Petitioner provides its employees with in-plant cafeteria and
vending machine services. The services are managed by an
independent caterer, but petitioner has the right to review and
approve the quality, quantity, and prices of the food served. When
petitioner notified respondent union, which represents the
employees, that the cafeteria and vending machine prices were to be
increased, the union requested bargaining over the prices and
services. Petitioner refused to bargain, and the union then filed
an unfair labor practice charge with the National Labor Relations
Board (NLRB), alleging a refusal to bargain contrary to §
8(a)(5) of the National Labor Relations Act (NLRA). The duty of
management and unions to bargain under § 8(a)(5) is defined by
§ 8(d) as the obligation to meet at reasonable times and
confer in good faith with respect to wages, hours, and "other terms
and conditions of employment." Taking its consistent view that
in-plant food prices and services are "other terms and conditions
of employment," the NLRB sustained the charge and ordered
petitioner to bargain. The Court of Appeals enforced the order.
Held: In-plant cafeteria and vending machine food and
beverage prices and services are "terms and conditions of
employment" subject to mandatory collective bargaining under
§§ 8(a)(5) and 8(d) of the NLRA. Pp.
441 U. S.
494-503.
(a) Since Congress has assigned to the NLRB the primary task of
marking out the scope of the statutory language and duty to
bargain, and since the NLRB has special expertise in classifying
bargaining subjects as "terms and conditions of employment," its
judgment as to what is a mandatory bargaining subject is entitled
to considerable deference. Pp.
441 U. S.
494-496.
(b) The NLRB's judgment is subject to judicial review, but if
its construction of the statute is reasonably defensible, it should
not be rejected merely because the courts might prefer another view
of the statute. Here, the NLRB's view is not an unreasonable or
unprincipled construction of the statute and should be accepted and
enforced. Pp.
441 U. S.
497-498.
Page 441 U. S. 489
(c) Including within § 8(d) the prices of in-plant-supplied
food and beverages serves the ends of the NLRA by funneling an area
of common dispute between employers and employees into collective
bargaining. Pp.
441 U. S.
498-500
(d) In-plant food prices and services are an aspect of the
relationship between petitioner and its employees, and no
third-party interest is directly implicated. Therefore, the
standard applied in
Chemical & Alkali Workers v. Pittsburgh
Plate Glass Co., 404 U. S. 157, as
to whether the third-party concern "vitally affects" the "terms and
conditions" of the bargaining unit employees' employment, has no
application. Pp.
441 U. S.
500-501.
(e) Petitioner's argument that in-plant food prices and services
are too trivial to qualify as mandatory bargaining subjects is
without merit, especially where both the NLRB and the bargaining
unit employees have taken a contrary view. P.
441 U. S.
501.
(f) Problems created by constantly shifting food prices can be
anticipated and provided for in the collective bargaining
agreement. To the extent that disputes are likely to be frequent
and intense, more, not less, collective bargaining is the remedy.
Pp.
441 U. S.
501-502.
(g) To require petitioner to bargain over in-plant food service
prices is not futile. Although the prices are set by the
third-party caterer, petitioner retains the right to review and
control such prices. In any event, an employer can always affect
prices by initiating or altering a subsidy to a third-party
supplier, such as that provided by petitioner in this case, and
will typically have the right to change suppliers in the future. P.
441 U. S.
503.
571 F.2d 993, affirmed.
WHITE, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which BURGER,
C.J., and BRENNAN, STEWART, MARSHALL, POWELL, REHNQUIST, and
STEVENS, JJ., joined. POWELL, J., filed a concurring opinion,
post, p.
441 U. S. 503.
BLACKMUN, J., filed an opinion concurring in the result,
post, p.
441 U. S.
504.
Page 441 U. S. 490
MR. JUSTICE WHITE delivered the opinion of the Court.
The principal question [
Footnote
1] in this case is whether prices for in-plant cafeteria and
vending machine food and beverages are "terms and conditions of
employment" subject to mandatory collective bargaining under
§§ 8(a)(5) and 8(d) of the National Labor Relations Act.
