Id. at 1103. It followed, in his view, that the
agreement was just as plainly anticompetitive as a direct agreement
to raise prices. Consequently,
Page 446 U. S. 646
no further inquiry under the rule of reason,
see National
Society of Professional Engineers v. United States,
435 U. S. 679
(1978), was required in order to establish the agreement's
unlawfulness.
Our cases fully support Judge Blumenfeld's analysis, and
foreclose both of the possible justifications on which the majority
relied. [
Footnote 8] In
Broadcast Music, Inc. v. Columbia Broadcasting System,
Inc., 441 U. S. 1,
441 U. S. 7-8
(1979), we said:
"In construing and applying the Sherman Act's ban against
contracts, conspiracies, and combinations in restraint of trade,
the Court has held that certain agreements or practices are so
'plainly anticompetitive,'
National Society of Professional
Engineers v. United States, 435 U. S. 679,
435 U. S.
692 (1978);
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania,
Inc., 433 U. S. 36,
433 U. S.
50 (1977), and so often ''ack . . . any redeeming
virtue,'
Northern Pac. R. Co. v. United States,
356 U. S.
1,
356 U. S. 5 (1958), that they
are conclusively presumed illegal without further examination under
the rule of reason generally applied in Sherman Act cases.
[
Footnote 9] "
Page 446 U. S. 647
A horizontal agreement to fix prices is the archetypal example
of such a practice. It has long been settled that an agreement to
fix prices is unlawful
per se. It is no excuse that the
prices fixed are themselves reasonable.
See, e.g., United
States v. Trenton Potteries Co., 273 U.
S. 392,
273 U. S.
397-398 (1927);
United States v. Trans-Missouri
Freight Assn., 166 U. S. 290,
166 U. S.
340-341 (1897). In
United States v. Socony-Vacuum
Oil Co., 310 U. S. 150
(1940), we held that an agreement among competitors to engage in a
program of buying surplus gasoline on the spot market in order to
prevent prices from falling sharply was unlawful without any
inquiry into the reasonableness of the program, even though there
was no direct agreement on the actual prices to be maintained. In
the course of the opinion, the Court made clear that
"the machinery employed by a combination for price fixing is
immaterial."
"Under the Sherman Act, a combination formed for the purpose and
with the effect of raising, depressing, fixing, pegging, or
stabilizing the price of a commodity in interstate or foreign
commerce is illegal
per se."
Id. at
310 U. S.
223.
Thus, we have held agreements to be unlawful
per se
that had substantially less direct impact on price than the
agreement alleged in this case. For example, in
Sugar Institute
v. United States, 297 U. S. 553,
297 U. S.
601-602 (1936), the Court held unlawful an agreement to
adhere to previously announced prices and terms of sale, even
though advance price announcements are perfectly lawful and even
though the particular prices and terms were not themselves fixed by
private agreement. Similarly, an agreement among competing firms of
professional engineers to refuse to discuss prices with potential
customers until after negotiations have resulted in the initial
selection of an engineer was held unlawful without requiring
further inquiry.
National Society of Professional Engineers v.
United States, supra at
435 U. S.
692-693. Indeed, a horizontal agreement among
competitors to use a
Page 446 U. S. 648
specific method of quoting prices may be unlawful.
Cf. FTC
v. Cement Institute, 333 U. S. 683,
333 U. S.
690-693 (1948). [
Footnote 10] It is virtually self-evident that extending
interest-free credit for a period of time is equivalent to giving a
discount equal to the value of the use of the purchase price for
that period of time. Thus, credit terms must be characterized as an
inseparable part of the price. [
Footnote 11] An agreement to terminate the practice of
giving credit is thus tantamount to an agreement to eliminate
discounts, and thus falls squarely within the traditional
per
se rule against price fixing. [
Footnote 12] While it
Page 446 U. S. 649
may be that the elimination of a practice of giving variable
discounts will ultimately lead in a competitive market to
corresponding decreases in the invoice price, that is surely not
necessarily to be anticipated. It is more realistic to view an
agreement to eliminate credit sales as extinguishing one form of
competition among the sellers. In any event, when a particular
concerted activity entails an obvious risk of anticompetitive
impact with no apparent potentially redeeming value, the fact that
a practice may turn out to be harmless in a particular set of
circumstances will not prevent its being declared unlawful
per
se.
The majority of the panel of the Court of Appeals suggested,
however, that a horizontal agreement to eliminate credit sales may
remove a barrier to other sellers who may wish to enter the market.
But in any case in which competitors are able to increase the price
level or to curtail production by agreement, it could be argued
that the agreement has the effect of making the market more
attractive to potential new entrants. If that potential justifies
horizontal agreements among competitors imposing one kind of
voluntary restraint or another on their competitive freedom, it
would seem to follow that the more successful an agreement is in
raising the price level, the safer it is from antitrust attack.
Nothing could be more inconsistent with our cases.
Nor can the informing function of the agreement, the increased
price visibility, justify its restraint on the individual
wholesaler's freedom to select his own prices and terms of sale.
For, again, it is obvious that any industry-wide agreement on
prices will result in a more accurate understanding of the terms
offered by all parties to the agreement. As the
Sugar
Institute case demonstrates, however, there is a plain
distinction between the lawful right to publish prices and terms of
sale, on the one hand, and an agreement among competitors
Page 446 U. S. 650
limiting action with respect to the published prices, on the
other.
