Title I of the Natural Gas Policy Act of 1978 (NGPA) defines
eight categories of natural gas production, specifies the maximum
lawful price that may be charged for "first sales" in each
category, and prescribes rules for increasing "first sale" prices
each month and passing them on to downstream purchasers. Section
2(21) of the Act defines "first sale" as including, as a general
rule, "any sale" of natural gas to any interstate or intrastate
pipeline or to any local distribution company, but as not including
such sales by the enumerated sellers or any affiliate thereof,
unless the sale "is attributable to" volumes of natural gas
produced by such sellers or any affiliate thereof. In 1979, the
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC) issued Order No. 58,
promulgating regulations implementing the statutory definition of
"first sale." Independent producers and pipeline affiliates were
assigned a "first sale" for all natural gas transferred to
interstate pipelines. But pipelines themselves were not
automatically assigned a "first sale" for their production. A
pipeline enjoys a "first sale" for gas sold at a wellhead; for gas
sold downstream that consists solely of its own production; for
downstream sales of commingled independent-producer and
pipeline-producer gas, as long as it dedicated an equivalent volume
of its production to that purchaser by contract; and for downstream
sales of commingled gas in an otherwise unregulated intrastate
market. But if a pipeline sells commingled gas in an interstate
market without dedicating a particular volume of its production to
that particular sale, it does not enjoy "first sale" treatment. In
1980, the FERC issued Order No. 98, promulgating regulations under
the Natural Gas Act (NGA) providing that the NGPA's "first sale"
pricing should apply to all pipeline production on leases acquired
after October 8, 1969, and from wells drilled after January 1,
1973, regardless of when the underlying lease had been acquired.
All other pipeline production would be priced for ratemaking
purposes just as it had before the
Page 463 U. S. 320
NGPA was enacted. Respondents (interstate pipeline companies
that transport natural gas from the wellhead to their customers)
petitioned the Court of Appeals for review of both FERC orders,
contending that Order No. 58 was based on a misreading of the NGPA
and that, in Order No. 98, the FERC had acted arbitrarily in
refusing to authorize NGPA pricing for all pipeline production. The
Court of Appeals held that the NGPA was intended to provide the
same incentives to pipeline production as to independent
production, that there were no practical obstacles to treating the
transfer of gas from a pipeline's production division to its
transportation division as a first sale, and that the FERC's
reading of the NGPA was inconsistent with Congress' goal. The Court
held Order No. 58 invalid, and therefore did not review Order No.
98 separately.
Held: The FERC's exclusion of pipeline production from
the NGPA's pricing scheme is inconsistent with the statutory
mandate, and would frustrate the regulatory policy that Congress
sought to implement; the FERC, however, has discretion in deciding
which transfer -- intracorporate or downstream -- should receive
the "first sale" treatment. Pp.
463 U. S.
325-343.
(a) As respondents contend, the FERC has the authority to treat
as a first sale either the intracorporate transfer of natural gas
from a pipeline-owned production system to the pipeline or the
downstream transfer of commingled gas from the pipeline to a
customer, in which case respondents would be able to include an
NGPA rate for production among their costs of service, just as they
do when they acquire natural gas from independent producers. The
downstream transfer plainly satisfies § 2(21)'s "general rule"
definition, and the legislative history clearly demonstrates that
this statute was not intended to prohibit the FERC from deeming the
intracorporate transfer a "sale." The statutory exception to the
"general rule" definition does not diminish the FERC's authority to
treat an intracorporate or downstream transfer as a first sale. Pp.
463 U. S.
325-327.
(b) The purposes of the NGPA to preserve the FERC's authority
under the NGA to regulate natural gas sales from pipelines to their
customers and to supplant the FERC's authority to establish rates
for the wholesale market, the market consisting of so-called "first
sales" of natural gas, the legislative history, and the overall
structure of the NGPA, all show that Congress intended pipeline
production to receive "first sale" pricing, and did not intend the
FERC to be able to exclude pipeline production from the NGPA's
coverage completely. Pp.
463 U. S.
327-338.
(c) The FERC's argument that it would be wrong to assign
intracorporate transfers a "first sale" price "automatically,"
because not even independent producers receive such treatment,
refutes a position that no one advocates, since it is agreed that
such a transfer should not "automatically" receive the NGPA ceiling
price. There is no merit to the
Page 463 U. S. 321
FERC's argument that giving "first sale" treatment to downstream
sales would result in the application of "first sale" maximum
lawful prices to all mixed volume retail sales by interstate and
intrastate pipelines and local distributors, thereby supplanting
traditional state regulatory authority over the costs of intrastate
pipeline transportation service. Nor is there any merit to the
FERC's argument that pipeline producers would enjoy an unintended
windfall if they receive "first sale" pricing. Pp.
463 U. S.
339-342.
664 F.2d 530, vacated and remanded.
STEVENS, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BURGER, C.J., and POWELL, REHNQUIST, and O'CONNOR, JJ., joined.
WHITE, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which BRENNAN, MARSHALL,
and BLACKMUN, JJ., joined,
post, p.
463 U. S.
348.
Page 463 U. S. 322
JUSTICE STEVENS delivered the opinion of the Court.
By enacting the Natural Gas Policy Act of 1978 (NGPA), 92 Stat.
3350, 15 U.S.C. § 3301
et seq. (1976 ed., Supp. V),
Congress comprehensively and dramatically changed the method of
pricing natural gas produced in the United States. In Title I of
that Act, Congress defined eight categories of natural gas
production, specified the maximum lawful price that may be charged
for "first sales" in each category, and prescribed rules for
increasing first sale prices each month and passing them on to
downstream purchasers. The question presented in these cases is
whether the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission has the authority
to exclude from this scheme most of the gas produced from wells
owned by interstate pipelines and to prescribe a different method
of setting prices for that gas. The answer is provided by the Act's
definition of a "first sale" and by the scheme of the entire
NGPA.
Respondents are interstate pipeline companies that transport
natural gas from the wellhead to consumers. They purchase most of
their gas from independent producers. In addition, they acquire a
significant amount of gas from wells that they own themselves or
that their affiliates own. Gas from all three sources is usually
commingled in the pipelines before being delivered to their
customers downstream. Thus, at the time of delivery, it is often
impossible to identify the producer of a particular volume of
gas.
On November 14, 1979, the Commission [
Footnote 1] entered Order No. 58, promulgating final
regulations to implement the definition
Page 463 U. S. 323
of "first sale" under the NGPA. [
Footnote 2] The first category of producers -- independent
producers -- is assigned a "first sale" for all natural gas
transferred to interstate pipelines. The second category of
producers -- pipeline affiliates that are not themselves pipelines
or distributors -- is also assigned a "first sale" for all natural
gas transferred to interstate pipelines, unless the Commission
specifically rules to the contrary. In contrast, the third category
of producers -- pipelines themselves -- is not automatically
assigned a "first sale" for its production. A pipeline does enjoy a
"first sale" for any gas it sells at the wellhead. Similarly, it
enjoys a "first sale" for any gas it sells downstream that consists
solely of its own production. It also enjoys a "first sale" for any
downstream sales of commingled independent producer and pipeline
producer gas, as long as it dedicated an equivalent volume of its
own production to that purchaser by contract. Finally, it enjoys a
"first sale" for any downstream sales of commingled gas in an
otherwise unregulated intrastate market. However, if a pipeline
producer sells commingled gas in an interstate market without
having dedicated a particular volume of its production to that
particular sale, it does not enjoy first sale treatment.
On August 4, 1980, the Commission entered Order No. 98.