49 Stat. 452, a amended, 29 U.S.C. §§ 158(a)(5) and
158(d). [
Footnote 2]
Page 441 U. S. 491
I
Petitioner, Ford Motor Co., operates an automotive parts
stamping plant in Chicago Heights, Ill., employing 3,600 hourly
rated production employees. These employees are represented in
collective bargaining with Ford by the International Union, United
Automobile, Aerospace and Agricultural Implement Workers of
America, and by its administrative component, Local 588, a
respondent here.
For many years, Ford has undertaken to provide in-plant food
services to its Chicago Heights employees. [
Footnote 3] These services, which include both
cafeterias and vending machines, are managed by an independent
caterer, ARA Services, Inc.
Page 441 U. S. 492
Under its contract with Ford, ARA furnishes the food,
management, machines, and personnel in exchange for reimbursement
of all direct costs and a 9% surcharge on net receipts. [
Footnote 4] Ford has the right to
review and approve the quality, quantity, and price of the food
served.
Over the years, Ford and the Union have negotiated about food
services. The National Labor Relations Board (Board) found:
"Since 1967, the local contract has included provisions dealing
with vending and cafeteria services. The contracts have covered the
staffing of service lines, adequate cafeteria supervision,
restocking and repairing vending machines, and menu variety. The
1974 local agreement also states,"
"the Company recognized its continuing responsibility for the
satisfactory performance of the caterer and for the expeditious
handling of complaints concerned with such performance."
Ford Motor Co. (Chicago Stamping Plant), 230 N.L.R.B.
716 (1977),
enf'd, 571 F.2d 993 (CA7 1978). Ford, however,
has always refused to bargain about the prices of food and
beverages served in its in-plant facilities.
On February 6, 1976, Ford notified the Union that cafeteria and
vending machine prices would be increased shortly by unspecified
amounts. The Union requested bargaining over both price and
services and also asked for information relevant to Ford's
involvement in food services in order to assist bargaining. These
requests were refused by Ford, which took the position that food
prices and services are not terms or conditions of employment
subject to mandatory bargaining.
Page 441 U. S. 493
The Union then filed an unfair labor practice charge with the
Board, alleging a refusal to bargain contrary to § 8(a)(5).
[
Footnote 5] The Board
sustained the charge, ordering Ford to bargain on both food prices
and services and to supply the Union with the relevant information
requested.
Ford Motor Co. (Chicago Stamping Plant), supra.
In doing so, the Board reaffirmed its position, expressed in
several prior cases, that prices of in-plant-supplied food and
beverages are generally mandatory bargaining subjects, a position
that had not been accepted by reviewing courts. [
Footnote 6] The Board also noted that the
circumstances of this case made it a particularly strong one for
invoking the duty to bargain. [
Footnote 7]
Page 441 U. S. 494
The case came before the Court of Appeals for the Seventh
Circuit on Ford's petition for review and the Board's
cross-petition for enforcement. That court, while adhering to its
prior decision in
NLRB v. Ladish Co., 538 F.2d 1267
(1976), which had refused enforcement of a Board order to bargain
about in-plant food prices, enforced the Board's order here
because,
"under the facts and circumstances of this case, in-plant
cafeteria and vending machine food prices and services materially
and significantly affect and have an impact upon terms and
conditions of employment, and therefore are mandatory subjects of
bargaining."
571 F.2d at 1000. The court was particularly influenced by the
lack of reasonable eating alternatives for employees, declaring
that
"[t]he food one must pay for and eat as a captive customer
within the employer's plant can be viewed as a physical dimension
of one's working environment."
Ibid.
Because of the importance of the issue and the apparent conflict
between the decision below and decisions of other Circuits,
see n. 6,
supra, we granted certiorari. 439 U.S.
891 (1978). We affirm the judgment of the Court of Appeals for the
Seventh Circuit enforcing the Board's order to bargain.
II
The Board has consistently held that in-plant food prices are
among those terms and conditions of employment defined
Page 441 U. S. 495
§ 8(d) and about which the employer and union must bargain
under § 8(a)(5) and 8(b)(3).
