During a certain period from 1972 through 1978, petitioner sold
its beer to respondent, the sole wholesale distributor for
petitioner's beer in Vanderburgh County, Ind., at a higher price
than petitioner charged its only wholesale distributor in Henderson
County, Ky., the two counties forming a single metropolitan area
across the state line. Under Indiana law, brewers were required to
sell to all Indiana wholesalers at a single price, Indiana
wholesalers were prohibited from selling to out-of-state retailers,
and Indiana retailers were not permitted to purchase beer from
out-of-state wholesalers. Respondent filed suit in Federal District
Court, alleging that petitioner's price discrimination violated
§ 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman
Act. After trial, the court held that respondent had established a
prima facie case of price discrimination, finding that,
although respondent and petitioner's Kentucky wholesaler did not
sell to the same retailers, they competed for sale of petitioner's
beer to consumers of beer from retailers in the market area; that
petitioner's pricing policy resulted in lower retail prices for its
beer in Kentucky than in Indiana; that many customers living in the
Indiana portion of the market ignored Indiana law to purchase
petitioner's beer more cheaply from Kentucky retailers; and that
petitioner's pricing policy thus prevented respondent from
competing effectively with petitioner's Kentucky wholesaler, and
caused respondent to sell less beer to Indiana retailers. The court
rejected petitioner's "meeting competition" defense under §
2(b) of the Clayton Act, which provides that a defendant may rebut
a
prima facie showing of illegal price discrimination by
establishing that its lower price to any purchaser or purchasers
"was made in good faith to meet an equally low price of a
competitor." The court reasoned that, instead of reducing its
prices to meet those of a competitor, petitioner had created the
price disparity by raising its prices to Indiana wholesalers more
than it had raised its Kentucky prices; that, instead of adjusting
prices on a customer-to-customer basis to meet competition from
other brewers, petitioner charged a single price throughout each
State; and that the higher Indiana price was not set in good faith,
but instead was raised solely to allow petitioner to follow other
brewers to enhance its profits. The Court of Appeals affirmed.
Page 460 U. S. 429
Held:
1. The District Court's findings, supported by direct evidence
of diverted sales, more than established the "competitive injury"
(the reasonable possibility that a price difference may harm
competition) required to establish a
prima facie violation
of § 2(a). For § 2(a)'s purposes, injury to competition
is established
prima facie by proof of a substantial price
discrimination between competing purchasers over time, although the
inference of competitive injury may be overcome by evidence
breaking the causal connection between the price differential and
lost sales or profits. This rule is not limited to cases where the
favored competitor is extraordinarily large. Nor is the competitive
injury component of a Robinson-Patman Act violation limited to the
injury to competition between the favored and the disfavored
purchaser; it also encompasses the injury to competition between
their customers. Pp.
460 U. S.
434-438.
2. Petitioner's meeting-competition defense under § 2(b) is
not defeated on the theory that the price difference resulted from
price increases in Indiana, rather than price decreases in
Kentucky, and that the higher Indiana price resulted from
petitioner's policy of following the Indiana prices of its larger
competitors in order to enhance its profits.
FTC v. A. E.
Staley Mfg. Co., 324 U. S. 746,
distinguished. Pp.
460 U. S.
438-447.
(a) The meeting-competition defense at least requires the seller
to show the existence of facts that would lead a reasonable and
prudent person to believe that the seller's lower price to the
favored purchaser or purchasers would meet the equally low price of
a competitor. The defense also requires the seller to demonstrate
that its lower price was actually a good faith response to that
competing low price. Pp.
460 U. S.
439-441.
(b) The standard governing the requirement of a "good faith
response" is the standard of a prudent businessman responding
fairly to what he reasonably believes is a situation of competitive
necessity. Here, the District Court did not address the crucial
question whether petitioner's Kentucky prices remained lower than
its Indiana prices in response to competitors' prices in Kentucky.
If petitioner set its
lower price in good faith to meet an
equally low price of a competitor, it did not violate the
Robinson-Patman Act. Moreover, the existence of industry-wide price
discrimination within the geographic retail market did not itself
establish collusion inconsistent with a good faith response,
particularly since the interstate price difference could well have
been attributable not to petitioner, but to Indiana's extensive
regulation of the sale of beer. Pp.
460 U. S.
441-444.
(c) Nothing in § 2(b) requires a seller to
lower
its prices in order to meet competition. On the contrary, §
2(b) requires the defendant to show only that its lower price was
made in good faith to meet a competitor's
Page 460 U. S. 430
equally low price. A price discrimination created by selective
smaller price increases can result from a good faith effort to meet
a competitor's low price. Nor is the good faith with which the
lower price is offered impugned if the prices raised, like those
kept lower, respond to competitors' prices and are set with the
goal of increasing the seller's profits. Pp.
460 U. S.
444-446.
(d) The meeting-competition defense is not limited to price
discrimination for the purpose of retaining a customer. A seller's
price discrimination must be a defensive response to competition,
in the sense that the lower price must be calculated and offered in
good faith to "meet not beat" the competitor's low price, but
§ 2(b) does not distinguish between meeting a competitor's
lower price to retain an old customer and meeting a competitor's
lower price in an attempt to gain new customers. Pp.
460 U. S.
446-447.
3. Petitioner's meeting-competition defense is not defeated on
the theory that § 2(b) applies only where the defendant sets
its lower price on a customer-by-customer basis ,rather than, as
here, by the defendant's use of area-wide pricing. Congress did not
intend to limit the availability of § 2(b) to
customer-specific responses, but also intended to allow reasonable
pricing responses on an area-specific basis where competitive
circumstances warrant them. A seller choosing to price on a
territorial basis must show that the decision was a genuine,
reasonable response to prevailing competitive circumstances. Pp.
460 U. S.
447-451.
4. In the absence of further findings, petitioner has not
established its meeting-competition defense as a matter of law.
While there is evidence in the record that might support an
inference that petitioner's decision to set a lower statewide price
in Kentucky was a good faith, well-tailored response to the
competitive circumstances prevailing there, the question whether to
draw such inference is for the trier of fact, not this Court. Pp.
