A California statute requires all wine producers and wholesalers
to file fair trade contracts or price schedules with the State. If
a producer has not set prices through a fair trade contract,
wholesalers must post a resale price schedule, and are prohibited
from selling wine to a retailer at other than the price set in a
price schedule or fair trade contract. A wholesaler selling below
the established prices faces fines or license suspension or
revocation. After being charged with selling wine for less than the
prices set by price schedules and also for selling wines for which
no fair trade contract or schedule had been filed, respondent
wholesaler filed suit in the California Court of Appeal asking for
an injunction against the State's wine pricing scheme. The Court of
Appeal ruled that the scheme restrains trade in violation of the
Sherman Act, and granted injunctive relief, rejecting claims that
the scheme was immune from liability under that Act under the
"state action" doctrine of
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341, and was also protected by § 2 of the
Twenty-first Amendment, which prohibits the transportation or
importation of intoxicating liquors into any State for delivery or
use therein in violation of the State's laws.
Held:
1. California's wine pricing system constitutes resale price
maintenance in violation of the Sherman Act, since the wine
producer holds the power to prevent price competition by dictating
the prices charged by wholesalers. And the State's involvement in
the system is insufficient to establish antitrust immunity under
Parker v. Brown, supra. While the system satisfies the
first requirement for such immunity that the challenged restraint
be "one clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as state
policy," it does not meet the other requirement that the policy be
"actively supervised" by the State itself. Under the system, the
State simply authorizes price setting and enforces the prices
established by private parties, and it does not establish prices,
review the reasonableness of price schedules, regulate the terms of
fair trade contracts, monitor market conditions, or engage in any
"pointed reexamination"
Page 445 U. S. 98
of the program. The national policy in favor of competition
cannot be thwarted by casting such a gauzy cloak of state
involvement over what is essentially a private price-fixing
arrangement. Pp.
445 U. S.
102-106.
2. The Twenty-first Amendment does not bar application of the
Sherman Act to California's wine pricing system. Pp.
445 U. S.
106-114.
(a) Although, under that Amendment, States retain substantial
discretion to establish liquor regulations over and above those
governing the importation or sale of liquor and the structure of
the liquor distribution system, those controls may be subject to
the federal commerce power in appropriate situations. Pp.
445 U. S.
106-110.
(b) There is no basis for disagreeing with the view of the
California courts that the asserted state interests behind the
resale price maintenance system of promoting temperance and
protecting small retailers are less substantial than the national
policy in favor of competition. Such view is reasonable, and is
supported by the evidence, there being nothing to indicate that the
wine pricing system helps sustain small retailers or inhibits the
consumption of alcohol by Californians. Pp.
445 U. S.
110-114.
90 Cal. App. 3d
979, 153 Cal. Rptr. 757, affirmed.
POWELL, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which all
other Members joined, except BRENNAN, J., who took no part in the
consideration or decision of the case.
Page 445 U. S. 99
MR. JUSTICE POWELL delivered the opinion of the Court.
In a state court action, respondent Midcal Aluminum, Inc., a
wine distributor, presented a successful antitrust challenge to
California's resale price maintenance and price posting statutes
for the wholesale wine trade. The issue in this case is whether
those state laws are shielded from the Sherman Act by either the
"state action" doctrine of
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341 (1943), or § 2 of the Twenty-first
Amendment.
I
Under § 24866(b) of the California Business and Professions
Code, all wine producers, wholesalers, and rectifiers must file
fair trade contracts or price schedules with the State. [
Footnote 1] If a wine producer has not
set prices through a fair trade contract, wholesalers must post a
resale price schedule for that producer's brands. § 24866(a).
No state-licensed wine merchant may sell wine to a retailer at
other than the price set "either in an effective price schedule or
in an effective fair trade contract. . . ." § 24862 (West
Supp. 1980).
The State is divided into three trading areas for administration
of the wine pricing program. A single fair trade contract or
schedule for each brand sets the terms for all wholesale
transactions in that brand within a given trading area.
§§ 24862, 24864, 24865 (West Supp. 1980). Similarly,
state
Page 445 U. S. 100
regulations provide that the wine prices posted by a single
wholesaler within a trading area bind all wholesalers in that area.