See n 6,
supra. Because it is evident that
Congress assigned to the Board the primary task of construing these
provisions in the course of adjudicating charges of unfair refusals
to bargain, and because the "classification of bargaining subjects
as
terms or conditions of employment' is a matter concerning
which the Board has special expertise," Meat Cutters v. Jewel
Tea Co., 381 U. S. 676,
381 U. S.
685-686 (1965), its judgment as to what is a mandatory
bargaining subject is entitled to considerable deference.
Section 8(a)(5) of the National Labor Relations Act, as
originally enacted, declared it an unfair practice for the employer
to refuse to bargain collectively. Act of July 5, 1935, 49 Stat.
453. Although the Act did not purport to define the subjects of
collective bargaining, § 9(a) made the union selected by a
majority in a bargaining unit the exclusive representative of the
employees for bargaining about "rates of pay, wages, hours of
employment, or other conditions of employment." Under these
provisions, the Board was left with the task of identifying on a
case-by-case basis those "other conditions of employment" over
which management was required to bargain.
In 1947, the Taft-Hartley Act amended the National Labor
Relations Act to obligate unions as well as management to bargain;
and § 8(d) explicitly defined the duty of both sides to
bargain as the obligation to "meet at reasonable times and confer
in good faith with respect to wages, hours, and other terms and
conditions of employment. . . ." 61 Stat. 142, now codified at 29
U.S.C. § 158(d). The original House bill had contained a
specific listing of the issues subject to mandatory bargaining,
H.R. 3020, 80th Cong., 1st Sess., § 2(11) (1947); H.R.Rep. No.
245, 80th Cong., 1st Sess., 22-23, 49 (1947), but this attempt to
"strait-jacke[t]" and to "limit narrowly the subject matters
appropriate for collective bargaining,"
Page 441 U. S. 496
id. at 71 (minority report); [
Footnote 8]
see also 93 Cong.Rec. 3446-3447
(1947) (remarks of Rep. Klein), was rejected in conference in favor
of the more general language adopted by the Senate and now
appearing in § 8(d). S. 1126, 80th Cong., 1st Sess., §
8(d) (1947);
see 93 Cong.Rec. 6444 (1947) (summary report
of Sen. Taft);
cf. H.R.Conf.Rep. No. 510, 80th Cong., 1st
Sess., 8, 34 (1947). It is thus evident that Congress made a
conscious decision to continue its delegation to the Board of the
primary responsibility of marking out the scope of the statutory
language and of the statutory duty to bargain. This case,
therefore, is one of those situations in which we should "recognize
without hesitation the primary function and responsibility of the
Board . . . ,"
NLRB v. Insurance Agents, 361 U.
S. 477,
361 U. S. 499
(1960), which is that
"of applying the general provisions of the Act to the
complexities of industrial life . . . and of '[appraising]
carefully the interests of both sides of any labor-management
controversy in the diverse circumstances of particular cases' from
its special understanding of 'the actualities of industrial
relations.'"
NLRB v. Erie Resistor Corp., 373 U.
S. 221,
373 U. S. 236
(1963), quoting
NLRB v. Steelworkers, 357 U.
S. 357,
357 U. S.
362-363 (1958). [
Footnote 9]
Page 441 U. S. 497
Of course, the judgment of the Board is subject to judicial
review; but if its construction of the statute is reasonably
defensible, it should not be rejected merely because the courts
might prefer another view of the statute.
NLRB v. Iron
Workers, 434 U. S. 335,
434 U. S. 350
(1978). In the past, we have refused enforcement of Board orders
where they had "no reasonable basis in law," either because the
proper legal standard was not applied or because the Board applied
the correct standard but failed to give the plain language of the
standard its ordinary meaning.
Chemical & Alkali Workers v.
Pittsburgh Plate Glass Co., 404 U. S. 157,
404 U. S. 166
(1971). We have also parted company with the Board's interpretation
where it was "fundamentally inconsistent with the structure of the
Act" and an attempt to usurp "major policy decisions properly made
by Congress."