[
Footnote 3] The Commission
noted that its construction of the NGPA in Order No. 58 had left
most interstate pipeline production outside the Act's coverage,
since so much of it is commingled with purchased gas. It announced
that such production and its downstream sale remain subject to the
Commission's regulatory jurisdiction under the Natural Gas Act
(NGA), 52 Stat. 821, 15 U.S.C. § 717
et seq. (1976
ed. and Supp. V). In order to provide pipelines with an incentive
to compete with independent producers in acquiring new leases and
drilling
Page 463 U. S. 324
new wells, the Commission decided that pipeline production
should receive treatment under the NGA that is comparable to the
treatment given independent production under the NGPA. It therefore
promulgated regulations under the NGA providing that the NGPA's
first sale pricing should apply to all pipeline production on
leases acquired after October 8, 1969, and to all pipeline
production from wells drilled after January 1, 1973, regardless of
when the underlying lease had been acquired. All other pipeline
production would be priced for ratemaking purposes just as it had
been before the NGPA was enacted. [
Footnote 4]
Respondents petitioned for review of both Commission orders,
contending that Order No. 58 was based on a misreading of the NGPA
and that, in Order No. 98, the Commission had acted arbitrarily in
refusing to authorize NGPA pricing for all pipeline production. The
Court of Appeals held that the NGPA was intended to provide the
same incentives to pipeline production as to independent
production, that there were no practical obstacles to treating the
transfer of gas from a pipeline's production division to its
transportation division as a first sale, and that the Commission's
reading of the NGPA was inconsistent with the goals of Congress.
664 F.2d 530 (CA5 1981). It held Order No. 58 invalid, and
therefore did not review Order No. 98 separately.
We granted petitions for certiorari filed by the Commission and
by state regulatory Commissions, which contend that the Court of
Appeals' holding will provide the pipelines with windfall profits
that Congress did not intend. 459 U.S. 820 (1982). In explaining
why we are in general agreement with the Court of Appeals, we first
review the statutory definition of "first sale," then consider the
history and structure of the NGPA, and finally examine the specific
arguments on behalf of the Commission's position.
Page 463 U. S. 325
I
The respondents seek first sale treatment for one of two
transfers of natural gas: the
intracorporate transfer from
a pipeline-owned production system to the pipeline, or the
downstream transfer of commingled gas from the pipeline to
a customer. If either transfer is treated as a first sale,
respondents would be able to include an NGPA rate for production
among their costs of service, just as they do when they acquire
natural gas from independent producers. They contend initially that
Congress has authorized the Commission, in the exercise of its
sound discretion, to treat either transfer as a first sale. They
contend further that Congress has not authorized the Commission to
reject both possibilities.
The definition of a "first sale" is found in § 2(21) of the
NGPA. 92 Stat. 3355, 15 U.S.C. § 3301(21) (1976 ed., Supp. V).
It takes the form of a general rule, qualified by an exclusion. The
general rule sweeps broadly, providing:
"(A) GENERAL RULE. -- The term 'first sale' means any sale of
any volume of natural gas -- "
"(i) to any interstate pipeline or intrastate pipeline;"
"(ii) to any local distribution company;"
"(iii) to any person for use by such person;"
"(iv) which precedes any sale described in clauses (i), (ii), or
(iii);
and"
"(v) which precedes or follows any sale described in clauses
(i), (ii), (iii), or (iv) and is defined by the Commission as a
first sale in order to prevent circumvention of any maximum lawful
price established under this Act."
92 Stat. 3355, 15 U.S.C. § 3301(21)(A) (1976 ed., Supp. V)
(emphasis added). Under the terms of the general rule, a transfer
that falls within any one of its five clauses is presumptively a
first sale. [
Footnote 5] This
means that there can be many first sales of a single
Page 463 U. S. 326
volume of gas between the well and the pipeline's customers.
[
Footnote 6] In this case, the
downstream transfer plainly satisfies the general rule. The only
obstacle to including the intracorporate transfer within the
general rule is the question whether it may properly be deemed a
"sale." [
Footnote 7] That
obstacle, however, is insubstantial. The legislative history
clearly demonstrates that the statute was not intended to prohibit
the Commission from deeming it a sale; the Conference Committee
Report provides that the Commission may "establish rules applicable
to intracorporate transactions under the first sale definition."
H.R.Conf.Rep. No. 95-1752, p. 116 (1978). Thus, if the first sale
definition consisted only of the general rule, the Commission would
plainly be authorized to treat either transfer as a first sale.
The exception to the general rule provides:
"(B) CERTAIN SALES NOT INCLUDED. -- Clauses (i), (ii), (iii), or
(iv) of subparagraph (A) shall not include the sale of any volume
of natural gas by any interstate pipeline, intrastate pipeline, or
local distribution company, or any affiliate thereof, unless such
sale is attributable to volumes of natural gas produced by such
interstate pipeline, intrastate pipeline, or local distribution
company, or any affiliate thereof."
92 Stat. 3355, 15 U.S.C. § 3301(21)(B) (1976 ed., Supp. V).
This language does not diminish the Commission's authority to treat
the intracorporate transfer as a first sale. Whether it affects the
Commission's authority to treat the downstream
Page 463 U. S. 327
transfer as a first sale depends on the meaning of the words
"attributable to." Although the Commission interpreted them as
meaning "
solely attributable to," it would be at least as
consistent with the ordinary understanding of the words to
interpret them as meaning "
measurably attributable to."
[
Footnote 8] Furthermore, it
would have been fully consistent with the spirit of the exemption
if the Commission had adopted the latter interpretation and had
given "first sale" treatment to a percentage of the downstream sale
-- the percentage that pipeline production forms of all the gas in
the pipeline.
Thus, we agree with the respondents that the Commission has the
authority to treat either the intracorporate transfer or the
downstream transfer as a first sale. That, however, does not
dispose of this litigation. For there is a substantial difference
between holding that the Commission had the authority to treat
either transfer as a first sale and holding that the Commission was
required so to treat one or the other.
II
In order to determine whether the Commission was obligated to
treat either the intracorporate transfer or the relevant portion of
the downstream transfer as a first sale, it is necessary to examine
the purposes of the NGPA. Those purposes are rooted in the history
of federal natural gas regulation before 1978 and in the overall
structure of the statute.
A
Between 1938 and 1978, the Commission regulated sales of natural
gas in interstate commerce pursuant to the NGA. The NGA was enacted
in response to reports suggesting that the monopoly power of
interstate pipelines was harming consumer welfare. [
Footnote 9] Initially, the Commission
construed the
Page 463 U. S. 328
NGA to require only regulation of gas sales at the downstream
end of interstate pipelines.
E.g., Natural Gas Pipeline
Co., 2 F.P.C. 218 (1940). It authorized rates that were "just
and reasonable" within the meaning of § 4(a) of the NGA, 52
Stat. 822, 15 U.S.C. § 717c(a), by examining whatever costs
the pipeline had incurred in acquiring and transporting the gas to
the consumer. If the pipeline itself or a pipeline affiliate had
produced the gas, the actual expenses historically associated with
production and gathering were included in the rate base to the
extent proper and reasonable.
See FPC v. Hope Natural Gas
Co., 320 U. S. 591,
320 U. S.
614-615, and n. 25 (1944);
Colorado Interstate Gas
Co. v. FPC, 324 U. S. 581,
324 U. S.
604-606 (1945). However, if the pipeline had purchased
the gas from an independent producer, the Commission did not take
jurisdiction over the producer to evaluate the reasonableness of
its rates; it only considered the broad issue of whether, from the
pipeline's perspective, the purchase price was "collusive or
otherwise improperly excessive."
Phillips Petroleum Co.,
10 F.P.C. 246, 280 (1951).
In 1954, this Court rejected the Commission's approach. We held
that the NGA required the Commission to take jurisdiction over
independent gas producers and to scrutinize the reasonableness of
the rates they charged to interstate pipelines.
Phillips
Petroleum Co. v. Wisconsin, 347 U. S. 672
(1954). We interpreted the purpose of the NGA as being
"to give the Commission jurisdiction over the rates of all
wholesales of natural gas in interstate commerce, whether by a
pipeline company or not and whether occurring before, during, or
after transmission by an interstate pipeline company,"
id. at
347 U. S. 682,
and concluded that, for regulatory purposes, there was no essential
difference between the gas a pipeline obtains from independent
producers and the gas it obtains from its own affiliates,
id. at
347 U. S.
685.
The problems of regulating the natural gas industry grew
steadily between
Phillips and the passage of the NGPA. At
first, the Commission attempted to follow the
Phillips
mandate
Page 463 U. S. 329
by applying the same regulatory technique it had always applied
to pipeline-produced natural gas. It calculated just and reasonable
rates for each company -- whether pipeline, pipeline affiliate, or
independent producer -- by studying the costs of production that
had historically been incurred by that particular company. But that
so-called "cost of service" approach quickly proved impractical.