Midcal Aluminum, Inc. v. Rice, 90 Cal. App. 3d
979, 983-984, 153 Cal. Rptr. 757, 760 (1979). A licensee
selling below the established prices faces fines, license
suspension, or outright license revocation. Cal.Bus. &
Prof.Code Ann. § 24880 (West Supp. 1980). [
Footnote 2] The State has no direct control over
wine prices, and it does not review the reasonableness of the
prices set by wine dealers.
Midcal Aluminum, Inc., is a wholesale distributor of wine in
southern California. In July, 1978, the Department of Alcoholic
Beverage Control charged Midcal with selling 27 cases of wine for
less than the prices set by the effective price schedule of the E.
& J. Gallo Winery. The Department also alleged that Midcal sold
wines for which no fair trade contract or schedule had been filed.
Midcal stipulated that the allegations were true and that the State
could fine it or suspend its license for those transgressions. App.
19-20. Midcal then filed a writ of mandate in the California Court
of Appeal for the Third Appellate District asking for an injunction
against the State's wine pricing system.
The Court of Appeal ruled that the wine pricing scheme restrains
trade in violation of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1
et
seq. The court relied entirely on the reasoning in
Rice v.
Alcoholic Beverage Control Appeals Bd., 21 Cal. 3d
431, 579 P.2d 476 (1978), where the California Supreme Court
struck down parallel restrictions on the sale of distilled liquors.
In that case, the court held that, because the State played only a
passive part in liquor pricing, there was no
Parker v.
Brown immunity for the program.
"In the price maintenance program before us, the state plays no
role whatever in setting the retail prices. The
Page 445 U. S. 101
prices are established by the producers according to their own
economic interests, without regard to any actual or potential
anticompetitive effect; the state's role is restricted to enforcing
the prices specified by the producers. There is no control, or
'pointed reexamination,' by the state to insure that the policies
of the Sherman Act are not 'unnecessarily subordinated' to state
policy."
21 Cal. 3d at 445, 579 P.2d at 486.
Rice also rejected the claim that California's liquor
pricing policies were protected by § 2 of the Twenty-first
Amendment, which insulates state regulation of intoxicating liquors
from many federal restrictions. The court determined that the
national policy in favor of competition should prevail over the
state interests in liquor price maintenance -- the promotion of
temperance and the preservation of small retail establishments. The
court emphasized that the California system not only permitted
vertical control of prices by producers, but also frequently
resulted in horizontal price fixing. Under the program, many
comparable brands of liquor were marketed at identical prices.
[
Footnote 3] Referring to
congressional and state legislative studies, the court observed
that resale price maintenance has little positive impact on either
temperance or small retail stores.
See infra at
445 U. S.
112-113.
In the instant case, the State Court of Appeal found the
analysis in
Rice squarely controlling. 90 Cal. App. 3d at
984, 153 Cal. Rptr. at 760. The court ordered the Department of
Alcoholic Beverage Control not to enforce the resale price
maintenance and price posting statutes for the wine trade. The
Department, which in
Rice had not sought certiorari
from
Page 445 U. S. 102
this Court, did not appeal the ruling in this case. [
Footnote 4] An appeal was brought by
the California Retail Liquor Dealers Association, an intervenor.
[
Footnote 5] The California
Supreme Court declined to hear the case, and the Dealers
Association sought certiorari from this Court. We granted the writ,
444 U.S. 824 (1979), and now affirm the decision of the state
court.
II
The threshold question is whether California's plan for wine
pricing violates the Sherman Act. This Court has ruled consistently
that resale price maintenance illegally restrains trade. In
Dr.
Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.
S. 373,
220 U. S. 407
(1911), the Court observed that such arrangements are "designed to
maintain prices . . . and to prevent competition among those who
trade in [competing goods]."
See Albrecht v. Herald Co.,
390 U. S. 145
(1968);
United States v. Parke, Davis & Co.,
362 U. S. 29
(1960);
United States v. A. Schrader's Son, Inc.,
252 U. S. 85
(1920). For many years, however, the Miller-Tydings Act of 1937
permitted the States to authorize resale price maintenance. 50
Stat. 693. The goal of that statute was to allow the States to
protect small retail establishments that Congress thought might
otherwise be driven from the marketplace by large-volume
discounters. But in 1975 that congressional permission was
rescinded. The Consumer Goods Pricing Act of 1975, 89 Stat. 801,
repealed the Miller-Tydings Act and related legislation. [
Footnote 6] Consequently, the Sherman
Act's ban on resale price
Page 445 U. S. 103
maintenance now applies to fair trade contracts unless an
industry or program enjoys a special antitrust immunity.