American Ship Building Co. v. NLRB,
380 U. S. 300,
380 U. S. 318
(1965). Similarly, in
NLRB v. Insurance Agent, supra at
361 U. S. 499,
we could not accept the Board's application of the Act where we
were convinced that the Board was moving "into a new area of
regulation which Congress had not committed to it."
The Board is vulnerable on none of these grounds in this case.
Construing and applying the duty to bargain and the language of
§ 8(d), "other terms and conditions of employment," are tasks
lying at the heart of the Board's function. With all due respect to
the Courts of Appeals that have held otherwise, we conclude that
the Board's consistent view that in-plant food prices and services
are mandatory bargaining subjects is not an unreasonable or
unprincipled construction of the statute ,and that it should be
accepted and enforced.
Page 441 U. S. 498
It is not suggested by petitioner that an employee should work a
full 8-hour shift without stopping to eat. It reasonably follows
that the availability of food during working hours and the
conditions under which it is to be consumed are matters of deep
concern to workers, and one need not strain to consider them to be
among those "conditions" of employment that should be subject to
the mutual duty to bargain. By the same token, where the employer
has chosen, apparently in his own interest, to make available a
system of in-plant feeding facilities for his employees, the prices
at which food is offered and other aspects of this service may
reasonably be considered among those subjects about which
management and union must bargain. [
Footnote 10] The terms and conditions under which food is
available on the job are plainly germane to the "working
environment,"
Fibreboard Paper Products Corp. v. NLRB,
379 U. S. 203,
379 U. S. 222
(1964) (STEWART, J., concurring). Furthermore, the company is not
in the business of selling food to its employees, and the
establishment of in-plant food prices is not among those
"managerial decisions, which lie at the core of entrepreneurial
control."
Id. at
379 U. S. 223
(STEWART, J., concurring). The Board is in no sense attempting to
permit the Union to usurp managerial decisionmaking; nor is it
seeking to regulate an area from which Congress intended to exclude
it. Including within § 8(d) the prices of in-plant-supplied
food and beverages would also serve the ends of the National Labor
Relations Act.
"The object of this Act was not to allow governmental regulation
of the terms and conditions of employment, but rather to insure
that employers and their employees could work together to establish
mutually satisfactory conditions. The basic theme of the Act was
that, through collective bargaining, the passions, arguments, and
struggles of prior years would be channeled into constructive,
Page 441 U. S. 499
open discussions leading, it was hoped, to mutual
agreement."
H. K. Porter Co. v. NLRB, 397 U. S.
99,
397 U. S. 103
(1970). As illustrated by the facts of this case, substantial
disputes can arise over the pricing of in-plant-supplied food and
beverages. National labor policy contemplates that areas of common
dispute between employers and employees be funneled into collective
bargaining. The assumption is that this is preferable to allowing
recurring disputes to fester outside the negotiation process until
strikes or other forms of economic warfare occur.
The trend of industrial practice supports this conclusion. In
response to increasing employee concern over the issue, many
contracts are now being negotiated that contain provisions
concerning in-plant food services. [
Footnote 11] In this case, as
Page 441 U. S. 500
already noted, local agreements between Ford and the Union have
contained detailed provisions about nonprice aspects of in-plant
food services for several years. Although not conclusive, current
industrial practice is highly relevant in construing the phrase
"terms and conditions of employment." [
Footnote 12]
III
Ford nevertheless argues against classifying food prices and
services as mandatory bargaining subjects because they do not
"vitally affect" the terms and conditions of employment within
Page 441 U. S. 501
the meaning of the standard assertedly established by
Chemical & Alkali Workers v. Pittsburgh Plate Glass
Co., 404 U.S. at
404 U. S. 176,
and because they are trivial matters over which neither party
should be required to bargain.
There is no merit to either of these arguments. First, Ford has
misconstrued
Pittsburgh Plate Glass. That case made it
clear that, while § 8(d) normally reaches
"only issues that settle an aspect of the relationship between
the employer and employees[,] matters involving individuals outside
the employment relationship . . . are not wholly excluded."
414 U.S. at
414 U. S. 178.
In such instances, as in
Teamsters v. Oliver, 358 U.