See Atlantic Refining Co. v. Public Service Comm'n of New
York, 360 U. S. 378,
360 U. S. 389
(1959). Whereas there were relatively few interstate pipelines, the
vast number of natural gas producers threatened to overwhelm the
Commission's administrative capacity.
See Permian Basin Area
Rate Cases, 390 U. S. 747,
390 U. S. 757,
and n. 13 (1968).
The Commission then shifted to an "area rate" approach.
See Statement of General Policy 611, 24 F.P.C. 818 (1960).
Instead of establishing individual rates for each company on the
basis of its own costs of service, it established a single rate
schedule for each producing region. Two elements of the area rate
method bear mention. First, the Commission continued to base its
computations on historical costs, rather than on projections of
future costs. And second, it established two maximum rates for each
area: a "new gas" rate for gas produced independently of oil from
wells drilled after a given date, and an "old gas" rate for all
other gas. The two-tiered structure, which priced gas on the basis
of its "vintage," rested on the theory that, for already-flowing
gas,
"price could not serve as an incentive, and . . . any price
above average historical costs, plus an appropriate return, would
merely confer windfalls."
Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, supra, at
390 U. S.
797.
The Permian Basin area rate proceeding governed only production
by independent producers. The Commission undertook a separate
proceeding to consider whether it remained appropriate to treat
pipelines and pipeline affiliates on a company-by-company basis. On
October 7, 1969, 17 months after this Court approved the use of
area rates, the
Page 463 U. S. 330
Commission concluded that, for leases acquired from that date
on, pipeline gas should receive pricing on a "parity" basis; such
gas would be eligible for the same area rate as independently
produced gas of the same vintage.
Pipeline Production Area Rate
Proceeding (Phase I), 42 F.P.C. 738, 752 (Opinion No. 568).
Gas produced from already-acquired leases would continue to be
priced on the old single-company cost-of-service method "in order
to expedite the proceedings and to avoid complications and
evidentiary problems."
Id. at 753. Significantly, gas
produced by pipeline affiliates would be treated in precisely the
same manner as gas produced by the pipelines themselves.
In the early 1970's, it became apparent that the regulatory
structure was not working. The Commission recognized that the
historical-cost-based, two-tiered rate scheme had led to serious
production shortages.
See Southern Louisiana Area Rate
Proceeding, 46 F.P.C. 86, 110-111 (1971).
See
generally Breyer & MacAvoy, The Natural Gas Shortage and
the Regulation of Natural Gas Producers, 86 Harv.L.Rev. 941,
965-979 (1973). Therefore, the Commission modified its practices,
shifting from an "area rate" to a "national rate" approach.
National Rates for Natural Gas, 51 F.P.C. 2212 (1974)
(Opinion No. 699). The national rate became effective for all wells
drilled after January 1, 1973, and applied equally to production by
independent producers, pipelines, and pipeline affiliates. A few
months later, the Commission responded further by shifting from a
pure historical-cost-based to an incentive-price-based approach,
National Rates for Natural Gas, 52 F.P.C. 1604, 1615-1618
(1974) (Opinion No. 699-H), and by temporarily abandoning the
practice of vintaging,
id. at 1636. [
Footnote 10]
These measures did not prove sufficient. The interstate rates
remained substantially below the unregulated prices available for
intrastate sales, and the interstate supply remained
Page 463 U. S. 331
inadequate. Throughout 1977 and 1978, the 95th Congress studied
the situation. During the closing hours of the Second Session, it
enacted a package of five Acts, one of which was the NGPA. The NGPA
is designed to preserve the Commission's authority under the NGA to
regulate natural gas sales from pipelines to their customers;
however, it is designed to supplant the Commission's authority to
establish rates for the wholesale market, the market consisting of
so-called "first sales" of natural gas.
B
The NGPA was the product of a Conference Committee's careful
reconciliation of two strong, but divergent, responses to the
natural gas shortage.
The House bill had proposed "a single uniform price policy for
natural gas produced in the United States." H.R.Rep. No. 95-496,
pt. 4, p. 96 (1977). A key element of that policy had been the
establishment of a statutory incentive price structure that would
simultaneously promote production and reduce the regulatory
burden:
"[O]ther controversial aspects of current Federal regulation are
not perpetuated. The uncertainties associated with lengthy judicial
review of Federal Power Commission wellhead price determinations
are avoided by use of a statutorily established maximum lawful
price. Regulatory lag and other problems associated with reliance
upon historical costs to establish just and reasonable wellhead
prices are similarly avoided. Vintaging of new natural gas prices
would also terminate."
Id. at 97. The Senate bill, passed on the floor, would
have maintained Natural Gas Act regulation for all gas sold or
delivered in interstate commerce before January 1, 1977, and
steadily cut back on Commission jurisdiction so that all natural
gas sold after January 1, 1982, would have been completely
deregulated.
Page 463 U. S. 332
S. 2104, 95th Cong., 1st Sess., 123 Cong.Rec. 32306 (1977).
The Conference Committee's compromise has been justly described
as "a comprehensive statute to govern future natural gas
regulation." Note, Legislative History of the Natural Gas Policy
Act, 59 Texas L.Rev. 101, 116 (1980). In Title I, it establishes an
exhaustive categorization of natural gas production, and sets forth
a methodology for calculating an appropriate ceiling price within
each category: Section 102 covers "new natural gas and certain
natural gas produced from the Outer Continental Shelf"; § 103
covers "new, onshore production wells"; § 104 covers "natural
gas committed or dedicated to interstate commerce on the day before
the date of the enactment of [the NGPA]"; § 105 covers "sales
under existing intrastate contracts"; § 106 covers "sales
under rollover contracts"; § 107 covers "high-cost natural
gas"; § 108 covers "stripper well natural gas"; [
Footnote 11] and § 109
Page 463 U. S. 333
is a catchall, covering "any natural gas which is not covered by
any maximum lawful price under any other section of this subtitle."
92 Stat. 3358-3368, 15 U.S.C. §§ 3312-3319 (1976 ed.,
Supp. V).
In each category of gas, the statute explicitly establishes an
incentive pricing scheme that is wholly divorced from the
traditional historical-cost methods applied by the Commission in
implementing the NGA. The price is established either in terms of a
dollar figure per million Btu's, or in terms of a previously
existing price, and is inflated over time according to a statutory
formula.
See § 101. For three categories of gas, the
statute recognizes that the ceiling may be too
low, and
authorizes the Commission to raise it whenever traditional NGA
principles would dictate a higher price.
See §§
104, 106, and 109. The Commission is also given a somewhat
ambiguous mandate to authorize increases above the ceiling for the
other five categories.
See § 110(a)(2). In none of
the eight categories, however, is the Commission given authority to
require a rate lower than the statutory ceiling.
Several features of this comprehensive scheme bear directly on
the question whether Congress intended the Commission to be able to
exclude pipeline production from its coverage completely. To begin
with, the categories are defined on the basis of the type of well
and the past uses of its gas, not on the basis of who owns the
well. And since it is drafted in a manner that is designed to be
exhaustive, all natural gas production falls within at least one of
the categories.
Page 463 U. S. 334
Moreover, the statute replaces the Commission's authority to fix
rates of return to gas producers according to what is "just and
reasonable" with a precise schedule of price ceilings. Section
601(b)(1)(A) provides that,
"[s]ubject to paragraph (4), for purposes of sections 4 and 5 of
the Natural Gas Act, any amount paid in any first sale of natural
gas shall be deemed to be just and reasonable if . . . such amount
does not exceed the applicable maximum lawful price established
under Title I of this Act."
92 Stat. 3410, 15 U.S.C. § 3431(b)(1)(A) (1976 ed., Supp.
V). The new statutory rates are intended to provide investors with
adequate incentives to develop new sources of supply. As the
Commission itself recognized in Order No. 98:
"The Congressional decision to reorder the economic regulation
of natural gas prices to provide a uniform system of statutorily
prescribed price incentives was based on a . . . belief that such
incentives are necessary to secure continued development and
additional production of natural gas."
45 Fed.Reg. 53093 (1980). [
Footnote 12]
The statute evinces careful thought about the extent to which
producers of "old gas" -- gas already dedicated to interstate
commerce before passage of the NGPA -- would be able to enjoy
incentive pricing. Section 104 of the statute directly incorporates
part of the "vintaging" pattern that previously existed under the
NGA. [
Footnote 13] Thus,
most old gas continues
Page 463 U. S. 335
to receive the price it received under the NGA, increased over
time in accordance with the inflation formula found in § 101.