460 U. S.
451-452.
Page 460 U. S. 431
JUSTICE BLACKMUN delivered the opinion of the Court.
Section 2(b) of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 730, as amended by the
Robinson-Patman Act, 49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. § 13(b),
provides that a defendant may rebut a
prima facie showing
of illegal price discrimination by establishing that its lower
price to any purchaser or purchasers "was made in good faith to
meet an equally low price of a competitor." [
Footnote 1] The United States Court of Appeals for
the Seventh Circuit has concluded that the "meeting-competition"
defense of § 2(b) is available only if the defendant sets its
lower price on a customer-by-customer basis and creates the price
discrimination by lowering, rather than by raising, prices. We
conclude that § 2(b) is not so inflexible.
I
From July 1, 1972, through November 30, 1978, petitioner Falls
City Industries, Inc., sold beer f.o.b. its Louisville, Ky.,
brewery to wholesalers throughout Indiana, Kentucky, and 11 other
States. Respondent Vanco Beverage, Inc., was the sole wholesale
distributor of Falls City beer in Vanderburgh County, Ind. That
county includes the city of Evansville. Directly across the state
line from Vanderburgh County is Henderson County, Ky., where Falls
City's only wholesale distributor was Dawson Springs, Inc. The city
of Henderson, Ky., located in Henderson County, is less than 10
miles from Evansville. The two cities are connected by a four-lane
interstate highway. The two counties generally are considered to be
a single metropolitan area. App. 124.
Page 460 U. S. 432
Vanco and Dawson Springs each purchased beer from Falls City and
other brewers and resold it to retailers in Vanderburgh County and
Henderson County, respectively. The two distributors did not
compete for sales to the same retailers. This was because Indiana
wholesalers were prohibited by state law from selling to
out-of-state retailers, Ind.Code § 7.1-3-3-5 (1982), and
Indiana retailers were not permitted to purchase beer from
out-of-state wholesalers.
See § 7.1-3-4-6. Indiana
law also affected beer sales in two other ways relevant to this
case. First, Indiana required brewers to sell to all Indiana
wholesalers at a single price. § 7.1-5-5-7. Second, although
it was ignored and virtually unenforced,
see Tr. 122-123,
135-136, state law prohibited consumers from importing alcoholic
beverages without a permit. § 7.1-5-11-1.
In December, 1976, Vanco sued Falls City in the United States
District Court for the Southern District of Indiana, alleging,
among other things, that Falls City had discriminated in price
against Vanco, in violation of § 2(a) of the Clayton Act, 38
Stat. 730, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, 49 Stat. 1526, 15
U.S.C. § 13(a), [
Footnote
2] by charging Vanco a higher price than it charged Dawson
Springs. Vanco also claimed that Falls City had violated
§§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1
and 2, by conspiring with other brewers and unnamed wholesalers to
maintain higher prices in Indiana than in Kentucky.
After trial, the District Court dismissed Vanco's Sherman Act
claims, finding no evidence to support the allegations of
Page 460 U. S. 433
conspiracy or monopolization.1980-2 Trade Cases � 63,357,
pp. 75,809, 75,820. The court held, however, that Vanco had made
out a
prima facie case of price discrimination under the
Robinson-Patman Act. The District Court found that Vanco competed
in a geographic market that spanned the state border and included
Vanderburgh and Henderson Counties.
Id. at 75,813-75,814.
Although Vanco and Dawson Springs did not sell to the same
retailers, they "competed for sale of [Falls City's] beer to . . .
consumers of beer from retailers situated in [that] market area."
Id. at 75,814. Falls City charged a higher price for beer
sold to Indiana distributors than it charged for the same beer sold
to distributors in other States, including Kentucky.
Ibid.
[
Footnote 3] This pricing
policy resulted in lower retail prices for Falls City beer in
Kentucky than in Indiana, because Kentucky distributors passed on
their savings to retailers who, in turn, passed them on to
consumers. Finding that many customers living in the Indiana
portion of the geographic market ignored state law to purchase
cheaper Falls City beer from Henderson County retailers, the court
concluded that Falls City's pricing policies prevented Vanco from
competing effectively with Dawson Springs,
id. at
75,815-75,816, and caused it to sell less beer to Indiana
retailers.
Id. at 75,814-75,817, 75,818. [
Footnote 4]
Page 460 U. S. 434
The District Court rejected Falls City's § 2(b)
meeting-competition defense. The court reasoned that, instead of
reducing its prices to meet those of a competitor, Falls City had
created the price disparity by raising its prices to Indiana
wholesalers more than it had raised its Kentucky prices. Instead of
"adjusting prices on a customer to customer basis to meet
competition from other brewers,"
id. at 75,822, Falls City
charged a single price throughout each State in which it sold beer.
The court concluded that Falls City's higher Indiana price was not
set in good faith; instead, it was raised "for the sole reason that
it followed the other brewers . . . for its profit."
Ibid.
The United States Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit, by a
divided vote, affirmed the finding of liability. 654 F.2d 1224
(1981). [
Footnote 5] The court
held that Vanco had established a
prima facie case of
illegal price discrimination, and that Falls City had not
demonstrated that the discrimination "was a good faith effort to
defend against competitors."
Id. at 1230. We granted
certiorari to review the Court of Appeals' holdings respecting
injury to competition and the "meeting-competition" defense. 455
U.S. 988 (1982).
II
To establish a
prima facie violation of § 2(a),
one of the elements a plaintiff must show is a reasonable
possibility that a
Page 460 U. S. 435
price difference may harm competition.
Corn Products
Refining Co. v. FTC, 324 U. S. 726,
324 U. S. 742
(1945). In keeping with the Robinson-Patman Act's prophylactic
purpose, § 2(a) "does not
require that the discriminations
must in fact have harmed competition.'" J. Truett Payne Co. v.
Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U. S. 557,
451 U. S. 562
(1981), quoting Corn Products, 324 U.S. at 324 U. S. 742.