California's system for wine pricing plainly constitutes resale
price maintenance in violation of the Sherman Act.
Schwegmann
Bros. v. Calvert Corp., 341 U. S. 384
(1951);
see Albrecht v. Herald Co., supra; Kiefer-Stewart Co.
v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, 340 U.
S. 211 (1951);
Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park
& Sons Co., supra. The wine producer holds the power to
prevent price competition by dictating the prices charged by
wholesalers. As Mr. Justice Hughes pointed out in
Dr.
Miles, such vertical control destroys horizontal competition
as effectively as if wholesalers "formed a combination and
endeavored to establish the same restrictions . . . by agreement
with each other." 220 U.S. at
220 U. S. 408.
[
Footnote 7] Moreover, there
can be no claim that the California program is simply intrastate
regulation beyond the reach of the Sherman Act.
See Schwegmann
Bros. v. Calvert Corp., supra; Burke v. Ford, 389 U.
S. 320 (1967) (per curiam).
Thus, we must consider whether the State's involvement in the
price-setting program is sufficient to establish antitrust immunity
under
Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341
(1943). That immunity for state regulatory programs is grounded in
our federal structure.
"In a dual system of government in which, under the
Constitution, the states are sovereign, save only as Congress may
constitutionally subtract from their authority,
Page 445 U. S. 104
an unexpressed purpose to nullify a state's control over its
officers and agents is not lightly to be attributed to
Congress."
Id. at
317 U. S. 351.
In
Parker v. Brown, this Court found in the Sherman Act no
purpose to nullify state powers. Because the Act is directed
against "individual, and not state, action," the Court concluded
that state regulatory programs could not violate it.
Id.
at
317 U. S.
352.
Under the program challenged in
Parker, the State
Agricultural Prorate Advisory Commission authorized the
organization of local cooperatives to develop marketing policies
for the raisin crop. The Court emphasized that the Advisory
Commission, which was appointed by the Governor, had to approve
cooperative policies following public hearings:
"It is the state which has created the machinery for
establishing the prorate program. . . . [I]t is the state, acting
through the Commission, which adopts the program and enforces it. .
. ."
Ibid. In view of this extensive official oversight, the
Court wrote, the Sherman Act did not apply. Without such oversight,
the result could have been different. The Court expressly noted
that
"a state does not give immunity to those who violate the Sherman
Act by authorizing them to violate it, or by declaring that their
action is lawful. . . ."
Id. at
317 U. S.
351.
Several recent decisions have applied
Parker's
analysis. In
Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.
S. 773 (1975), the Court concluded that fee schedules
enforced by a state bar association were not mandated by ethical
standards established by the State Supreme Court. The fee schedules
therefore were not immune from antitrust attack.
"It is not enough that . . . anticompetitive conduct is
'prompted' by state action; rather, anticompetitive activities must
be compelled by direction of the State acting as a sovereign."
Id. at
421 U. S. 791.
Similarly, in
Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.
S. 579 (1976), a majority of the Court found that no
antitrust immunity was conferred when a state agency passively
accepted a public utility's tariff. In contrast, Arizona rules
against lawyer advertising were held immune from Sherman Act
challenge because
Page 445 U. S. 105
they "reflect[ed] a clear articulation of the State's policy
with regard to professional behavior," and were "subject to pointed
reexamination by the policymaker -- the Arizona Supreme Court -- in
enforcement proceedings."
Bates v. State Bar of Arizona,
433 U. S. 350,
433 U. S. 362
(1977).
Only last Term, this Court found antitrust immunity for a
California program requiring state approval of the location of new
automobile dealerships.
New Motor Vehicle Bd. of Cal. v. Orrin
W. Fox Co., 439 U. S. 96
(1978). That program provided that the State would hold a hearing
if an automobile franchisee protested the establishment or
relocation of a competing dealership.