However, § 101(b)(5) of the Act specifies that, if a volume of
gas fits into more than one category, "the provision which could
result in the highest price shall be applicable." 92 Stat. 3357, 15
U.S.C. § 3311(b)(5) (1976 ed., Supp. V). Thus, old gas that
would be subject to the old NGA vintaging rules may be entitled to
a higher rate if it falls within one or more of the other Title I
categories, in particular § 107 (high-cost natural gas) and
§ 108 (stripper well gas). Whether or not the old NGA rates
were in fact sufficient to stimulate some production from those
categories, Congress concluded
Page 463 U. S. 336
that the Nation's energy needs justified the higher, statutory
rates. [
Footnote 14]
In addition, the costs of providing these production incentives
are plainly to be shouldered by downstream consumers, not by
pipelines. Title II of the Act establishes a complicated structure,
to be implemented by the Commission, for determining which
consumers are to face the bulk of the price increases. 92 Stat.
3371-3381, 15 U.S.C. §§ 3341-3348 (1976 ed., Supp. V).
That Title is designed to allocate the burden among categories of
consumers; it is not designed to diminish in any way the incentive
for producers or to force pipelines to bear any part of that
burden. As the Conference Report makes plain:
"The conference agreement guarantees that interstate pipelines
may pass through costs of natural gas purchases if the price of the
purchased natural gas does not exceed the ceiling price levels
established under the legislation. . . . This recovery must be
consistent with the incremental pricing provisions of Title II;
however, Title II is structured to permit recovery of all costs
which a pipeline is entitled to recover."
H.R.Conf.Rep. No. 95-1752, p. 124 (1978).
Given such a comprehensive scheme, we conclude that Congress
would have clearly identified, either in the statutory language or
in the legislative history, any significant source of production
that was intended to be excluded. For the usefulness of natural gas
does not depend on who produces it, and there is no reason to
believe that any one group of producers is less likely to respond
to incentives than any
Page 463 U. S. 337
other. [
Footnote 15] Yet
nowhere in the NGPA do we find any expression of a desire to
exclude pipeline production.
Indeed, three statutory provisions combine to give a clear
signal that the statute was intended to include such production.
Section 203, which defines the acquisition costs subject to
passthrough requirements, specifically states:
"Interstate pipeline production. -- For purposes of this
section, in the case of any natural gas produced by any interstate
pipeline or any affiliate of such pipeline, the first sale
acquisition cost of such natural gas shall be determined in
accordance with rules prescribed by the Commission."
92 Stat. 3375, 15 U.S.C. § 3343(b)(2) (1976 ed., Supp. V).
This provision expressly mentions pipeline production as a matter
subject to NGPA jurisdiction. Perhaps even more significantly, it
makes clear that Congress intended to continue a policy that had
been in effect since 1938: a policy of drawing no distinction
between wells owned by a pipeline itself and those owned by an
affiliate. That point is equally apparent from the exemption half
of the definition of "first sale" in Title I. That provision
requires first sale treatment of a sale that is "attributable to
volumes of natural gas produced by such interstate pipeline . . .
or any affiliate thereof." § 2(21)(B) (emphasis
added).
See supra at
463 U. S. 326.
Given that
Page 463 U. S. 338
pipelines are to be treated in the same manner as pipeline
affiliates, and given that pipeline affiliates are explicitly
covered under the NGPA,
see § 601(b)(1)(E), it
follows directly that pipeline production is covered. [
Footnote 16]
In sum, the Court of Appeals correctly concluded that Congress
intended pipeline production to receive first sale pricing. The
Commission had no authority to ignore that intention absent a
persuasive justification for doing so. [
Footnote 17]
Page 463 U. S. 339
III
Of course, "the interpretation of an agency charged with the
administration of a statute is entitled to substantial deference."
Blum v. Bacon, 457 U. S. 132,
457 U. S. 141
(1982). It is therefore incumbent upon us to consider carefully the
Commission's arguments that Congress implicitly intended to exempt
pipeline production from an otherwise comprehensive regulatory
scheme. We think it important to address three of the Commission's
arguments explicitly: one is aimed at the propriety of giving first
sale treatment to the intracorporate transfer, one at the propriety
of giving first sale treatment to the downstream sale, and the
third at the propriety of any form of first sale treatment for
pipeline production.
The Commission suggests that it would be wrong to assign the
intracorporate transfer a first sale price "automatically," because
not even independent producers receive such automatic treatment. It
emphasizes the Conference Committee's admonition that "maximum
lawful prices are ceiling prices only. In no case may a seller
receive a higher price than his contract permits." H.R.Conf.Rep.
No. 95-1752, p. 74 (1978). Since arm's length contractual
bargaining may reduce the price for independent producers, the
Commission suggests that
"[i]t would be anomalous in the extreme to conclude that
Congress nonetheless meant to permit pipeline producers to qualify
automatically for full NGPA prices by virtue of intracorporate
transfers that are not covered by contracts."
Brief for Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 31-32.
Page 463 U. S. 340
This argument refutes a position that no one advocates. We agree
completely that the intracorporate transfer should not
"automatically" receive the NGPA ceiling price. Congress
undoubtedly intended pipeline producers to be treated in the same
manner as pipeline affiliate producers. The latter group is
subjected to market control, through the application of §
601(b)(1)(E), which provides that,
"in the case of any first sale between any interstate pipeline
and any affiliate of such pipeline, any amount paid in any first
sale shall be deemed to be just and reasonable if, in addition to
satisfying the requirements of [Title I], such amount does not
exceed the amount paid in comparable first sales between persons
not affiliated with such interstate pipeline."
92 Stat. 3410, 15 U.S.C. § 331(b)(1)(E) (1976 ed., Supp.
V).
The Commission also argues that adoption of the downstream sale
theory would result in the application of first sale maximum lawful
prices to all mixed volume retail sales by interstate pipelines,
intrastate pipelines, and local distribution companies, thereby
supplanting traditional state regulatory authority over the costs
of intrastate pipeline transportation service. [
Footnote 18] We find this argument to be
exaggerated. The Commission concedes that a downstream sale of
pipeline production in another State is a "first sale" if that
production has not been commingled with purchased gas. It allows
the pipeline to include an appropriate NGPA rate (reflecting the
costs of producing the gas) in the overall downstream price (which
also reflects transportation and administrative costs). Applying
the same principle to commingled gas [
Footnote 19] would in
Page 463 U. S. 341
no way trench upon state regulatory authority. The narrow issue
posed -- the proper cost to be assigned a pipeline's production
efforts -- is no different from the issue posed when a cost must be
assigned to a pipeline's purchase of gas from its producing
affiliate. And it effects no special change in the relationship
between federal and state regulatory jurisdiction. [
Footnote 20]
Finally, the Commission argues that pipeline producers would
enjoy an unintended windfall if they received first sale pricing.
This windfall argument is obviously limited to only one particular
category of gas: gas already dedicated to interstate commerce on
the date of enactment of the NGPA, and subject to cost-of-service
pricing. For under the Commission's own Order No. 98, all other
pipeline production receives the same price it would receive if
treated as a first sale under the NGPA. The Commission argues,
however, that the residual cost-of-service production should be
excluded because the pipelines were guaranteed a risk-free return
on their initial investments in those wells. To allow the pipelines
to receive NGPA pricing on future production from those wells would
allegedly be "an irrational result with . . . unfair consequences
for consumers." [
Footnote
21]
This argument glosses over the full meaning of Congress'
determination that old gas qualifies for "first sale"
treatment.