This reasonable possibility of harm is often referred to as
competitive injury. Unless rebutted by one of the Robinson-Patman
Act's affirmative defenses, a showing of competitive injury as part
of a prima facie case is sufficient to support injunctive
relief, and to authorize further inquiry by the courts into whether
the plaintiff is entitled to treble damages under § 4 of the
Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 731, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 15 (1976
ed., Supp. V). J. Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors
Corp., 451 U.S. at 451 U. S. 562.
[Footnote 6]
Falls City contends that the Court of Appeals erred in relying
on
FTC v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S.
37 (1948), to uphold the District Court's finding of
competitive injury. In
Morton Salt, this Court held that,
for the purposes of § 2(a), injury to competition is
established
prima facie by proof of a substantial price
discrimination between competing purchasers over time. 334 U.S. at
334 U. S. 46,
50-51;
see id. at
334 U. S. 60 (Jackson, J., dissenting in part). In the
absence of direct evidence of displaced sales, this inference may
be overcome by evidence breaking the causal connection between a
price differential and lost sales or profits. F. Rowe, Price
Discrimination Under the Robinson-Patman Act 182 (1962) (Rowe);
see Chrysler Credit Corp. v. J. Truett Payne Co., 670 F.2d
575, 581 (CA5 1982).
Page 460 U. S. 436
According to Falls City, the
Morton Salt rule should be
applied only in cases involving "large buyer preference or seller
predation." Brief for Petitioner 31. Falls City does not, however,
suggest any economic reason why
Morton Salt's
"self-evident" inference, 334 U.S. at
334 U. S. 50,
should not apply when the favored competitor is not extraordinarily
large. Although concerns about the excessive market power of large
purchasers were primarily responsible for passage of the
Robinson-Patman Act,
see generally Rowe at 3-23; U.S.
Dept. of Justice, Report on the Robinson-Patman Act 101-139 (1977)
(1977 Report), the Act "is of general applicability and prohibits
discriminations generally,"
FTC v. Sun Oil Co.,
371 U. S. 505,
371 U. S. 522
(1963). The determination whether to alter the scope of the Act
must be made by Congress, not this Court, as is recognized by the
commentators on which Falls City relies.
See 1977 Report
at 221-228 and 290-291; ABA Antitrust Section, Monograph No. 4, The
Robinson-Patman Act: Policy and Law, Vol. I, 102-103 (1980).
The
Morton Salt rule was not misapplied in this case.
In a strictly literal sense, this case differs from
Morton
Salt because Vanco and Dawson Springs did not compete with
each other at the wholesale level; Vanco sold only to Indiana
retailers, and Dawson Springs sold only to Kentucky retailers. But
the competitive injury component of a Robinson-Patman Act violation
is not limited to the injury to competition between the favored and
the disfavored purchaser; it also encompasses the injury to
competition between their customers -- in this case, the
competition between Kentucky retailers and Indiana retailers, who,
under a District Court finding not challenged in this Court, were
selling in a single, interstate retail market. [
Footnote 7]
Page 460 U. S. 437
After observing that Falls City had maintained a substantial
price difference between Vanco and Dawson Springs over a
significant period of time, the Court of Appeals, like the District
Court, considered the evidence that Vanco's loss of Falls City beer
sales was attributable to factors other than the price difference,
particularly the market-wide decline of Falls City beer. Both
courts found it likely that this overall decline accounted for some
-- or even most -- of Vanco's lost sales. Nevertheless, if some of
Vanco's injury was attributable to the price discrimination, Falls
City is responsible to that extent.
See Perma Life Mufflers,
Inc. v. International Parts Corp., 392 U.
S. 134,
392 U. S. 144
(1968) (WHITE, J., concurring).
The Court of Appeals agreed with the District Court's findings
that "the major reason for the higher Indiana retail beer prices
was the higher prices charged Indiana distributors," and
"the lower retail prices in Henderson County attracted Indiana
customers away from Indiana retailers, thereby causing the
retailers to curtail purchases from Vanco."
654 F.2d at 1229. These findings were supported by direct
evidence of diverted sales, [
Footnote 8] and more than established the competitive
Page 460 U. S. 438
injury required for a
prima facie case under §
2(a).
See J. Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp.,
451 U.S. at
451 U. S.
561-562;
Morton Salt, 334 U.S. at
334 U. S. 50-51.
We therefore turn to Falls City's "meeting-competition"
defense.
III
When proved, the meeting-competition defense of § 2(b)
exonerates a seller from Robinson-Patman Act liability.
Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U. S. 231,
340 U. S.
246-247 (1951). This Court consistently has held that
the meeting-competition defense
"'at least requires the seller, who has knowingly discriminated
in price, to show the existence of facts which would lead a
reasonable and prudent person to believe that the granting of a
lower price would in fact meet the equally low price of a
competitor.'"
United States v. United States Gypsum Co., 438 U.
S. 422,
438 U. S. 451
(1978), quoting
FTC v. A. E. Staley Mfg. Co., 324 U.
S. 746,
324 U. S.
759-760 (1945);
see Great A&P Tea Co. v.
FTC, 440 U. S. 69,
440 U. S. 82
(1979). The seller must show that, under the circumstances, it was
reasonable to believe that the quoted price or a lower one was
available to the favored purchaser or purchasers from the seller's
competitors.
See United States Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. at
438 U. S. 451.
Neither the District Court nor the Court of Appeals addressed the
question whether Falls City had shown information that would have
led a reasonable and prudent person to believe that its lower
Kentucky price would meet competitors' equally low prices there;
indeed, no findings whatever were made regarding competitors'
Kentucky prices, or
Page 460 U. S. 439
the information available to Falls City about its competitors'
Kentucky prices.
Instead, the Court of Appeals reasoned that Falls City had
otherwise failed to show that its pricing "was a good faith effort"
to meet competition. 654 F.2d at 1230. The Court of Appeals
considered it sufficient to defeat the defense that the price
difference "resulted from price increases in Indiana, not price
decreases in Kentucky,"
ibid., and that the higher Indiana
price was the result of Falls City's policy of following the
Indiana prices of its larger competitors in order to enhance its
profits. The Court of Appeals also suggested that Falls City's
defense failed because it adopted a "general system of
competition," rather than responding to "individual situations."