S. 283 (1959), and
Fibreboard Paper Products Corp.
v. NLRB, 379 U. S. 203
(1964), the test is not whether the
"third-party concern is antagonistic to or compatible with the
interests of bargaining unit employees, but whether it vitally
affects the 'terms and conditions' of their employment."
404 U.S. at
404 U. S. 179.
Here, however, the matter of in-plant food prices and services is
an aspect of the relationship between Ford and its own employees.
No third-party interest is directly implicated, and the standard of
Pittsburgh Plate Glass has no application.
As for the argument that in-plant food prices and service are
too trivial to qualify as mandatory subjects, the Board has a
contrary view, and we have no basis for rejecting it. It is also
clear that the bargaining unit employees in this case considered
the matter far from trivial, since they pressed an unsuccessful
boycott to secure a voice in setting food prices. They evidently
felt, and common sense also tells us, that even minor increases in
the cost of meals can amount to a substantial sum of money over
time. In any event, we accept the Board's view that in-plant food
prices and service are conditions of employment, and are subject to
the duty to bargain.
Ford also argues that the Board's position will result in
unnecessary disruption because any small change in price or service
will trigger the obligation to bargain. The problem, it
Page 441 U. S. 502
is said, will be particularly acute in situations where several
unions are involved, [
Footnote
13] possibly requiring endless rounds of negotiations over
issues as minor as the price of a cup of coffee or a soft
drink.
These concerns have been thought exaggerated by the Board. Its
position in this case, as in all past cases involving the same
issue, is that it is sufficient compliance with the statutory
mandate if management honors a specific union request for
bargaining about changes that have been made or are to be made.
Ford Motor Co. (Chicago Stamping Plant), 230 N.L.R.B. at
718;
Westinghouse Electric Corp., 156 N.L.R.B. 1080, 1081,
enf'd, 369 F.2d 891 (CA4 1966),
rev'd en banc,
387 F.2d 542 (1967). The Board apparently assumes that, as a
practical matter, requests to bargain will not be lightly made.
Moreover, problems created by constantly shifting food prices can
be anticipated and provided for in the collective bargaining
agreement. Furthermore, if it is true that disputes over food
prices are likely to be frequent and intense, it follows that more,
not less, collective bargaining is the remedy. This is the
assumption of national labor policy, and it is soundly supported by
both reason and experience. [
Footnote 14]
Page 441 U. S. 503
Finally, Ford asserts that to require it to engage in bargaining
over in-plant food service prices would be futile because those
prices are set by a third-party supplier, ARA. It is true that ARA
sets vending machine and cafeteria prices, but under Ford's
contract with ARA, Ford retains the right to review and control
food services and prices. In any event, an employer can always
affect prices by initiating or altering a subsidy to the
third-party supplier such as that provided by Ford in this case,
and will typically have the right to change suppliers at some point
in the future. To this extent the employer holds future, if not
present, leverage over in-plant food services and prices. [
Footnote 15]
We affirm, therefore, the Court of Appeals' judgment upholding
the Board's determination in this case that in-plant food services
and prices are "terms and conditions of employment" subject to
mandatory bargaining under § § 8(a)(6) and 8(d) of the
National Labor Relations Act.
So ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
The National Labor Relation Board's order at issue here directed
petitioner to bargain with respondent Union "with respect to food
services and changes in food prices in [petitioner's in-plant]
vending machines and cafeteria. . . ."
Ford Motor Co. (Chicago
Stamping Plant), 230 N.L.R.B. 716, 719 (1977),
enf'd,
571 F.2d 993 (CA7 1978). The duty to bargain over nonprice aspects
of in-plant food services is thus also at issue here. The Board's
order also obligated petitioner to supply respondent Union with the
information necessary for bargaining. 230 N.L.R.B. at 719. It seems
agreed that, if food prices and service are mandatory bargaining
subjects, the order to furnish information should stand.
See
Detroit Edison Co. v. NLRB, 440 U. S. 301,
440 U. S. 303
(1979).