Page 463 U. S. 342
Under § 104, such gas retains its former NGA price, subject
to increases over time for inflation. Section 104 provides
absolutely no opportunity for a windfall. To be sure, old gas could
receive a rate higher than the inflated NGA rate if it falls within
one of the special categories of gas whose production Congress saw
a need to stimulate. Seizing on that fact, the Commission suggests
in a footnote to its brief that much of the gas at issue here would
be "stripper well" production, subject to the incentive prices of
§ 108. It argues that, at least for that category of gas, a
windfall would exist, since the Commission believes that
cost-of-service treatment would provide just as strong an incentive
as the § 108 price. [
Footnote 22]
That belief, however, was plainly not shared by Congress. For
the statute explicitly grants the § 108 rate to pipeline
affiliates -- entities that were previously subject to the same
cost-of-service treatment as the pipelines themselves. Moreover,
the Commission does not pursue its windfall argument to its logical
conclusion. For it agrees that a pipeline is entitled to the NGPA
price for any production it sells at the wellhead. Yet by denying
the pipeline NGPA treatment if it transports the gas to another
State, the Commission only creates an incentive for wellhead sales,
in flat contradiction to one of the NGPA's motivating purposes --
to eliminate the dual market that distinguished between interstate
and intrastate sales of natural gas. [
Footnote 23]
The Commission's position is contrary to the history, structure,
and basic philosophy of the NGPA. Like the Court of Appeals, we
conclude that its exclusion of pipeline production is "inconsistent
with the statutory mandate, [and would] frustrate the policy that
Congress sought to implement."
FEC
Page 463 U. S. 343
v. Democratic Senatorial Campaign Committee,
454 U. S. 27,
454 U. S. 32
(1981). Unlike the Court of Appeals, however, we believe Congress
intended to give the Commission discretion in deciding whether
first sale treatment should be provided at the intracorporate
transfer or at the downstream transfer. [
Footnote 24] The cases should be remanded to the
Commission so that it may may make that choice. The judgment of the
Court of Appeals is vacated, and the cases are remanded for further
proceedings consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
* Together with No. 81-1958,
Arizona Electric Power
Cooperative, Inc. v. Mid-Louisiana Gas Co. et al.; No.
81-2042,
Michigan v. Mid-Louisiana Gas Co. et al.; and No.
82-19,
Federal Energy Regulatory Commission v. Mid-Louisiana
Gas Co. et al., also on certiorari to the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
In this opinion, we use the term "Commission" to refer to both
the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission and its predecessor, the
Federal Power Commission.
[
Footnote 2]
See 44 Fed.Reg. 66577 (1979). The final regulations are
found at 18 CFR § 270.203 (1983).
[
Footnote 3]
See 45 Fed.Reg. 53091 (1980).
[
Footnote 4]
The final regulations are found at 18 CFR §§ 2.66,
154.42 (1983).
[
Footnote 5]
The text of clause (v) makes it plain that the italicized word
"and" at the end of clause (iv) was intended to be "or."
[
Footnote 6]
One commentator has suggested that
"where the producer sells to a gatherer, who in turn sells to a
processor who eventually sells to a pipeline, there may be
three first sales of the same gas."
Hollis, Title I and Related Producer Matters Under the NGPA, in
2 Energy Law Serv., Monograph 4D, § 4D.02 (H. Green ed.1981).
See also 18 CFR § 270.202 (1983) (setting forth rules
governing resales).
[
Footnote 7]
As defined in the statute,
"[t]he term 'sale' means any sale, exchange, or other transfer
for value."
92 Stat. 3355, 15 U.S.C. § 3301(20) (1976 ed., Supp.
V).
[
Footnote 8]
The latter meaning would be clear beyond debate if, instead of
the word "unless," Congress had used the phrase, "except to the
extent that."
[
Footnote 9]
See Federal Trade Comm'n, Utility Corporations, S. Doc.
No. 92, 70th Cong. , 1st Sess. (1928). The reports are mentioned
explicitly in § 1(a) of the NGA.
[
Footnote 10]
In 1976, the Commission decided to return to vintaging.
See
National Rates for Natural Gas, 56 F.P.C. 509 (1976) (Opinion
No. 770).
[
Footnote 11]
Stripper well natural gas is defined as follows:
"(1) General Rule. -- Except as provided in paragraph (2), the
term 'stripper well natural gas' means natural gas determined . . .
to be nonassociated natural gas produced during any month from a
well if -- "
"(A) during the preceding 90-day production period, such well
produced nonassociated natural gas at a rate which did not exceed
an average of 60 Mcf per production day during such period;
and"
"(B) during such period such well produced at its maximum
efficient rate of flow, determined in accordance with recognized
conservation practices designed to maximize the ultimate recovery
of natural gas."
"(2) Production in excess of 60 Mcf -- The Commission shall, by
rule, provide that, if nonassociated natural gas produced from a
well which previously qualified as a stripper well under paragraph
(1) exceeds an average of 60 Mcf per production day during any
90-day production period, such natural gas may continue to qualify
as stripper well natural gas if the increase in nonassociated
natural gas produced from such well was the result of the
application of recognized enhanced recovery techniques."
"(3) Definitions. -- For purposes of this subsection -- "
"(A) Production Day. -- The term 'production day' means -- "
"(i) any day during which natural gas is produced; and"
"(ii) any day during which natural gas is not produced if
production during such day is prohibited by a requirement of State
law or a conservation practice recognized or approved by the State
agency having regulatory jurisdiction over the production of
natural gas."
"(B) 90-day Production Period. -- The term '90-day production
period' means any period of 90 consecutive calendar days excluding
any day during which natural gas is not produced for reasons other
than voluntary action of any person with the right to control
production of natural gas from such well."
"(C) Nonassociated Natural Gas. -- The term 'nonassociated
natural gas' means natural gas which is not produced in association
with crude oil."
92 Stat. 3367-3368, 15 U.S.C. § 3318(b) (1976 ed., Supp.
V).
[
Footnote 12]
The dissent suggests that, because § 104 of the NGPA
preserves the old NGA price for certain first sales of "old gas,"
the NGPA "did not intend to eliminate all vestiges of the
Commission's earlier pricing authority."
Post at
463 U. S.
348-349;
see also post at
463 U. S. 348,
n. 6. This suggestion confuses the choice of a benchmark
price with the choice of regulatory
authority.
For some (but not all) old gas, the NGA price is preserved as an
initial ceiling price. But over time, that price moves according to
a statutory formula, rather than through the exercise of Commission
regulatory authority.
See §§ 101,
601(b)(1)(A).
[
Footnote 13]
Section 104 provides:
"(a) APPLICATION. -- In the case of natural gas committed or
dedicated to interstate commerce on the day before the date of the
enactment of this Act and for which a just and reasonable rate
under the Natural Gas Act was in effect on such date for the first
sale of such natural gas, the maximum lawful price computed under
subsection (b) shall apply to any first sale of such natural gas
delivered during any month."
"(b) MAXIMUM LAWFUL PRICE. -- "
"(1) GENERAL RULE. -- The maximum lawful price under this
section for any month shall be the higher of -- "
"(A)(i) the just and reasonable rate, per million Btu's,
established by the Commission which was (or would have been)
applicable to the first sale of such natural gas on April 20, 1977,
in the case of April 1977; and"
"(ii) in the case of any month thereafter, the maximum lawful
price, per million Btu's, prescribed under this subparagraph for
the preceding month multiplied by the monthly equivalent of the
annual inflation adjustment factor applicable for such month,
or"
"(B) any just and reasonable rate which was established by the
Commission after April 27, 1977, and before the date of the
enactment of this Act and which is applicable to such natural
gas."
"(2) Ceiling Prices May Be Increased If Just and Reasonable. --
The Commission may, by rule or order, prescribe a maximum lawful
ceiling price, applicable to any first sale of any natural gas (or
category thereof, as determined by the Commission) otherwise
subject to the preceding provisions of this section, if such price
is -- "
"(A) higher than the maximum lawful price which would otherwise
be applicable under such provisions; and"
"(B) just and reasonable within the meaning of the Natural Gas
Act."
92 Stat. 3362-3363, 15 U.S.C. § 3314 (1976 ed., Supp.
V).
[
Footnote 14]
For some categories of gas, the NGPA ceiling prices are an
intermediate step on the path from a fully regulated industry to a
deregulated industry. Sections 121 and 122 of the NGPA provide a
mechanism for the ultimate decontrol of a number of categories of
natural gas.
[
Footnote 15]
In Order No. 98, the Commission effectively conceded that the
goals of the NGPA apply just a directly to pipeline production as
to independent production:
"Having embarked under the NGA upon a course which would provide
price incentives for both pipeline and independent producer
production to encourage production of additional gas supplies, and
having been reaffirmed in this course by evidence of a similar
purpose in Congress' enactment of a pricing scheme in the NGPA
designed to encourage additional production, we believe that our
mandate of coordinating the NGPA and the NPA would best be
accomplished through a policy of pricing parity among independent
and pipeline producers."