Id. at
439 U. S. 103.
In view of the State's active role, the Court held, the program was
not subject to the Sherman Act. The "clearly articulated and
affirmatively expressed" goal of the state policy was to "displace
unfettered business freedom in the matter of the establishment and
relocation of automobile dealerships."
Id. at
439 U. S.
109.
These decisions establish two standards for antitrust immunity
under
Parker v. Brown. First, the challenged restraint
must be "one clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as
state policy"; second, the policy must be "actively supervised" by
the State itself.
City of Lafayette v. Louisiana Power &
Light Co., 435 U. S. 389,
435 U. S. 410
(1978) (opinion of BRENNAN, J.). [
Footnote 8] The California system for wine pricing
satisfies the first standard. The legislative policy is
forthrightly stated and clear in its purpose to permit resale price
maintenance. The program, however, does not meet the second
requirement for
Parker immunity. The State simply
authorizes price setting and enforces the prices established by
private parties. The State neither establishes prices nor reviews
the reasonableness of the price schedules; nor does it regulate
Page 445 U. S. 106
the terms of fair trade contracts. The State does not monitor
market conditions or engage in any "pointed reexamination" of the
program. [
Footnote 9] The
national policy in favor of competition cannot be thwarted by
casting such a gauzy cloak of state involvement over what is
essentially a private price-fixing arrangement. As Parker
teaches,
"a state does not give immunity to those who violate the Sherman
Act by authorizing them to violate it, or by declaring that their
action is lawful. . . ."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
351.
III
Petitioner contends that, even if California's system of wine
pricing is not protected state action, the Twenty-first Amendment
bars application of the Sherman Act in this case. Section 1 of that
Amendment repealed the Eighteenth Amendment's prohibition on the
manufacture, sale, or transportation of liquor. The second section
reserved to the States certain power to regulate traffic in
liquor:
"The transportation or importation into any State, Territory, or
possession of the United States for delivery or use therein of
intoxicating liquors, in violation of the laws thereof, is hereby
prohibited."
The remaining question before us is whether § 2 permits
California to countermand the congressional policy -- adopted under
the commerce power -- in favor of competition.
A
In determining state powers under the Twenty-first Amendment,
the Court has focused primarily on the language of the
Page 445 U. S. 107
provision, rather than the history behind it.
State Board v.
Young's Market Co., 299 U. S. 59,
299 U. S. 63-64
(1936). [
Footnote 10] In
terms, the Amendment gives the States control over the
"transportation or importation" of liquor into their territories.
Of course, such control logically entails considerable regulatory
power not strictly limited to importing and transporting alcohol.
Ziffrin, Inc. v. Reeves, 308 U. S. 132,
308 U. S. 138
(1939). We should not, however, lose sight of the explicit grant of
authority.
This Court's early decisions on the Twenty-first Amendment
recognized that each State holds great powers over the importation
of liquor from other jurisdictions.
Young's Market, supra,
concerned a license fee for interstate imports of alcohol; another
case focused on a law restricting the types of liquor that could be
imported from other States,
Mahoney v. Joseph Triner
Corp., 304 U. S. 401
(1938); two others
Page 445 U. S. 108
involved "retaliation" statutes barring imports from States that
proscribed shipments of liquor from other States,
Joseph S.
Finch & Co. v. McKittrick, 305 U.
S. 395 (1939);
Indianapolis Brewing Co. v. Liquor
Control Comm'n, 305 U. S. 391
(1939). The Court upheld the challenged state authority in each
case, largely on the basis of the States' special power over the
"importation and transportation" of intoxicating liquors. Yet even
when the States had acted under the explicit terms of the
Amendment, the Court resisted the contention that § 2 "freed
the States from all restrictions upon the police power to be found
in other provisions of the Constitution."
Young's Market,
supra at
299 U. S.
64.
Subsequent decisions have given "wide latitude" to state liquor
regulation,
Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc. v.
Hostetter, 384 U. S. 35,
384 U. S. 42
(1966), but they also have stressed that important federal
interests in liquor matters survived the ratification of the
Twenty-first Amendment. The States cannot tax imported liquor in
violation of the Export-Import Clause.
Department of Revenue v.