[
Footnote 2]
The relevant provisions of the National Labor Relations Act are
as follows:
"SEC 8.(a) It shall be an unfair labor practice for an employer
--"
"
* * * *"
"(5) to refuse to bargain collectively with the representatives
of his employees, subject to the provisions of section 9(a)."
"
* * * *"
"(d) For the purposes of this section, to bargain collectively
is the performance of the mutual obligation of the employer and the
representative of the employees to meet at reasonable times and
confer in good faith with respect to wages, hours, and other terms
and conditions of employment, or the negotiation of an agreement,
or any question arising thereunder, and the execution of a written
contract incorporating any agreement reached if requested by either
party, but such obligation does not compel either party to agree to
a proposal or require the making of a concession. . . ."
"
* * * *"
"SEC. 9.(a) Representatives designated or selected for the
purposes of collective bargaining by the majority of the employees
in a unit appropriate for such purposes, shall be the exclusive
representatives of all the employees in such unit for the purposes
of collective bargaining in respect to rates of pay, wages, hours
of employment, or other conditions of employment. . . ."
As amended, 61 Stat. 140, 142, 143.
As originally enacted, the Wagner Act did not define the
subjects of § 8(a)(5)'s obligation to bargain, although §
9(a), which was contained in the Wagner Act, made reference to
"rates of pay, wages, hours of employment, or other conditions of
employment." Section 8(d) was added by the Taft-Hartley amendments
to the Act in 1947, and expressly defined the scope of the duty to
bargain as including "wages, hours, and other terms and conditions
of employment." The relevant details of this development are
discussed
infra at
441 U. S.
495-496.
[
Footnote 3]
It is difficult for employees to eat away from the plant during
their shifts. The lunch period is 30 minutes, and the few
restaurants in the vicinity are all over a mile away, in an area
heavily saturated with industrial plants employing thousands of
workers. As a result, very few of the 3,600 workers leave the plant
during the lunch period. Two 22-minute rest breaks are also
provided during the shifts, but employees are not permitted to
leave the plant then.
Some workers bring food to work. No refrigerated storage
facilities are provided, however, and spoilage and vermin are a
problem, particularly in the summer.
[
Footnote 4]
If receipts exceed ARA's cost plus the 9% surcharge, Ford is
entitled to the excess. If revenues do not meet the costs of the
operation plus the surcharge, the company is obligated to pay ARA
up to $52,000 a year. In recent years, deficits have occurred
often. In meeting the deficits, Ford has thereby subsidized
employee meals and indirectly influenced the price of the food
sold.
[
Footnote 5]
The Union also began a boycott of food services in which more
than half of the employees participated. The boycott ended slightly
more than three months later without any reductions in prices.
[
Footnote 6]
Westinghouse Electric Corp., 156 N.L.R.B. 1080, 1081,
enf'd, 369 F.2d 891 (CA4 1966),
rev'd en banc,
387 F.2d 542 (1967);
McCall Corp., 172 N.L.R.B. 540
(1968),
enf. denied, 432 F.2d 187 (CA4 1970);
Package
Machinery Co., 191 N.L.R.B. 268 (1971),
enf. denied,
457 F.2d 936 (CA1 1972);
Ladish Co., 219 N.L.R.B. 354
(1975),
enf. denied, 538 F.2d 1267 (CA7 1976).
[
Footnote 7]
See Ford Motor Co. (Chicago Stamping Plant), 230
N.L.R.B. at 717-718, n. 11:
"We note that the instant case, on its facts, is in many
respects a stronger case than
Ladish for adhering to our
position. Unlike
Ladish, where the respondent had no input
on prices, the Respondent in this case retains influence over
cafeteria and vending machine prices by its right to review prices
and its leverage of the subsidy agreement. In addition, there also
exists the possibility for the Respondent to make a profit on the
food service operation. Also, since 1967, the parties in this case
have bargained over in-plant food services. No such bargaining
history was present in
Ladish. Moreover, in
Ladish, the court implied that 'brownbagging' is a viable
alternative to purchasing lunch from the commercial food service.