Ibid. The court believed that
FTC v. A. E. Staley Mfg.
Co., supra, supported this holding. 654 F.2d at 1230.
A
On its face, § 2(b) requires more than a showing of facts
that would have led a reasonable person to believe that a lower
price was available to the favored purchaser from a competitor. The
showing required is that the "lower price . . .
was made
in good faith
to meet" the competitor's low price. 15
U.S.C. § 13(b) (emphasis added). Thus, the defense requires
that the seller offer the lower price in good faith
for the
purpose of meeting the competitor's price, that is, the lower
price must actually have been a good faith response to that
competing low price.
See Rowe, at 234-235.
See
generally Kuenzel & Schiffres, Making Sense of
Robinson-Patman: The Need to Revitalize Its Affirmative Defenses,
62 Va.L.Rev. 1211, 1237-1255 (1976). In most situations, a showing
of facts giving rise to a reasonable belief that equally low prices
were available to the favored purchaser from a competitor will be
sufficient to establish that the seller's lower price was offered
in good faith to meet that price. In others, however, despite the
availability from other sellers of a low price, it may be apparent
that the defendant's low offer was not a good faith response.
Page 460 U. S. 440
In
Staley, this Court applied that principle. The
Federal Trade Commission (FTC) had proceeded against Staley and six
competing manufacturers of glucose, all of whom adhered to the same
Chicago basing-point pricing system.
See C. Edwards, Price
Discrimination Law 372-379 (1959).
See generally FTC
Policy Toward Geographic Pricing Practices, 1 CCH Trade Reg.Rep.
�� 3601.27, 3601.40-3601.42, pp. 5346, 5351-5352
(10th ed.1959). Like its competitors, Staley, whose plant was
located in Decatur, Ill., sold glucose to candy and syrup
manufacturers at a delivered price that included the freight rate
from Chicago to the point of delivery. Purchasers nearer Decatur
thus were charged an element of "phantom" freight, while Staley
"absorbed" an element of freight in sales to buyers nearer Chicago.
324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 749.
Customers located near Staley's Decatur plant were harmed because,
despite being located closer to the plant, they were forced to pay
more for glucose than did their Chicago area competitors.
Id. at 756.
The FTC eventually charged all seven manufacturers individually
with price discrimination and jointly under the Federal Trade
Commission Act with price fixing.
See Corn Products Refining
Co., 47 F.T.C. 587 (1950). At the time of the
Staley
decision, both the FTC and this Court had determined that use of
the pricing system by Staley's competitors was illegal under §
2(a).
See Corn Products Refining Co. v. FTC, 324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 732,
324 U. S.
737-739. And although neither the FTC nor this Court
directly relied on the fact in finding price discrimination, Staley
itself had been found to be a party to an interseller conspiracy
aimed at maintaining "oppressive and uniform net delivered prices"
throughout the country.
See A. E. Staley Mfg. Co. v. FTC,
4 F.T.C. Stat. & Dec. 795, 805 (1943).
The Court observed that § 2(b) could exonerate Staley only
if that section permitted a seller to establish "an otherwise
unlawful system of discriminatory prices" in order to benefit from
"a like unlawful system maintained by his competitors."
Page 460 U. S. 441
324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 753.
Staley could not claim that its low Chicago prices were set for the
purpose of meeting the equally low prices of competitors there; the
Chicago prices could be seen only as part of a collusive pricing
system designed to exact artificially high prices throughout the
country. Since the low prices were set "in order to establish
elsewhere the artificially high prices whose discriminatory effect
permeates respondents' entire pricing system,"
id. at
324 U. S. 756,
the Court sustained the FTC's finding "that respondents' price
discriminations were not made to meet a
lower' price, and
consequently were not in good faith," id. at 324 U. S.
758.
Thus, even had Staley been able to show that its prices
throughout the country did not undercut those of its competitors,
its lower price in the Chicago area was not a good faith response
to the lower prices there. Staley had not priced in response to
competitors' discrete pricing decisions, but from the outset had
followed an industry-wide practice of setting its prices according
to a single, arbitrary scheme that, by its nature, precluded
independent pricing in response to normal competitive forces.
B
Almost 20 years ago, the FTC set forth the standard that governs
the requirement of a "good faith response":
"At the heart of Section 2(b) is the concept of 'good faith.'
This is a flexible and pragmatic, not a technical or doctrinaire,
concept. The standard of good faith is simply the standard of the
prudent businessman responding fairly to what he reasonably
believes is a situation of competitive necessity."
Continental Baking Co., 63 F.T.C. 2071, 2163 (1963).
Whether this standard is met depends on "
the facts and
circumstances of the particular case, not abstract theories or
remote conjectures.'" United States v. United States Gypsum
Co., 438 U.S. at 438 U. S. 454,
quoting Continental Baking Co., 63 F.T.C. at
2163.
Page 460 U. S. 442
The "facts and circumstances" present in
Staley differ
markedly from those present here. Although the District Court
characterized the Indiana prices charged by Falls City and its
competitors as "artificially high," there is no evidence that Falls
City's lower prices in Kentucky were set as part of a plan to
obtain artificially high profits in Indiana, rather than in
response to competitive conditions in Kentucky. Falls City did not
adopt an illegal system of prices maintained by its competitors.
[
Footnote 9] The District Court
found that Falls City's prices rose in Indiana in response to
competitors' price increases there; it did not address the crucial
question whether Falls City's Kentucky prices remained lower in
response to competitors' prices in that State.
Vanco attempts to liken this case to
Staley by arguing
that the existence of industry-wide price discrimination within the
single geographic retail market itself indicates "tacit or explicit
collusion, or . . . market power" inconsistent with a good faith
response. Brief for Respondent 39. By its terms, however, the
meeting-competition defense requires a seller to justify only its
lower price.
See Staley, 324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 753.
Thus, although the Sherman Act would provide a remedy if Falls
City's higher Indiana price were set collusively, collusion is
relevant to Vanco's Robinson-Patman Act claim only if it affected
Falls City's lower Kentucky price. If Falls City set its lower
price in good faith to meet an equally low price of a competitor,
it did not violate the Robinson-Patman Act.