James Beam Co., 377 U. S. 341
(1964). Nor can they insulate the liquor industry from the
Fourteenth Amendment's requirements of equal protection,
Craig
v. Boren, 429 U. S. 190,
429 U. S.
204-209 (1976), and due process,
Wisconsin v.
Constantineau, 400 U. S. 433,
400 U. S. 436
(1971).
More difficult to define, however, is the extent to which
Congress can regulate liquor under its interstate commerce power.
Although that power is directly qualified y § 2, the Court has
held that the Federal Government retains some Commerce Clause
authority over liquor. In
William Jameson & Co. v.
Morgenthau, 307 U. S. 171
(1939) (per curiam), this Court found no violation of the
Twenty-first Amendment in a whiskey labeling requirement prescribed
by the Federal Alcohol Administration Act, 49 Stat. 977. And in
Ziffrin, Inc. v. Reeves, supra, the Court did not uphold
Kentucky's system of licensing liquor haulers until it was
satisfied that the state program was reasonable. 308 U.S. at
308 U. S.
139.
Page 445 U. S. 109
The contours of Congress' commerce power over liquor were
sharpened in
Hostetter v. Idlewild Liquor Corp.,
377 U. S. 324,
377 U. S.
331-332 (1964).
"To draw a conclusion . . . that the Twenty-first Amendment has
somehow operated to 'repeal' the Commerce Clause wherever
regulation of intoxicating liquors is concerned would, however, be
an absurd oversimplification. If the Commerce Clause had been
pro tanto 'repealed,' then Congress would be left with no
regulatory power over interstate or foreign commerce in
intoxicating liquor. Such a conclusion would be patently bizarre,
and is demonstrably incorrect."
The Court added a significant, if elementary, observation:
"Both the Twenty-first Amendment and the Commerce Clause are
parts of the same Constitution. Like other provisions of the
Constitution, each must be considered in the light of the other,
and in the context of the issues and interests at stake in any
concrete case."
Id. at
377 U. S. 332.
See Craig v. Boren, supra, at
429 U. S. 206.
[
Footnote 11]
This pragmatic effort to harmonize state and federal powers has
been evident in several decisions where the Court held liquor
companies liable for anticompetitive conduct not mandated by a
State.
See Kiefer-Stewart Co. v. Joseph E. Seagram & Sons,
Inc., 340 U. S. 211
(1951);
United States v. Frankfort Distilleries, Inc.,
324 U. S. 293
(1945). In
Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Corp., 341 U.
S. 384 (1951), for example, a liquor manufacturer
attempted to force a distributor to comply with Louisiana's resale
price maintenance program, a
Page 445 U. S. 110
program similar in many respects to the California system at
issue here. The Court held that, because the Louisiana statute
violated the Sherman Act, it could not be enforced against the
distributor. Fifteen years later, the Court rejected a Sherman Act
challenge to a New York law requiring liquor dealers to attest that
their prices were "no higher than the lowest price" charged
anywhere in the United States.
Joseph E. Seagram & Sons,
Inc. v. Hostetter, supra. The Court concluded that the statute
exerted "no irresistible economic pressure on the [dealers] to
violate the Sherman Act in order to comply," but it also cautioned
that "[n]othing in the Twenty-first Amendment, of course, would
prevent enforcement of the Sherman Act" against an interstate
conspiracy to fix liquor prices.
Id. at
384 U. S. 45-46.
See Burke v. Ford, 389 U. S. 320
(1967) (per curiam).
These decisions demonstrate that there is no bright line between
federal and state powers over liquor. The Twenty-first Amendment
grants the States virtually complete control over whether to permit
importation or sale of liquor and how to structure the liquor
distribution system. Although States retain substantial discretion
to establish other liquor regulations, those controls may be
subject to the federal commerce power in appropriate situations.
The competing state and federal interests can be reconciled only
after careful scrutiny of those concerns in a "concrete case."
Hostetter v. Idlewild Liquor Corp., supra at
377 U. S.
332.
B
The federal interest in enforcing the national policy in favor
of competition is both familiar and substantial.
"Antitrust laws in general, and the Sherman Act in particular,
are the Magna Carta of free enterprise. They are as important to
the preservation of economic freedom and our free enterprise system
as the Bill of Rights is to the protection of our fundamental
personal freedoms. "
Page 445 U. S. 111
United States v. Topco Associates, Inc., 405 U.