46 Fed.Reg. 63093 (1980).
[
Footnote 16]
In its reply brief, the Commission argues that Congress intended
to distinguish between production by pipelines and production by
pipeline affiliates, on the theory that affiliate sales "are
governed by sales contracts" and are therefore "subject to the
realities of the marketplace." Reply Brief for Federal Energy
Regulatory Commission 4-6. Yet § 601(b)(1)(E) reveals that
Congress expressly refused to rely on affiliate sales contracts as
reflecting the realities of the marketplace.
See infra at
463 U. S. 340.
Congress brought affiliate production within the scope of the NGPA,
fully aware that it could not rely on arm's length bargaining
between affiliates to keep prices low.
The dissent declares that
"there is nothing in the legislative hearings, Reports, or
debates which expresses any congressional dissatisfaction with the
existing pricing of pipeline production or which suggests that the
Commission's pricing of the oldest and lowest cost pipeline
production on a cost-of-service basis . . . inhibited optimum
production efforts by the pipelines."
Post at
463 U. S.
347-348;
see also post at
463 U. S.
350-351 ("the very fact that NGPA prices are not
necessary to spur natural gas production by the pipeline companies
-- as they are for independent producers -- is a sufficient basis
upon which to uphold the Commission's interpretation"). The
expression and suggestion are indeed present in both the statute,
§ 601(b)(1)(E), and the Conference Report, H.R.Conf.Rep. No.
95-1752, p. 124 (1978) -- if cost-of-service pricing were adequate,
Congress simply would not have included pipeline affiliate
production within the scope of the NGPA.
[
Footnote 17]
The dissent suggests that we violate the principle of deference
to the agency's construction of the statute and improperly
substitute our own reading of the statutory scheme. It is
difficult, however, to argue convincingly that the Court is
disregarding the agency's expertise when the Commission itself
recognized in Order No. 98 that the policies of the NGPA would be
better served by granting NGPA incentive prices to
pipeline-produced gas. On this point, the Commission observed:
"Having embarked under the NGA upon a course which would provide
price incentives for both pipeline and independent producer
production to encourage production of additional gas supplies
and having been reaffirmed in this course by evidence of a
similar purpose in Congress' enactment of a pricing scheme in the
NGPA designed to encourage additional production, we believe
that our mandate of coordinating the NGPA and the NGA would best be
accomplished through a policy of pricing parity among independent
producers and pipeline producers."
46 Fed.Reg. 53093 (1980) (emphasis added).
See also
supra at
463 U. S.
334.
[
Footnote 18]
See Brief for Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
39.
[
Footnote 19]
We note that there do not appear to be any technical
difficulties in taking this approach, for the Commission itself has
established it as the approach it will follow in the absence of
other regulatory procedures. In Order No. 58, the Commission
invoked its "circumvention authority" under the NGPA to
provide:
"[T]he term 'first sale' includes any sale by a pipeline or
distributor which is comprised of production volumes from
identifiable wells, properties, or reservoirs if a portion of those
volumes is produced from wells, properties, or reservoirs owned by
such pipeline or distributor unless:"
"(1) The price at which such natural gas is sold is regulated
pursuant to the Natural Gas Act or is regulated by a State agency
empowered by State statute to establish, modify or set aside the
rate for such sale; or"
"(2) the Commission, on application, has determined not to treat
such sale as a first sale."
44 Fed.Reg. 66580 (1979).
[
Footnote 20]
As we recently noted in
Exxon Corp. v. Eagerton,
462 U. S. 176,
462 U. S. 186
(1983), § 105(a) of the NGPA extends federal authority to
control producer prices to the intrastate market, but, at the same
time, 602(a) allows the States to establish price ceilings for that
market that are lower than the federal ceiling.
[
Footnote 21]
Brief for Federal Energy Regulatory Commission 35.
[
Footnote 22]
Id. at 34, n. 35.
[
Footnote 23]
Similarly, the Commission admits that a pipeline is entitled to
the NGPA price for its own production as long as the downstream
contract shows that the gas was "dedicated" to it from the
beginning. We perceive no reason why the absence of a "dedication"
clause in the contract should turn a legitimate incentive into a
"windfall."
[
Footnote 24]
The dissent appears to misunderstand our holding today, since it
suggests that we do not hold unreasonable either of the
Commission's actions (with regard to the downstream transfer and
with regard to the intracorporate transfer). To summarize, we have
reached three conclusion in this litigation. (1) It would be
reasonable for the Commission not to give first sale treatment to
the intracorporate transfer,
as long as such treatment is given
to the downstream transfer. (2) Similarly, it would be
reasonable for the Commission not to give first sale treatment to
the downstream transfer,
as long as such treatment is given to
the intracorporate transfer. (3) Yet it was an unreasonable
construction of this comprehensive and exhaustive new legislation,
contrary to its structure, purposes, and history, for the
Commission to chop out virtually all pipeline production and to
relegate it to discretionary regulation under the NGA. Both the
dissent,
post at
463 U. S.
350-351, and the Court of Appeals, 664 F.2d 530, 536-538
(CA5 1981), offer reasons for preferring approach (1) to approach
(2). Those policy arguments are not totally without merit, but they
are not so persuasive that we would reverse the Commission if it
adopted approach (2),
see supra at
463 U. S.
340-341, and they of course provide no justification for
rejecting approach (1).
JUSTICE WHITE, with whom JUSTICE BRENNAN, JUSTICE MARSHALL, and
JUSTICE BLACKMUN join, dissenting.
Our task in these cases is not to interpret the Natural Gas
Policy Act (NGPA) as we think best, but rather the narrower inquiry
into whether the Commission's construction was sufficiently
reasonable to be accepted by a reviewing court.
FEC v.
Democratic Senatorial Campaign Committee, 454 U. S.
27,
454 U. S. 39
(1981);
Train v. Natural Resources
Defense
Page 463 U. S. 344
Council, Inc., 421 U. S. 60,
421 U. S. 75
(1975);
Zenith Radio Corp. v. United States, 437 U.
S. 443,
437 U. S. 450
(1978).
"To satisfy this standard it is not necessary for a court to
find that the agency's construction was the only reasonable one or
even the reading the court would have reached if the question
initially had arisen in a judicial proceeding."
FEC v. Democratic Senatorial Campaign Committee, supra,
at
454 U. S. 39;
Udall v. Tallman, 380 U. S. 1,
380 U. S. 16
(1965). The Court today rejects the agency's interpretation and
substitutes its own reading of this highly complex law. In doing
so, the Court imposes a construction not set forth in the statute
itself, not addressed in the legislative history, not selected by
the agency, and different even from that of the Court of Appeals.
Notwithstanding its novelty, perhaps the Court's construction that
pipeline production must be given "first sale" treatment either as
an intracorporate transfer or at the point of a downstream sale is
a reasonable interpretation of the Act. But its reasonability does
not establish the unreasonability of the Commission's
interpretation, and that, of course, is the question before us.
I
The relevant statutory provisions of the NGPA clearly will bear
the Commission's construction. Order No. 58 of the Commission, the
interpretive regulation at issue, delineates the circumstances
under which a sale of production by an interstate or intrastate
pipeline, local distribution company, or affiliate of one of these
entities, will be regulated as a first sale under the NGPA. Section
2(21)(B) of the NGPA provides that a sale of natural gas by a
pipeline or affiliate thereof is not a first sale unless the sale
is "attributable" to volumes of natural gas produced by such
pipeline, distributor, or affiliate thereof. [
Footnote 2/1] The Court's interpretation of the
provision was considered but rejected by the Commission.
Page 463 U. S. 345
"Although many comments have recommended otherwise, the
Commission will not interpret the term 'attributable' so as to
confer first sale treatment on pipeline sales if only a portion of
the gas involved was produced by the pipeline. The language of
section 2(21)(B) requires that a sale be 'attributable' to the
pipeline's
own production. We believe that Congress did
not intend for pipeline or distributor sales from general system
supply to qualify as 'first sales' merely because some portion of
that supply, no matter how small, consists of its own production.
