965. Neither the Voting Rights Act
nor its legislative history said anything about judicial review.
Nevertheless, the
Morris Court concluded that the
"nature of the [statutory] remedy . . . strongly suggests that
Congress did not intend the Attorney General's actions under that
provision to be subject to judicial review."
Id. at
432 U. S. 501.
The Court reasoned that Congress had intended the approval
procedure to be expeditious, and that reviewability would
unnecessarily extend the period the State must wait for effecting
its change.
Id. at
432 U. S.
504-505. The Court also found relevant the existence of
other remedies to ensure the realization of the Voting Rights Act's
objectives.
Id. at
432 U. S.
505-507. In these circumstances, even though proof of
specific congressional intent was not "clear and convincing" in the
traditional evidentiary sense, the Court unremarkably found the
intent to preclude judicial review implicit in the statutory
scheme.
In this case, the Court of Appeals did not take the balanced
approach to statutory construction reflected in the
Morris
opinion. Rather, it recited this Court's oft-quoted statement
that
"only upon a showing of 'clear and convincing evidence' of a
contrary legislative intent should the courts restrict access to
judicial review."
Abbott Laboratories v. Gardner, 387 U.
S. 136,
387 U. S. 141
(1967).
See also Southern R. Co. v. Seaboard Allied Milling
Corp., supra, at
442 U. S. 462;
Dunlop v. Bachowski, 421 U. S. 560,
421 U. S. 568
(1975). According to the Court of Appeals, the "clear and
convincing evidence" standard required it to find unambiguous
proof, in the traditional evidentiary sense, of a congressional
intent to preclude judicial review at the consumers' behest. Since
direct statutory language or legislative history on this issue
could not be found, the Court of Appeals found the presumption
favoring judicial review to be controlling.
This Court has, however, never applied the "clear and convincing
evidence" standard in the strict evidentiary sense the
Page 467 U. S. 351
Court of Appeals thought necessary in this case. Rather, the
Court has found the standard met, and the presumption favoring
judicial review overcome, whenever the congressional intent to
preclude judicial review is "fairly discernible in the statutory
scheme."
Data Processing Service v. Camp, 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 157.
In the context of preclusion analysis, the "clear and convincing
evidence" standard is not a rigid evidentiary test, but a useful
reminder to courts that, where substantial doubt about the
congressional intent exists, the general presumption favoring
judicial review of administrative action is controlling. That
presumption does not control in cases such as this one, however,
since the congressional intent to preclude judicial review is
"fairly discernible" in the detail of the legislative scheme.
Congress simply did not intend for consumers to be relied upon to
challenge agency disregard of the law.
It is true, as the Court of Appeals also noted, that this Court
determined, in
Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.
S. 288 (1944), that dairy producers could challenge
certain administrative actions even though the Act did not
expressly provide them a right to judicial review. The producers
challenged certain deductions the Secretary had made from the
"producer settlement fund" established in connection with the milk
market order in effect at the time. "[T]he challenged deduction[s]
reduce[d]
pro tanto the amount actually received by the
producers for their milk."
Id. at
321 U. S. 302.
These deductions injured what the producers alleged were "definite
personal rights" that were "not possessed by the people generally,"
id. at
321 U. S. 304,
321 U. S. 309,
and gave the producers standing to object to the administration of
the settlement fund.
See id. at
321 U. S. 306.
Though the producers' standing could not, by itself, ensure
judicial review of the Secretary's action at their behest,
see
ibid., the statutory scheme as a whole, the Court concluded,
implicitly authorized producers' suits concerning settlement fund
administration.
See id. at
321 U. S.
309-310. "[H]andlers [could not] question the use of the
fund, because handlers had
Page 467 U. S. 352
no financial interest in the fund or its use."
Id. at
321 U. S. 308.
Thus, there was "no forum" in which this aspect of the Secretary's
actions could or would be challenged. Judicial review of the
producers' complaint was therefore necessary to ensure achievement
of the Act's most fundamental objectives -- to-wit, the protection
of the producers of milk and milk products.
By contrast, preclusion of consumer suits will not threaten
realization of the fundamental objectives of the statute. Handlers
have interests similar to those of consumers. Handlers, like
consumers, are interested in obtaining reliable supplies of milk at
the cheapest possible prices.
See Zuber v. Allen, 396 U.S.
at
396 U. S. 190.
Handlers can therefore be expected to challenge unlawful agency
action, and to ensure that the statute's objectives will not be
frustrated. [
Footnote 3]
Indeed, as noted above, consumer suits might themselves frustrate
achievement of the statutory purposes. The Act contemplates a
cooperative venture among the Secretary, producers, and handlers;
consumer participation is not provided for or desired under the
complex scheme enacted by Congress. Consumer suits would undermine
the congressional preference for administrative remedies, and
provide a mechanism for disrupting administration of the
congressional scheme. Thus, preclusion of consumer suits is
perfectly consistent with the Court's contrary conclusion
concerning producer challenges in
Stark v. Wickard and its
analogous conclusion concerning voter challenges in
Morris v.
Gressette.
IV
The structure of this Act implies that Congress intended to
preclude consumer challenges to the Secretary's market orders.
Preclusion of such suits does not pose any threat to
Page 467 U. S. 353
realization of the statutory objectives; it means only that
those objectives must be realized through the specific remedies
provided by Congress and at the behest of the parties directly
affected by the statutory scheme. [
Footnote 4] Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of
Appeals is reversed.
It is so ordered.
JUSTICE STEVENS took no part in the decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
Under many orders, milk is divided into three classes. For
purposes of this case, however, all milk other than milk used for
fluid purposes is referred to as Class II milk.
[
Footnote 2]
Prior to filing suit, respondents petitioned the Secretary to
hold a rulemaking hearing to amend the market orders so that
reconstituted milk would no longer be subject to the compensatory
payment rule.
See 44 Fed.Reg. 65989 (1979). The Secretary
published a Notice of Request and asked for comments.
Ibid. Subsequently, the Secretary published a preliminary
impact analysis of the proposal and invited comments.
See
45 Fed.Reg. 75956 (1980). In April 1981, after respondents had
filed suit in the District Court, the Secretary determined not to
hold a rulemaking hearing, because respondents' proposal would not
further the purposes of the Act.
See App. 57-63. The
portion of respondents' complaint challenging the Secretary's
inaction on their rulemaking request was held moot by the Court of
Appeals. 225 U.S.App.D.C. 387, 403, and n. 93, 698 F.2d 1239, 1255,
and n. 93 (1983). Respondents did not cross-petition for certiorari
review of this issue, and we therefore have no occasion to consider
it.
[
Footnote 3]
Whether handlers would pass on to consumers any savings they
might secure through a successful challenge to the market order
provisions is irrelevant. Consumers' interest in market orders is
limited to lowering the prices charged to handlers in the hope that
consumers will then reap some benefit at the retail level.
[
Footnote 4]
The conclusion that Congress intended to preclude consumers from
seeking judicial review of the Secretary's market orders avoids any
pronouncement on the merits of respondents' substantive claims.
Since congressional preclusion of judicial review is in effect
jurisdictional, we need not address the standing issues decided by
the Court of Appeals in this case.
See National Railroad
Passenger Corp. v. National Assn. of Railroad Passengers,
414 U. S. 453,
414 U. S. 456
(1974);
see also id. at
414 U. S. 465,
and n. 13.