Page 460 U. S. 443
Moreover, the collusion argument founders on a complete lack of
proof. Persistent industry-wide price discrimination within a
geographic market should certainly alert a court to a substantial
possibility of collusion. [
Footnote 10]
See Posner, Oligopoly and the
Antitrust Laws: A Suggested Approach, 21 Stan.L.Rev. 1562,
1578-1579 (1969). Here, however, the persistent interstate price
difference could well have been attributable not to Falls City, but
to extensive state regulation of the sale of beer. Indiana required
each brewer to charge a single price for its beer throughout the
State, and barred direct competition between Indiana and Kentucky
distributors for sales to retailers. In these unusual
circumstances, the prices charged to Vanco and other wholesalers in
Vanderburgh County may have been influenced more by market
conditions in distant Gary and Fort Wayne than by conditions in
nearby Henderson County, Ky. Moreover, wholesalers in Henderson
County competed directly, and attempted to price competitively,
with wholesalers in neighboring Kentucky counties. App. 52-53. A
separate pricing structure might well have evolved in the two
States without collusion, notwithstanding
Page 460 U. S. 444
the existence of a common retail market along the border. Thus,
the sustained price discrimination does not itself demonstrate that
Falls City's Kentucky prices were not a good faith response to
competitors' prices there.
C
The Court of Appeals explicitly relied on two other factors in
rejecting Falls City's meeting-competition defense: the price
discrimination was created by raising, rather than lowering,
prices, and Falls City raised its prices in order to increase its
profits. Neither of these factors is controlling. Nothing in §
2(b) requires a seller to lower its price in order to meet
competition. On the contrary, § 2(b) requires the defendant to
show only that its "lower price . . . was made in good faith to
meet an equally low price of a competitor." A seller is required to
justify a price difference by showing that it reasonably believed
that an equally low price was available to the purchaser and that
it offered the lower price for that reason; the seller is not
required to show that the difference resulted from subtraction,
rather than addition.
A different rule would not only be contrary to the language of
the statute, but also might stifle the only kind of legitimate
price competition reasonably available in particular industries. In
a period of generally rising prices, vigorous price competition for
a particular customer or customers may take the form of smaller
price increases, rather than price cuts. Thus, a price
discrimination created by selective price increases can result from
a good faith effort to meet a competitor's low price.
Nor is the good faith with which the lower price is offered
impugned if the prices raised, like those kept lower, respond to
competitors' prices and are set with the goal of increasing the
seller's profits. A seller need not choose between
"ruinously cutting its prices to all its customers to match the
price offered to one, [and] refusing to meet the competition
and
Page 460 U. S. 445
then ruinously raising its prices to its remaining customers to
cover increased unit costs."
Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U.S. at
340 U. S. 250.
Nor need a seller choose between keeping all its prices ruinously
low to meet the price offered to one, and ruinously raising its
prices to all customers to a level significantly above that charged
by its competitors. A seller is permitted
"to retain a customer by realistically meeting in good faith the
price offered to that customer, without necessarily changing the
seller's price to its other customers."
Ibid. The plain language of § 2(b) also permits a
seller to retain a customer by realistically meeting in good faith
the price offered to that customer, without necessarily freezing
his price to his other customers.
Section 2(b) does not require a seller, meeting in good faith a
competitor's lower price to certain customers, to forgo the profits
that otherwise would be available in sales to its remaining
customers. The very purpose of the defense is to permit a seller to
treat different competitive situations differently. The prudent
businessman responding fairly to what he believes in good faith is
a situation of competitive necessity might well raise his prices to
some customers to increase his profits, while meeting competitors'
prices by keeping his prices to other customers low.
The Court in
Staley said that the meeting-competition
defense
"presupposes that the person charged with violating the Act
would, by his normal, nondiscriminatory pricing methods, have
reached a price so high that he could reduce it in order to meet
the competitor's equally low price."
324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 754.
In that case, however, the Court was not dealing with a seller
whose "normal, nondiscriminatory pricing methods" called for a
price increase, but who wished to exempt certain customers from the
increase in order to meet prices, lower than the increased price,
available to those customers from competitors. Of course, a seller
could accomplish the same result within the guidelines the Court of
Appeals
Page 460 U. S. 446
would impose by instituting across-the-board price increases
followed by selective reductions. But far from being flexible and
pragmatic, a rule requiring such costly behavior would be
nonsensical. [
Footnote
11]
D
Vanco also contends that Falls City did not satisfy § 2(b)
because its price discrimination "was not a
defensive
response to competition." Brief for Respondent 47 (emphasis
supplied). According to Vanco, the Robinson-Patman Act permits
price discrimination only if its purpose is to retain a customer.
Id. at 32-33. We agree that a seller's response must be
defensive, in the sense that the lower price must be calculated and
offered in good faith to "meet not beat" the competitor's low
price.
See United States Gypsum Co., 438 U.S. at
438 U. S. 454.
Section 2(b), however, does not distinguish between one who meets a
competitor's lower price to retain an old customer and one who
meets a competitor's lower price in an attempt to gain new
customers. [
Footnote 12]
See Stevens, Defense of Meeting the Lower Price of a
Competitor, in Summer Institute on International and Comparative
Law, University of Michigan Law School, Lectures on Federal
Antitrust Laws 129, 135-136 (1953). Such a distinction would be
Page 460 U. S. 447
inconsistent with that section's language and logic,
see
Sunshine Biscuits, Inc. v. FTC, 306 F.2d 48, 51-52 (CA7
1962),
"would not be in keeping with elementary principles of
competition, and would in fact foster tight and rigid commercial
relationships by insulating them from market forces."
1955 Report at 18;
see 1977 Report at 26, 265.
[
Footnote 13]
IV
The Court of Appeals also relied on
Staley for the
proposition that the meeting-competition defense "
places
emphasis on individual [competitive] situations, rather than upon a
general system of competition,'" 554 F.2d at 1230 (quoting
Staley, 324 U.S. at 324 U. S.