Rather, we believe that these sales were precisely the type of
sales which were intended to qualify for general exclusion from
first sale regulation for pipeline or distributor sales in section
2(21)(B) of the NGPA. The attribution rule accomplishes that
result."
Order No. 58, 44 Fed.Reg. 66578 (1979). Unlike the majority of
this Court, the Court of Appeals did not reject this
interpretation, which limits the downstream sales of pipeline
produced gas eligible for first sale prices,
see ante at
463 U. S. 323.
Even the Court stops short of suggesting that the Commission's
interpretation is not a plausible construction of the statutory
language. [
Footnote 2/2]
The Court notes only that it would be "at least as consistent
with the ordinary understanding of the words to interpret them as
meaning
measurably attributable to,'" thus including
downstream sales of commingled gas. Ante at 463 U. S. 327.
I doubt that the Court's meaning is equally plausible,
given
Page 463 U. S. 346
other usages of similar language throughout the NGPA, [
Footnote 2/3] but, accepting the Court's
alternative definition as a reasonable possibility, one still does
not reach the conclusion that the Commission's own interpretation
is
unreasonable.
The Commission also refused to accord first sale treatment to
pipeline production by imputing a sale at the point where the
pipeline takes its gas into its transmission system.
"[I]mputing a sale at the wellhead would extend the first sale
concept to intracorporate transactions. As a result, Title I prices
would be applied to bookkeeping and accounting entries of a
corporation, rather than to actual sales."
44 Fed.Reg. 66579 (1979). [
Footnote
2/4] The Court of Appeals, and now this Court, reject this
interpretation by the Commission, again notwithstanding that it is
a perfectly reasonable interpretation of the statutory language.
The issue turns on whether intracorporate transfers must be deemed
"sales." The NGPA defines a "sale" as a "sale, exchange or other
transfer for value." § 2(20), 15 U.S.C. § 3301(2)(20)
(1976 ed., Supp. V). The ordinary meaning of the term supports the
Commission's view that a
Page 463 U. S. 347
"sale" should be an actual exchange of value and title, rather
than a paper transaction. The Conference Report's indication that
the Commission may establish rules applicable to intracorporate
transactions under the first sale definition, H.R.Conf.Rep. No.
95-1752, p. 116 (1978), allows, but does not compel, the agency to
treat intracorporate transfers as first sales. Indeed, if the
statute required the Commission to give first sale treatment to
such transfers, the Conference Report's point would be superfluous.
Moreover, the Conference Report discusses the question in the
context of the Commission's authority to include intracorporate
transfers as first sales in order to prevent circumvention of
maximum price requirements. To use that language to require
transfers to be given first sale prices is to turn the Conference
Report on its head. In sum, neither the statute nor the legislative
history compels the agency to define intracorporate transfers as
first sales -- a definition that would depart from 40 years of
administration of the Natural Gas Act (NGA), during which time an
intracorporate transfer had never been considered a sale of natural
gas.
The Court concedes that
"there is a substantial difference between holding that the
Commission had the authority to treat either transfer as a first
sale and holding that the Commission was
required so to
treat one or the other."
Ante at
463 U. S. 327.
Since there is no legislative history which supports its position,
the Court turns to the structure and purposes of the NGPA.
Concededly, the purpose of the NGPA was to replace traditional
historical cost methods with an incentive pricing scheme that would
create sufficient financial incentive to spur the exploration and
development of natural gas.
See H.R.Rep. No. 95-496
(1978); Note, Legislative History of the Natural Gas Policy Act, 59
Texas L.Rev. 101 (1980). If the Commission's interpretation
undermined the Act's ability to fulfill that goal, the Court would
have a stronger case. But there is nothing in the legislative
hearings, Reports, or debates which expresses any congressional
dissatisfaction
Page 463 U. S. 348
with the existing pricing of pipeline production or which
suggests that the Commission's pricing of the oldest and lowest
cost pipeline production on a cost-of-service basis, under which
the pipelines recover all of their prudent investments regardless
of the success of their efforts, inhibited optimum production
efforts by the pipelines. One can easily agree with the Court that
"there is no reason to believe that any one group of producers is
less likely to respond to incentives than any other,"
ante
at
463 U. S.
336-337, while finding that the cost-of-service basis
provides sufficient incentives for pipeline companies to increase
production. Thus, Order No. 58 is in no sense inconsistent with the
primary purpose of the NGPA. [
Footnote
2/5]
Unable to demonstrate that the Commission's interpretation is
counter to the primary purpose of the NGPA, [
Footnote 2/6] the Court attempts to portray the
Commission's regulation as inconsistent with "several features" of
the regulatory scheme. The effort is unsuccessful. First, the Act's
treatment of old gas in § 104 of the NGPA supports, rather
than undermines, the Commission's position. By incorporating part
of the vintaging pattern that previously existed under the NGA,
§ 104 indicates that the NGPA did not intend to eliminate
all
Page 463 U. S. 349
vestiges of the Commission's earlier pricing authority or to
ensure that all gas, including old gas, would be entitled to higher
"first sale" prices. Only that old gas which qualified for first
sale treatment would receive the higher price. §
101(b)(5).
Second, the Court makes much of the fact that categories of gas
entitled to first sale treatment are defined on the basis of the
type of well, and not on who owns the well. This is true of the
general "first sale" rule, but not of the exception to that rule
provided in § 2(21)(B) which governs these cases and which
unmistakably is directed at the treatment to be given pipeline
production
vis-a-vis natural gas obtained from independent
producers. Moreover, since the Act does not direct or contemplate
that all natural gas will receive higher prices, the Court's
discussion of Title II of the Act, which deals with who is to
shoulder the higher prices, hardly bears on what gas is entitled to
first sale treatment under Title I. The fact that consumers would
shoulder the "bulk of the price increases,"
ante at
463 U. S. 336,
is no argument for enlarging the amount of gas for which price
increases would be provided.
Finally, the limitation on affiliate pricing in §
601(b)(1)(E), does not, either singly or in combination with other
sections,
ante at
463 U. S. 337-338, require that all pipeline production
be entitled to "first sale" treatment. [
Footnote 2/7] As the Court observes later in its
opinion, the purpose of § 601(b)(1)(E) is to insure that, if
first sale prices are afforded to pipeline affiliates, such
Page 463 U. S. 350
affiliate pricing would be subject to market control.
Ante at
463 U. S. 340.
This section, which assures that the lack of arm's length
bargaining where first sales are to affiliates does not result in
excessive prices, hardly reflects a congressional intent that all
pipeline production be entitled to first sale prices. Thus, §
203 of the Act, which defines the acquisition costs subject to
passthrough requirements, offers no support for the Court's
position. The section defines how first sale costs shall be
determined, but does not determine the volumes of gas eligible to
receive first sale prices; in addition, the provision, by its
terms, covers only wells owned by pipeline affiliates.
II
Since neither the plain language of the Act nor its legislative
history forbids the agency's interpretation, and the purpose of the
Act is not undermined by the Commission's approach, considerable
deference should be afforded the agency's interpretation.
Blum
v. Bacon, 457 U. S. 132,
457 U. S.
141-142 (1982). [
Footnote
2/8] Indeed, the very fact that NGPA prices are not necessary
to spur natural gas production by the pipeline companies -- as they
are for independent producers -- is a sufficient basis upon which
to uphold the Commission's interpretation.
Page 463 U. S. 351
The Commission, however, has gone further and offered additional
reasons for the order.
The Commission's justification for rejecting the Court's
intracorporate transfer and downstream "first sales" approaches are
not implausible. Adoption of the "downstream sale" approach would
override the existing division between state and federal regulation
of pipeline sales of natural gas. As the Commission pointed out,
adoption of this theory
"would result in the uniform application of first sale maximum
lawful prices to all mixed volume retail sales made by pipelines
and distributors. . . . The Commission finds no evidence in
[§] 2(21)(B) or in any other provision of the statute that
suggests that Congress intended to require the Commission to expand
the field of federal ratemaking authority to include all mixed
volume sales by intrastate pipelines or local distribution
companies, the regulation of which has been the historic preserve
of the states."
Order No. 102, 45 Fed.Reg. 67086 (1980). The Court rejects this
argument as "exaggerated" because certain downstream pipeline
sales, such as those of gas which has not been commingled with
purchased gas, receive an NGPA rate.