S. 596,
405 U. S. 610
(1972).
See Northern Pacific R. Co. v. United States,
356 U. S. 1,
356 U. S. 4
(1958). Although this federal interest is expressed through a
statute, rather than a constitutional provision, Congress
"exercis[ed] all the power it possessed" under the Commerce Clause
when it approved the Sherman Act.
Atlantic Cleaners & Dyers
v. United States, 286 U. S. 427,
286 U. S. 435
(1932);
see City of Lafayette v. Louisiana Power & Light
Co., 435 U.S. at
435 U. S. 398.
We must acknowledge the importance of the Act's procompetition
policy.
The state interests protected by California's resale price
maintenance system were identified by the state courts in this
case, 90 Cal. App. 3d at 983, 153 Cal. Rptr. at 760, and in
Rice v. Alcoholic Beverage Control Appeals Bd., 21 Cal. 3d
at 451, 579 P.2d at 490. [
Footnote 12] Of course, the findings and conclusions of
those courts are not binding on this Court to the extent that they
undercut state rights guaranteed by the Twenty-first Amendment.
See Hooven & Allison Co. v. Evatt, 324 U.
S. 652,
324 U. S. 659
(1945);
Creswill v. Knights of Pythias, 225 U.
S. 246,
225 U. S. 261
(1912). Nevertheless, this Court accords "respectful consideration
and great weight to the views of the state's highest court" on
matters of state law,
Indiana ex rel. Anderson v. Brand,
303 U. S. 95,
303 U. S. 100
(1938), and we customarily accept the factual findings of state
courts in the
Page 445 U. S. 112
absence of "exceptional circumstances."
Lloyd A. Fry Roofing
Co. v. Wood, 344 U. S. 157,
344 U. S. 160
(1952).
The California Court of Appeal stated that its review of the
State's system of wine pricing was "controlled by the reasoning of
the [California] Supreme Court in
Rice [
supra]."
90 Cal. App. 3d at 983, 153 Cal. Rptr. at 760. Therefore, we turn
to that opinion's treatment of the state interests in resale price
maintenance for distilled liquors.
In
Rice, the State Supreme Court found two purposes
behind liquor resale price maintenance -- "to promote temperance
and orderly market conditions." 21 Cal. 3d at 451, 579 P.2d at 490.
[
Footnote 13] The court
found little correlation between resale price maintenance and
temperance. It cited a state study showing a 42 increase in per
capita liquor consumption in California from 1950 to 1972, while
resale price maintenance was in effect.
Id. at 457-458,
579 P.2d at 494, citing California Dept. of Finance, Alcohol and
the State: A Reappraisal of California's Alcohol Control Policies,
xi, 15 (1974). Such studies, the court wrote, "at the very least
raise a doubt regarding the justification for such laws on the
ground that they promote temperance." 21 Cal. 3d at 4575, 579 P.2d
at 494. [
Footnote 14]
The
Rice opinion identified the primary state interest
in orderly market conditions as "protect[ing] small licensees from
predatory pricing policies of large retailers."
Id. at
456, 579 P.2d at 493. [
Footnote
15] In gauging this interest, the court
Page 445 U. S. 113
adopted the views of the Appeals Board of the Alcoholic
Beverages Control Department, which first ruled on the claim in
Rice. The state agency "rejected the argument that fair
trade laws were necessary to the economic survival of small
retailers. . . ."
Ibid. The agency relied on a
congressional study of the impact on small retailers of fair trade
laws enacted under the Miller-Tydings Act. The study revealed that
"states with fair trade laws had a 55 percent higher rate of firm
failures than free trade states, and the rate of growth of small
retail stores in free trade states between 1956 and 1972 was 32 per
cent higher than in states with fair trade laws."
Ibid.,
citing S.Rep. No. 94-466, p. 3 (1975). Pointing to the
congressional abandonment of fair trade in the 1975 Consumer Goods
Pricing Act,
see supra at
445 U. S. 102,
the State Supreme Court found no persuasive justification to
continue "fair trade laws which eliminate price competition among
retailers." 21 Cal. 3d at 457, 579 P.2d at 494. The Court of Appeal
came to the same conclusion with respect to the wholesale wine
trade. 90 Cal. App. 3d at 983, 153 Cal. Rptr. at 760.