Thus, under the reasoning of our cases, an agreement among
competing wholesalers to refuse to sell unless the retailer makes
payment in cash either in advance or upon delivery is "plainly
anticompetitive." Since it is merely one form of price fixing, and
since price-fixing agreements have been adjudged to lack any
"redeeming virtue," it is conclusively presumed illegal without
further examination under the rule of reason.
Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed,
and the case is remanded for further proceedings consistent with
this opinion.
It is so ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
Title 28 U.S.C. § 1292(b) provides:
"When a district judge, in making in a civil action an order not
otherwise appealable under this section, shall be of the opinion
that such order involves a controlling question of law as to which
there is substantial ground for difference of opinion and that an
immediate appeal from the order may materially advance the ultimate
termination of the litigation, he shall so state in writing in such
order. The Court of Appeals may thereupon, in its discretion,
permit an appeal to be taken from such order, if application is
made to it within ten days after the entry of the order:
Provided, however, That application for an appeal
hereunder shall not stay proceedings in the district court unless
the district judge or the Court of Appeals or a judge thereof shall
so order."
[
Footnote 2]
In pertinent part, the District Judge's order read as
follows:
"'In the opinion of the Court, this order involves a controlling
question of law, whether an agreement among competitors to
eliminate the extension of trade credit constitutes a
per
se violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. §
1), as to which there is substantial ground for difference of
opinion, and that an immediate appeal from the order will
materially advance the ultimate termination of the litigation since
this issue is central to the conduct of discovery and trial of this
case.'"
App. D to Pet. for Cert
[
Footnote 3]
The District Court had also granted summary judgment against two
plaintiffs for failure to establish injury in fact. Those
plaintiffs appealed separately. The Court of Appeals consolidated
their appeal with the appeal taken pursuant to § 1292(b), and
unanimously reversed that portion of the District Court's order. No
review is sought in this Court of that ruling.
[
Footnote 4]
See Record 152.
[
Footnote 5]
Cal.Bus. & Prof. Code Ann. § 25509 (West Supp.
1980).
[
Footnote 6]
Pet. for Cert. 4.
[
Footnote 7]
Senior District Judge for the District of Connecticut, sitting
by designation.
[
Footnote 8]
Respondents nowhere suggest a procompetitive justification for a
horizontal agreement to fix credit. Their argument is confined to
disputing that settled case law establishes that such an agreement
is unlawful on its face.
[
Footnote 9]
The quotation from
Northern Pacific R. Co. v. United
States, 356 U. S. 1,
356 U. S. 5
(1958), is drawn from the following passage:
"[T]here are certain agreements or practices which, because of
their pernicious effect on competition and lack of any redeeming
virtue, are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable, and therefore
illegal without elaborate inquiry as to the precise harm they have
caused or the business excuse for their use. This principle of
per se unreasonableness not only makes the type of
restraints which are proscribed by the Sherman Act more certain to
the benefit of everyone concerned, but it also avoids the necessity
for an incredibly complicated and prolonged economic investigation
. . . -- an inquiry so often wholly fruitless when undertaken.
Among the practices which the courts have heretofore deemed to be
unlawful in and of themselves are price fixing. . . ."
[
Footnote 10]
The Court there held that an agreement to use a multiple basing
point pricing system was an unfair method of competition prohibited
by § 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 15 U.S.C. §
45, even though the same conduct would also violate § 1 of the
Sherman Act.
[
Footnote 11]
See Fortner Enterprises, Inc. v. United States Steel
Corp., 394 U. S. 495,
394 U. S. 507
(1969).
"In the usual sale on credit the seller, a single individual or
corporation, simply makes an agreement determining when and how
much he will be paid for his product. In such a sale, the credit
may constitute such an inseparable part of the purchase price for
the item that the entire transaction could be considered to involve
only a single product."
See also G. Lamb & C. Shields, Trade Association
Law and Practice 129 (rev. ed.1971) ("Credit terms are increasingly
viewed as elements of price, and any interference with the elements
of price is regarded as illegal
per se under the Sherman
Act").
Cf. P. Areeda, Antitrust Analysis 878 (2d ed.1974)
("To charge cash and credit customers the same price is,
economically speaking, to discriminate against the former");
Hog v.
Ruffner, 1 Black 115,
66 U. S.
118-119 (1861).
[
Footnote 12]
Cf. Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn. v. United States,
268 U. S. 588,
268 U. S. 600
(1925), in which the Court upheld an exchange of information
concerning credit in order to prevent fraud on the members of the
association, but also noted that
"[t]he evidence falls far short of establishing any
understanding on the basis of which credit was to be extended to
customers, or that any cooperation resulted from the distribution
of this information, or that there were any consequences from it
other than such as would naturally ensue from the exercise of the
individual judgment of manufacturers in determining, on the basis
of available information, whether to extend credit or to require
cash or security from any given customer."
See also Swift & Co. v. United States, 196 U.
S. 375,
196 U. S. 392,
196 U. S. 394
(1905);
Wall Products Co. v. National Gypsum
Co., 326 F.
Supp. 295 (ND Cal.1971).