Ante at
463 U. S. 340.
But for this type of gas, Congress has made the judgment in §
2(21)(B) that the NGPA rate should govern. Applying the same
principle to commingled gas, and most pipeline production falls
within this category, would vastly expand the role of federal rates
in what hitherto has been a sector regulated by the States. While
§ 602(a) of the NGPA allows the States to compete with the
federal scheme by establishing price ceilings for the intrastate
market that are lower than the federal NGPA ceiling, the Commission
is fully justified in believing that it should not unnecessarily
intrude into this sphere any further than actually required by the
Act.
There is a second reasonable basis for the Commission's order
that is submitted in this Court. The Commission argues that
pipeline producers would enjoy an unintended
Page 463 U. S. 352
windfall if they received first sale pricing. Since present
cost-of-service pricing permits pipelines to recover costs needed
to stimulate production, first sale prices are unnecessary to
increase natural gas production by pipelines.
Supra at
463 U. S.
347-348. Even if the windfall that would have been given
for new gas were debatable, there can be no question that, for gas
already dedicated to interstate commerce on the date of enactment
of the NGPA and subject to cost-of-service pricing, the affording
of an NGPA price is nothing more than a gift. Accordingly, a number
of state public service commissions, and municipal and other
publicly owned energy systems which provide natural gas service to
citizens, and would foot the bill for the windfall have filed
briefs as
amici curiae in support of the Commission's
position. In precluding this windfall, the Commission is fulfilling
the purpose of the NGA "to protect consumers against exploitation
at the hands of natural gas companies,"
FPC v. Hope Natural Gas
Co., 320 U. S. 591,
320 U. S. 610
(1944);
FPC v. Transcontinental Gas Pipe Line Corp.,
365 U. S. 1,
365 U. S. 19
(1961), and "to afford consumers a complete, permanent and
effective bond of protection from excessive rates and charges,"
Atlantic Refining Co. v. Public Service Comm'n of New
York, 360 U. S. 378,
360 U. S. 388
(1959). Nothing in the NGPA suggests an abandonment of the consumer
protection rationale -- the basis for regulating the industry in
the first place. Thus, the Commission's order does not discourage
pipeline production activity, but only wisely minimizes the size of
the price increases to that necessary to meet the NGPA's
objectives. The Court's rejection of this position is based on the
fact that "the Commission does not pursue its windfall argument to
its logical conclusion,"
ante at
463 U. S. 342,
by denying NGPA prices to pipeline production sold at the wellhead.
But when a pipeline sells gas at the wellhead, it is acting much
like an independent producer, and it is reasonable for the
Commission to have distinguished such sales from intracorporate
transfers and downstream sales of intermingled gas. Similarly,
Page 463 U. S. 353
the judgment that gas dedicated to a downstream contract was
sufficiently similar to a wellhead sale to deserve first sale
treatment does not undermine the Commission's decision not to give
"first sale" treatment to gas which cannot be attributed solely to
the pipelines' own production. In any event, the need to provide a
partial windfall to comply with the Act hardly compels the agency
to multiply the burden on consumers and industry which rely on
natural gas for their energy needs.
III
Today the Court upsets the Commission's interpretation
notwithstanding that it is undeniably supportable under the plain
language of the statute, not contrary to the legislative history,
and consistent with the Act's purpose to increase the supply of
natural gas. In doing so, it rejects out of hand the Commission's
laudable objectives in not unduly intruding into the sphere of
state regulation and not granting the regulated industry an
unwarranted windfall profit. I can recall no similar case in which
we have overturned an agency's interpretation, and I respectfully
dissent from this first and unfortunate instance.
[
Footnote 2/1]
"(B) Certain sales not included. -- Clauses (i), (ii), (iii), or
(iv) of subparagraph (A) shall not include the sale of any volume
of natural gas by any interstate pipeline, intrastate pipeline, or
local distribution company, or any affiliate thereof, unless such
sale is attributable to volumes of natural gas produced by such
interstate pipeline, intrastate pipeline, or local distribution
company, or any affiliate thereof."
92 Stat. 3355, 15 U.S.C. § 3301(21)(B) (1976 ed., Supp.
V).
[
Footnote 2/2]
The Commission's interpretation that downstream pipeline sales
need not be considered first sales within the meaning of the Act is
supported by the House Report on the proposed legislation which
states that "the first sale price is essentially a wellhead price."
H.R.Rep. No. 95-496, pt. 4, P. 103 (1977). In addition, Title I of
the NGPA itself is entitled "wellhead pricing."
[
Footnote 2/3]
When Congress meant to limit the applicability of certain
sections, it used "attributable" in conjunction with qualifying
language.
See, e.g., § 110(a)(1), 15 U.S.C. §
3320(a)(1) (1976 ed., Supp. V), which provides that a first sale
price may exceed the maximum lawful price if the excess is
necessary to recover
"State severance taxes attributable to the production of such
natural gas and borne by the seller, but only to the extent the
amount of such taxes does not exceed the limitation of subsection
(b);"
see also § 503(e)(2)(B), 15 U.S.C. §
3413(e)(2)(B) (1976 ed., Supp. V). Congress' failure to similarly
modify "attributable" in § 2(21)(B) suggests that
"attributable" means, as the Commission held, "exclusively
comprised of."
[
Footnote 2/4]
"In addition, such a rule would extend NGPA first sale
jurisdiction to all corporations which produce their own natural
gas. Comments filed by industrial corporations which consume their
own natural gas production indicate that this would produce
undesirable results, and that no valid regulatory purpose would be
served by extending the Commission's jurisdiction to cover such
production."
44 Fed.Reg. 66579 (1979).
[
Footnote 2/5]
This is even more true after Order No. 98, which grants new
pipeline production parity pricing with first sale prices for
independent producers. Only old gas is now limited to the NGA
prices. The added revenues derived by pipelines from production of
gas from pre-1973 wells cannot possibly operate as an incentive for
the drilling of new wells.
[
Footnote 2/6]
The Court does suggest that the Commission's view serves to
perpetuate the dual system of natural gas regulation. While the
House bill had a more ambitious objective of completely replacing
the existing regulatory structure, the Senate disagreed, and the
compromise enacted into law did not totally supplant the NGA.
Section 104 of the Act directly incorporates the NGA "vintaging"
pattern. As the Court recognizes, most old gas continues to receive
the price it received under the NGA, increased over time in
accordance with the inflation formula found in § 101.
Ante at
463 U. S.
334-336. The Act provides incentive pricing for new gas
to insure adequate supplies in the interstate market, but maintains
NGA price controls on old gas to prevent unnecessary price
increases.
[
Footnote 2/7]
The Commission plausibly distinguishes affiliate sales, governed
by sales contracts, from the purely internal transfers of gas
between production and transportation divisions of a single
corporation.
See Order No. 102, 45 Fed.Reg. 67084 (1980).
In a footnote, the Court denigrates the Commission's analysis by
observing that § 601(b)(1)(E) "reveals that Congress expressly
refused to rely on affiliate sales contracts as reflecting the
realities of the marketplace."
Ante at
463 U. S. 338,
n. 16. But it is precisely because § 601(b)(1)(E) safeguards
the consumer from unduly priced sales involving affiliates but not
intracorporate transfers that it is reasonable that the former, but
not the latter, may receive first sale treatment.
[
Footnote 2/8]
The Court suggests that it is not disregarding the agency's
expertise, because the Commission subsequently granted NGPA
incentive prices to new pipeline produced gas in Order No. 98.
Ante at
463 U. S.
338-339, n. 17. The Commission concluded, however, that
the policies of the NGPA would be better served by granting NGPA
prices
only to pipelines previously subject to area or
nationwide rate treatment while retaining NGA pricing for gas
produced under cost-of-service pricing.
"[T]he Commission found that such incentive prices should not be
available for production from leases previously subject to
cost-of-service treatment, reasoning that such pipelines have
already enjoyed the benefits of a certain recovery of and return on
the costs of production, and that their customers, who have borne
the risks of this investment in the early years of exploration and
development, should have an opportunity to receive the price
benefits of cost-of-service treatment for gas produced as a result
of the expenditures."
Order No. 102, 45 Fed.Reg. 67084 (1980).