However, in this case, employees have complained about spoilage of
food stored in their lockers until lunch, as well as unsanitary
conditions in the locker room (wherein the Respondent has found it
necessary on occasion to exterminate). Additionally, the employees
have apparently been so concerned with the food pricing that over
half of them participated in a boycott of the Respondent's food
service operations. There was no such labor strife involved in
Ladish. Lastly, in
Ladish, the employees were
represented by seven unions. The court therein projected that each
time the food prices were raised 'the Company could be compelled to
engage in seven rounds of negotiations.' 538 F.2d at 1272. This
fact, the court declared, 'provides a good example of a situation
in which bargaining could be both disruptive of stable relations
and economically wasteful.'
Id. In the instant case,
however, the employees are represented by a single union. While we
adhere to the view that the number of unions representing employees
at a single plant is not a factor in resolving this issue, we
nevertheless note that, even in the court's view, there is no
potential for conflicting union demands in this case."
[
Footnote 8]
The Report declared:
"The appropriate scope of collective bargaining cannot be
determined by a formula; it will inevitably depend upon the
traditions of an industry, the social and political climate at any
given time, the needs of employers and employees, and many related
factors. What are proper subject matters for collective bargaining
should be left in the first instance to employers and trade unions,
and, in the second place, to any administrative agency skilled in
the field and competent to devote the necessary time to a study of
industrial practices and traditions in each industry or area of the
country, subject to review by the courts. It cannot and should not
be straitjacketed by legislative enactment."
H.R.Rep. No. 245, 80th Cong., 1st Sess., 71 (1947) (minority
report).
[
Footnote 9]
See also Chemical & Alkali Workers v. Pittsburgh Plate
Glass Co., 404 U. S. 157,
404 U. S. 178
(1971) ("Section 8(d) of the Act, of course, does not immutably fix
a list of subjects for mandatory bargaining");
East Bay Union
of Machinists v. NLRB, 116 U.S.App.D.C.198, 201, 322 F.2d 411,
414 (1963) (Burger, J.) ("The use of this language was a reflection
of the congressional awareness that the act covered a wide variety
of industrial and commercial activity and a recognition that
collective bargaining must be kept flexible without precise
delineation of what subjects were covered, so that the Act could be
administered to meet changing conditions"),
aff'd sub nom.
Fibreboard Paper Products Corp. v. NLRB, 379 U.
S. 203 (1964).
[
Footnote 10]
We should not be understood as holding that whether in-plant
food services are to be provided where such services do not already
exist is a mandatory bargaining subject. That issue is not involved
here.
[
Footnote 11]
See, e.g., 2 Bureau of National Affairs, Collective
Bargaining (Negotiation and Contracts) 95:421-95:424 (1976).
See also the following arbitration decisions construing
collective bargaining agreements to cover the cost of
employer-supplied food as a condition of employment:
Universal
Form Clamp Co., 68 Lab.Arb. 1223 (Miller, 1977) (cost of
coffee);
Hilton Hotels Corp., 42 Lab.Arb. 1267, 1270-1272
(Hanlon, 1964) (cost and type of meals);
Greater Los Angeles
Zoo Assn., 60 Lab.Arb. 838 (Christopher, 1973) (employer may
not discontinue practice of providing free meals to zoo food
venders when contract provided that there would be no reduction of
employee benefits);
Alpena General Hospital, 50 Lab.Arb.
48 (Jones, 1967), and
Lutheran Medical Center, 44 Lab.Arb.
107 (Wolf, 1964) (free meals are working condition).
A survey conducted by the Bureau of National Affairs' Personnel
Policies Forum found that 54% of the responding companies provided
food services for employees using a lunchroom with vending
machines; 43% of the companies provided cafeterias; and 15%
provided vending machines with snackbar service. BNA, Labor Policy
and Practice Series (Personnel Management) 245:201-245:204 (1976).
The National Industrial Conference Board in 1964 reported that 47%
of the manufacturing companies that responded to a survey provided
cafeteria services, and 55% of the companies subsidized the
operation. Only 8% of the companies reported that they were trying
to operate the cafeterias at a profit. NICB, Personnel Practices in
Factory and Office: Manufacturing, Personnel Policy Study No.194,
pp. 76-77 (1964).