753), and "does not justify the maintenance of
discriminatory pricing among classes of customers that results
merely from the adoption of a competitor's discriminatory pricing
structure," 654 F.2d at 1230. The Court of Appeals was apparently
invoking the District Court's findings that Falls City set prices
statewide, rather than on a "customer to customer basis," and the
District Court's conclusion that this practice disqualified Falls
City from asserting the meeting-competition defense. 1980-2 Trade
Cases at 75,817. At least two other Courts of Appeals have read
Staley to hold that the defense is unavailable to sellers
pricing on other than a customer-by-customer basis, while two
Courts of Appeals have held that a customer-by-customer response is
not required. [Footnote
14]
Page 460 U. S. 448
There is no evidence that Congress intended to limit the
availability of § 2(b) to customer-specific responses. Section
2(b)'s predecessor, § 2 of the original Clayton Act, stated
that "nothing herein contained shall prevent . . . discrimination
in price in the same or different communities made in good faith to
meet competition." 38 Stat. 730. The Judiciary Committee of the
House of Representatives, which drafted the clause that became the
current § 2(b),
see Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U.S.
at
340 U. S.
247-248, n. 14, explained the new section's anticipated
function:
"It should be noted that, while the seller is permitted to meet
local competition, [§ 2(b)] does not permit him to
cut
local prices until his competitor has first offered
lower prices, and then he can go no further than to meet those
prices."
H.R.Rep. No. 2287, 74th Cong., 2d Sess., 16 (1936) (emphasis
supplied). Congress intended to allow reasonable pricing responses
on an area-specific basis where competitive circumstances warrant
them. The purpose of the amendment was to "restric[t] the proviso
to price differentials occurring in actual competition."
Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U.S. at
340 U. S. 242.
We conclude that Congress did not intend to bar territorial price
differences that are in fact responses to competitive
conditions.
Section 2(b) specifically allows a "lower price . . . to any
purchaser or purchasers" made in good faith to meet a competitor's
equally low price. A single low price surely may be extended to
numerous purchasers if the seller has a reasonable basis for
believing that the competitor's lower price is available to them.
[
Footnote 15] Beyond the
requirement that the lower
Page 460 U. S. 449
price be reasonably calculated to "meet not beat" the
competition, Congress intended to leave it a "question of fact . .
. whether the way in which the competition was met lies within the
latitude allowed." 80 Cong.Rec. 9418 (1936) (remarks of Rep.
Utterback). Once again, this inquiry is guided by the standard of
the prudent businessman responding fairly to what he reasonably
believes are the competitive necessities.
A seller may have good reason to believe that a competitor or
competitors are charging lower prices throughout a particular
region.
See William Inglis & Sons Baking Co. v. ITT
Continental Baking Co., 668 F.2d 1014, 1046 (CA9 1981),
cert. denied, 459 U.S. 825 (1982);
Balian Ice Cream
Co. v. Arden Farms Co., 231 F.2d 356, 366 (CA9 1955),
cert. denied, 350 U.S. 991 (1956); Rowe at 235-236. In
such circumstances, customer-by-customer negotiations would be
unlikely to result in prices different from those set according to
information relating to competitors' territorial prices. A
customer-by-customer requirement might also make meaningful price
competition unrealistically expensive for smaller firms such as
Falls City, which was attempting to compete with larger national
breweries in 13 separate States.
Cf. Callaway Mills Co. v.
FTC, 362 F.2d 435, 442 (CA5 1966) (in some circumstances,
requirement of customer-by-customer pricing "would be burdensome,
unreasonable, and practically unfeasible").
In
Staley, 324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 753,
as in each of the later cases in which this Court has contrasted a
"general system of competition" with "individual competitive
situations,"
see, e.g., FTC v. National Lead Co.,
352 U. S. 419,
352 U. S. 431
(1957);
FTC v. Cement Institute, 333 U.
S. 683,
333 U. S. 708
(1948), the seller's lower
Page 460 U. S. 450
price was quoted not "
because of lower prices by a
competitor," but "
because of a preconceived pricing scale
which [was] operative regardless of variations in competitor's
prices." Rowe at 234 (emphasis in original). In those cases, the
contested lower prices were not truly "
responsive to
rivals' competitive prices,"
ibid. (emphasis in original),
and therefore were not genuinely made to meet competitors' lower
prices. Territorial pricing, however, can be a perfectly reasonable
method -- sometimes the most reasonable method -- of responding to
rivals' low prices. [
Footnote
16] We choose not to read into § 2(b) a restriction that
would deny the meeting-competition defense to one whose area-wide
price is a well-tailored response to competitors' low prices.
Of course, a seller must limit its lower price to that group of
customers reasonably believed to have the lower price available to
it from competitors. A response that is not reasonably tailored to
the competitive situation as known to the seller, or one that is
based on inadequate verification, would not meet the standard of
good faith. Similarly, the response may continue only as long as
the competitive circumstances justifying it, as reasonably known by
the seller, persist. [
Footnote
17] One choosing to price on a territorial basis, rather than
on a
Page 460 U. S. 451
customer-by-customer basis, must show that this decision was a
genuine, reasonable response to prevailing competitive
circumstances.
See International Air Industries, Inc. v.
American Excelsior Co., 517 F.2d 714, 725-726 (CA5 1975),
cert. denied, 424 U.S. 943 (1976);
Callaway Mills Co.
v. FTC, 362 F.2d at 441-442.
See generally 1977
Report at 265. Unless the circumstances call into question the
seller's good faith, this burden will be discharged by showing that
a reasonable and prudent businessman would believe that the lower
price he charged was generally available from his competitors
throughout the territory and throughout the period in which he made
the lower price available.
See William Inglis & Sons Baking
Co. v. ITT Continental Baking Co., 668 F.2d at 1045-1046.
V
In summary, the meeting-competition defense requires the seller
at least to show the existence of facts that would lead a
reasonable and prudent person to believe that the seller's lower
price would meet the equally low price of a competitor; it also
requires the seller to demonstrate that its lower price was a good
faith response to a competitor's lower price.