We have no basis for disagreeing with the view of the California
courts that the asserted state interests are less substantial than
the national policy in favor of competition. That evaluation of the
resale price maintenance system for wine is reasonable, and is
supported by the evidence cited by the State Supreme Court in
Rice. Nothing in the record in this case suggests that the
wine pricing system helps sustain small retail establishments.
Neither the petitioner nor the State Attorney General in his
amicus brief has demonstrated that the program inhibits
the consumption of alcohol by Californians. We need not consider
whether the legitimate state interests in temperance and the
protection of small retailers
Page 445 U. S. 114
ever could prevail against the undoubted federal interest in a
competitive economy. The unsubstantiated state concerns put forward
in this case simply are not of the same stature as the goals of the
Sherman Act.
We conclude that the California Court of Appeal correctly
decided that the Twenty-first Amendment provides no shelter for the
violation of the Sherman Act caused by the State's wine pricing
program. [
Footnote 16] The
judgment of the California Court of Appeal, Third Appellate
District, is
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN did not take part in the consideration or
decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
The statute provides:
"Each wine grower, wholesaler licensed to sell wine, wine
rectifier, and rectifier shall:"
"(a) Post a schedule of selling prices of wine to retailers or
consumers for which his resale price is not governed by a fair
trade contract made by the person who owns or controls the
brand."
"(b) Make and file a fair trade contract and file a schedule of
resale prices, if he owns or controls a brand of wine resold to
retailers or consumers."
Cal.Bus. & Prof.Code Ann. § 24866 (West 1964).
[
Footnote 2]
Licensees that sell wine below the prices specified in fair
trade contracts or schedules also may be subject to private damages
suits for unfair competition. § 24752 (West 1964).
[
Footnote 3]
The court cited record evidence that, in July, 1976, five
leading brands of gin each sold in California for $4.89 for a fifth
of a gallon, and that five leading brands of Scotch whiskey sold
for either $8.39 or $8.40 a fifth.
Rice v. Alcoholic Beverage
Control Appeals Bd., 21 Cal. 3d at 454, and nn. 14, 16, 579
P.2d at 491-492, and nn. 14, 16.
[
Footnote 4]
The State also did not appeal the decision in
Capiscean
Corp. v. Alcoholic Beverage Control Appeals Bd., 7 Cal. App.
3d 996, 151 Cal. Rptr. 492 (1979), which used the analysis in
Rice to invalidate California's resale price maintenance
scheme for retail wine sales to consumers.
[
Footnote 5]
The California Retail Liquor Dealers Association, a trade
association of independent retail liquor dealers in California,
claims over 3,000 members.
[
Footnote 6]
The congressional Reports accompanying the Consumer Goods
Pricing Act of 1975 noted that repeal of fair trade authority would
not alter whatever power the States hold under the Twenty-first
Amendment to control liquor prices. S.Rep. No. 94-466, p. 2 (1975);
H.R.Rep. No. 94-341, p. 3, n. 2 (1975). We consider the effect of
the Twenty-first Amendment on this case in
445 U.
S. infra.
[
Footnote 7]
In
Rice, the California Supreme Court found direct
evidence that resale price maintenance resulted in horizontal price
fixing.
See supra at
445 U. S. 101,
and n. 3. Although the Court of Appeal made no such specific
finding in this case, the court noted that the wine pricing system
"cannot be upheld for the same reasons the retail price maintenance
provisions were declared invalid in
Rice."
Midcal
Aluminum, Inc. v. Rice, 90 Cal. App. 3d
979, 983, 153 Cal. Rptr. 757, 760 (1979).
[
Footnote 8]
See Norman's On the Waterfront, Inc. v. Wheatley, 444
F.2d 1011, 1018 (CA3 1971);
Asheville Tobacco Bd. v. FTC,
263 F.2d 502, 509-510 (CA4 1959); Note,
Parker v. Brown
Revisited: The State Action Doctrine After
Goldfarb,
Cantor, and
Bates, 77 Colum.L.Rev. 898, 916
(1977).
[
Footnote 9]
The California program contrasts with the approach of those
States that completely control the distribution of liquor within
their boundaries.
E.g., Va.Code §§ 4-15, 4-28
(1979). Such comprehensive regulation would be immune from the
Sherman Act under
Parker v. Brown, since the State would
"displace unfettered business freedom" with its own power.
New
Motor Vehicle Bd. of Cal. v. Orrin W. Fox Co., 439 U. S.
96,
439 U. S. 109
(1978);
see State Board v. Young's Market Co.,
299 U. S. 59,
299 U. S. 63
(1936).
[
Footnote 10]
The approach is supported by sound canons of constitutional
interpretation, and demonstrates a wise reluctance to wade into the
complex currents beneath the congressional proposal of the
Amendment and its ratification in the state conventions. The Senate
sponsor of the Amendment resolution said the purpose of § 2
was "to restore to the States . . . absolute control in effect over
interstate commerce affecting intoxicating liquors. . . ." 76
Cong.Rec. 4143 (1933) (remarks of Sen. Blaine). Yet he also made
statements supporting Midcal's claim that § 2 was designed
only to ensure that "dry" States could not be forced by the Federal
Government to permit the sale of liquor.
See 76 Cong.Rec.
at 4140-4141. The sketchy records of the state conventions reflect
no consensus on the thrust of § 2, although delegates at
several conventions expressed their hope that state regulation of
liquor traffic would begin immediately. E. Brown, Ratification of
the Twenty-first Amendment to the Constitution 104 (1938) (Wilson,
President of Idaho Convention);
id. at 191-192 (Darnall,
President of Maryland Convention);
id. at 247 (Gaylord,
Chairman of Missouri Convention);
id. at 469-473
(resolution adopted at Washington Convention calling for state
action "to regulate the liquor traffic").
See generally
Note, The Effect of the Twenty-first Amendment on State Authority
to Control Intoxicating Liquors, 75 Colum.L.Rev. 1578, 1580 (1975);
Note, Economic Localism in State Alcoholic Beverage Laws --
Experience Under the Twenty-First Amendment, 72 Harv.L.Rev. 1145,
1147 (1959).
[
Footnote 11]
In
Nippert v. Richmond, 327 U.
S. 416 (1946), the Court commented in a footnote:
"[E]ven the commerce in intoxicating liquors, over which the
Twenty-first Amendment gives the States the highest degree of
control, is not altogether beyond the reach of the federal commerce
power, at any rate when the State's regulation squarely conflicts
with regulation imposed by Congress. . . ."
Id. at
327 U. S. 425,
n. 15.
[
Footnote 12]
As the unusual posture of this case reflects, the State of
California has shown less than an enthusiastic interest in its wine
pricing system. As we noted, the state agency responsible for
administering the program did not appeal the decision of the
California Court of Appeal.
See supra at
445 U. S.
101-102; Tr. of Oral Arg. 20. Instead, this action has
been maintained by the California Retail Liquor Dealers
Association, a private intervenor. But neither the intervenor nor
the State Attorney General, who filed a brief
amicus
curiae in support of the legislative scheme, has specified any
state interests protected by the resale price maintenance system
other than those noted in the state court opinions cited in
text.
[
Footnote 13]
The California Court of Appeal found no additional state
interests in the instant case. 90 Cal. App. 3d at 984, 153 Cal.
Rptr. at 760-761. That court rejected the suggestion that the wine
price program was designed to protect the State's wine industry,
pointing out that the statutes "do not distinguish between
California wines and imported wines."
Ibid.
[
Footnote 14]
See Joseph E. Seagram & Sons, Inc. v. Hostetter,
384 U. S. 35,
384 U. S. 39
(1966) (citing study concluding that resale price maintenance in
New York State had "no significant effect upon the consumption of
alcoholic beverages") .
[
Footnote 15]
The California Supreme Court also stated that orderly market
conditions might "reduce excessive consumption, thereby encouraging
temperance." 21 Cal. 3d at 456, 579 P.2d at 493. Since Midcal
requested only injunctive relief from the state court, there is no
question before us involving liability for damages under 15 U.S.C.
§ 15.
[
Footnote 16]
The concern for temperance, however, was considered by the court
as an independent state interest in resale price maintenance for
liquor.