Falls City contends that it has established its
meeting-competition defense as a matter of law. In the absence of
further findings, we do not agree. The District Court and the Court
of Appeals did not decide whether Falls City had shown facts that
would have led a reasonable and prudent person to conclude that its
lower price would meet the equally low price of its competitors in
Kentucky throughout the period at issue in this suit. Nor did they
apply the proper standards to the question whether Falls City's
decision to set a single statewide price in Kentucky was a good
faith, well-tailored response to the competitive circumstances
prevailing there. The absence of allegations to the contrary is not
controlling; the statute places the burden of establishing the
defense on Falls City, not Vanco. There is evidence
Page 460 U. S. 452
in the record that might support an inference that these
requirements were met, [
Footnote
18] but whether to draw that inference is a question for the
trier of fact, not this Court.
Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of Appeals is vacated,
and the case is remanded for further proceedings consistent with
this opinion.
It is so ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
Section 2(b)'s "meeting-competition" proviso reads:
"[N]othing herein contained shall prevent a seller rebutting the
prima-facie case thus made by showing that his lower price or the
furnishing of services or facilities to any purchaser or purchasers
was made in good faith to meet an equally low price of a
competitor, or the services or facilities furnished by a
competitor."
[
Footnote 2]
That section provides in relevant part:
"It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the
course of such commerce, either directly or indirectly, to
discriminate in price between different purchasers of commodities
of like grade and quality where either or any of the purchases
involved in such discrimination are in commerce . . . and where the
effect of such discrimination may be substantially to lessen
competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce,
or to injure, destroy, or prevent competition with any person who
either grants or knowingly receives the benefit of such
discrimination, or with customers of either of them. . . ."
[
Footnote 3]
Falls City charged Vanco and other Indiana distributors 10-30%
more than it charged Dawson Springs and other Kentucky
distributors. The District Court concluded that this price
differential was not explained by differing costs. Falls City's
distributors -- wherever located -- picked up the beer at Falls
City's Louisville brewery. 1980-2 Trade Cases at 75,814.
[
Footnote 4]
The District Court acknowledged that, during the period at
issue, sales of Falls City beer dropped precipitously throughout
Indiana and Kentucky.
Id. at 75,815. This decline
paralleled a significant nationwide trend that favored national
brands of beer, and harmed or eliminated many regional brewers like
Falls City.
See generally FTC, Staff Report of Bureau of
Economics, The Brewing Industry 13-28 (1978). But Vanco's sales of
Falls City beer declined more rapidly than did Falls City's sales
in Indiana as a whole, or in Henderson County. Moreover, Falls
City's rate of decline in Henderson County was less than that in
Kentucky as a whole. The District Court found that the difference
between Vanco's rate of decline and the rate of decline elsewhere
was caused by Falls City's price discrimination. 1980-2 Trade Cases
at 75,815.
[
Footnote 5]
The Court of Appeals remanded the case to the District Court for
a redetermination of damages because, contrary to our decision in
J. Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U.
S. 557 (1981), the District Court had found, 1980-2
Trade Cases at 75,823, that the aggregate overcharges to Vanco --
$575,293.79 -- were "automatic damage[s]," and had entered judgment
for treble that amount. 654 F.2d at 1231. The damages issue is not
before this Court.
[
Footnote 6]
Section 4 of the Clayton Act requires "some showing of actual
injury attributable to something the antitrust laws were designed
to prevent."
J. Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp.,
451 U.S. at
451 U. S. 562.
In this case, the Court of Appeals affirmed the District Court's
finding of antitrust injury, 654 F.2d at 1230, and that issue is
not before us.
[
Footnote 7]
The Court of Appeals upheld the District Court's findings that
the sale of Falls City beer to Vanco was in interstate commerce,
and that Henderson County and Vanderburgh County constituted a
unified retail market for beer.
Id. at 1227-1229. These
holdings are not before us. Falls City does not argue, and never
has argued, that "Indiana's consumer-level non-importation law
compels a finding that Evansville and Henderson are separate retail
beer markets." Reply Brief for Petitioner to Supplemental Brief
after Oral Argument 3. Indeed, Falls City's counsel affirmatively
waived this argument in a letter written to the District Court
before trial, App. to Supplemental Brief for Respondent after Oral
Argument. Nor is the broader question whether Indiana and Kentucky
constitute separate markets fairly included within the scope of the
questions presented in Falls City's petition for certiorari.
Counsel for Falls City made this very clear at oral argument,
stating that "I'm not asking this Court to delve into the record to
second-guess that determination by the lower courts." Tr. of Oral
Arg. 5-6.
[
Footnote 8]
Falls City's own sales agent reported that the different prices
charged in the two States accounted -- at least in part -- for the
substantial difference in Vanco's and Dawson Spring's sales
performances. App. 97-98, 157, 166. The local press reported
substantial purchases of beer in Kentucky by Indiana residents. Tr.
114-122, 128. Kentucky retailers located just south of the Indiana
state line on the four-lane highway between Evansville and
Henderson advertised their low prices extensively in the Evansville
media and utilized "drive-in windows" at which customers could
purchase beer without leaving their cars.
E.g., id. at
336. Witnesses testified that they observed cars with Indiana
license plates parked at Henderson County carryout retailers, to
which drivers would return carrying cases of beer.
Id. at
86-112, 629-632. One Indiana resident testified that he purchased
beer in Kentucky because of lower prices there.
Id. at
121-122, 218-222, 229. The District Court also relied on the
differing rates of decline.
See n 4,
supra.
[
Footnote 9]
Except through its rejected Sherman Act claim, Vanco has never
attempted to prove that the competing prices Falls City claims to
have met were themselves illegal, or that Falls City met those
prices knowing them to be unlawful. The plaintiff bears the burden
of proving that the prices met were actually illegal.
Cadigan
v. Texaco, Inc., 492 F.2d 383, 387 (CA9 1974);
National
Dairy Products Corp. v. FTC, 395 F.2d 517, 524 (CA7),
cert. denied, 393 U.S. 977 (1968);
see Standard Oil
Co. v. Brown, 238 F.2d 54, 58, and n. 7 (CA5 1956).
[
Footnote 10]
Indeed, in some circumstances, there may be no other plausible
explanation for persistent "economic" price discrimination.
Cf.
FTC v. Cement Institute, 333 U. S. 683,
333 U. S. 715
(1948) ("the multiple basing point system of delivered prices as
employed by respondents contravened accepted economic principles,
and could only have been maintained through collusion");
Staley, 324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 756
(it "seems inescapable" that basing point system was adopted not to
meet equally low prices of competitors, but to establish
artificially high prices elsewhere).
"Economic" price discrimination consists in selling a product to
different customers at prices that bear different ratios to the
marginal costs of sales to those customers, for example, charging
the same price to two customers despite the fact that the seller
incurs higher costs to serve one than the other, or charging
different prices to two customers despite the fact that the
seller's costs of service are the same. Price discrimination under
the Robinson-Patman Act, however, "is merely a price difference."
FTC v. Anheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U.
S. 536,
363 U. S. 549
(1960).
[
Footnote 11]
"Section 2(b) should not require proof that the seller departed
from a previously uniform price schedule. Such
previous
pricing is not relevant to evaluation of genuine responses to a
current competitive situation."
Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the
Antitrust Laws 182 (1955) (1955 Report) (emphasis in original).
[
Footnote 12]
At least three Courts of Appeals have held that the defense is
not limited to attempts to retain customers.
Cadigan v. Texaco,
Inc., 492 F.2d at 387, and n. 3;
Hanson v. Pittsburgh
Plate Glass Industries, Inc., 482 F.2d 220, 226-227 (CA5
1973),
cert. denied, 414 U.S. 1136 (1974);
Sunshine
Biscuits, Inc. v. FTC, 306 F.2d 48, 51-52 (CA7 1962).
But
see Standard Motor Products, Inc. v. FTC, 265 F.2d 674, 677
(CA2) (defense available only if lower price responds to individual
competitive demand),
cert. denied, 361 U.S. 826
(1959).
[
Footnote 13]
Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U.
S. 231 (1951), is not to the contrary. The Court there
referred to the defense's being available to a seller seeking to
"retain" customers,
id. at
340 U. S. 242,
340 U. S. 249,
340 U. S. 250,
simply because the petitioner had so framed its defense in that
particular case.
Id. at
340 U. S. 234,
340 U. S. 236;
see 1955 Report at 184; Kuenzel & Schiffres, Making
Sense of Robinson-Patman: The Need to Revitalize its Affirmative
Defenses, 62 Va.L.Rev. 1211, 1253-1254 (1976).
[
Footnote 14]
Compare Exquisite Form Brassiere, Inc. v. FTC, 123
U.S.App.D.C. 358, 359, 360 F.2d 492, 493 (1965)
(customer-by-customer response required),
cert. denied,
384 U.S. 959 (1966), and
Standard Motor Products, Inc. v.
FTC, 265 F.2d at 677 (same),
with William Inglis &
Sons Baking Co. v. ITT Continental Baking Co., 668 F.2d 1014,
1046 (CA9 1981) (customer-by-customer response not necessarily
required),
cert. denied, 459 U.S. 825 (1982),
Callaway
Mills Co. v. FTC, 362 F.2d 435, 442 (CA5 1966) (same),
and
Balian Ice Cream Co. v. Arden Farms Co., 231 F.2d 356, 366
(CA9 1955) (same),
cert. denied, 350 U.S. 991 (1956).
[
Footnote 15]
See also Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U.S. at
340 U. S. 247,
n. 13, quoting statement of Herbert A. Bergson, Assistant Attorney
General, at Hearings on S. 236 before a Subcommittee of the Senate
Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 81st Cong., 1st
Sess., 77 (1949) ("
The section presently permits sellers to
justify otherwise forbidden price discriminations on the ground
that the lower prices to one set of buyers were made in good faith
to meet the equally low prices of a competitor'").
[
Footnote 16]
See Rowe at 240 ("a seller's area-wide and blanket
lower price, if made in good faith to meet competitors' lower
prices, may be justified . . . as responsive to an
individual
competitive situation'"). Cf. Maryland Baking Co. v. FTC,
243 F.2d 716, 719 (CA4 1957) (FTC permits competitive area price
variations to avert placing "prices in a straightjacket throughout
the country"); Anheuser-Buch, Inc., 54 F.T.C. 277, 301
(1957) (suggesting that offer of lower price throughout particular
area might be responsive to "individual competitive situation");
C. E. Niehoff & Co., 51 F.T.C. 1114, 1130, 1146 (1955)
(rejecting position that "showing that the seller's discriminations
were temporary and localized in area is an indispensable
prerequisite" to defense).
[
Footnote 17]
See Klein, Meeting Competition by Price Systems Under
§ 2(b) of the Robinson-Patman Act: Problems and Prospects, 16
Antitrust Bull. 213, 233-234, 238 (1971); Kuenzel & Schiffres,
62 Va.L.Rev. at 1244-1249.
[
Footnote 18]
Were the courts below to find that Falls City reasonably
believed that low prices were available to Dawson Springs and other
Kentucky wholesalers from Falls City's competitors, a factfinding
that we decline to address on this record, Falls City could not
easily have eliminated price discrimination between Dawson Springs
and Vanco. In such circumstances, had Falls City raised prices in
Kentucky in lockstep with price increases in Indiana, it would have
lost sales in Kentucky because its competitors would have been
offering far lower prices. Raising its Kentucky prices only in
Henderson County would not only have cost Falls City sales there,
but also might have exposed Falls City to new Robinson-Patman Act
claims, since Dawson Springs competed for sales with wholesalers in
neighboring Kentucky counties. Nor, in such circumstances, could
Falls City reasonably be required to charge Vanco the lower
Kentucky price. Indiana law prohibited Falls City from doing so
without simultaneously offering the same price to all other Indiana
wholesalers. This approach might well have harmed Falls City's
economic interests, since most of Falls City's Indiana sales were
in areas far removed from lower Kentucky prices and
competition.