Cf. Fisher, Operating Your Firm's Dining
Area -- Profitably, Administrative Management, Oct.1966, pp. 66-67;
Scheer, The Company Cafeteria, 45 Personnel J. 85-86 (1966);
Feeding the Big Captive Customers, Business Week, Oct. 27, 1975,
pp. 46-54.
Although the decision below by the Seventh Circuit was the first
to uphold the Board's order to bargain about the prices of
in-plant-supplied food services, other aspects of food services
have been found to be covered by § 8(d). These include
improvement in lunchroom equipment and supplies,
Preston
Products Co., 158 N.L.R.B. 322 (1966),
aff'd in relevant
part, 129 U.S.App.D.C.196, 392 F.2d 801 (1967),
cert.
denied, 392 U.S. 906 (1968); coffee break scheduling and
service of free coffee,
Missourian Pub. Co., 216 N.L.R.B.
175, 180 (1975);
D & C Textile Corp., 189 N.L.R.B.
769, 771, 783 (1971);
Fleming Mfg. Co., 119 N.L.R.B. 452,
455 (1957); free meal policy,
O'Land, Inc., d/b/a Ramada Inn
South, 206 N.L.R.B. 210, 214-215 (1973); cancellation of
catering truck service,
Bralco Metals, Inc., 214 N.L.R.B.
143, 146-150 (1974); meal areas,
Hasty Print, Inc., d/b/a
Walker Color Graphics, 227 N.L.R.B. 455, 461 (1976); and
cleanup of lunchroom areas by employees,
Cosmo Graphics,
Inc., 217 N.L.R.B. 1061, 1066 (1975).
And, where no in-plant facilities exist, employers are still
obligated to bargain about meal hours and coffee breaks.
See,
e.g., Fibreboard Paper Products Corp. v. NLRB, 379 U.S. at 222
(STEWART, J., concurring);
Meat Cutters v. Jewel Tea Co.,
381 U. S. 676,
381 U. S. 691
(1965).
[
Footnote 12]
"While not determinative, it is appropriate to look to
industrial bargaining practices in appraising the propriety of
including a particular subject within the scope of mandatory
bargaining.
Labor Board v. American Nat. Ins. Co.,
343 U. S.
395,
343 U. S. 408. Industrial
experience is not only reflective of the interests of labor and
management in the subject matter, but is also indicative of the
amenability of such subjects to the collective bargaining
process."
Fibreboard Paper Products Corp. v. NLRB, supra at
379 U. S.
211.
[
Footnote 13]
This factor is essentially irrelevant to the determination in
this case. The definition of a mandatory collective bargaining
subject does not depend on the number of unions within the
bargaining unit.
Westinghouse Electric Corp., 156 N.L.R.B.
at 1089;
McCall Corp., 172 N.L.R.B. at 547.
[
Footnote 14]
See, e.g., Fibreboard Paper Products Corp. v. NLRB,
supra at 211 ("The Act was framed with an awareness that
refusals to confer and negotiate had been one of the most prolific
causes of industrial strife");
Westinghouse Electric Corp. v.
NLRB, 369 F.2d at 895 ("The underlying philosophy of the Labor
Act is that discussion of issues between labor and management
serves as a valuable prophylactic by removing grievances, real or
fancied, and tends to improve and stabilize labor relations");
see also Cox, The Duty to Bargain in Good Faith, 71
Harv.L.Rev. 1401, 1412 (1958):
"Participation in debate often produces changes in a seemingly
fixed position either because new facts are brought to light or
because the strengths and weaknesses of the several arguments
become apparent. Sometimes the parties hit upon some novel
compromise of an issue which has been thrashed over and over. Much
is gained even by giving each side a better picture of the strength
of the other's convictions. The cost is so slight that the
potential gains easily justify legal compulsion to engage in the
discussion."
[
Footnote 15]
In-plant food services provided by third parties are not unlike
other kinds of benefits, such as health insurance, implicating
outside suppliers. In each case, the employer contracts with a
third party to provide a benefit to employees and, during the term
of the contract, is unable to change the price at which that
benefit is available to the employee except by employee
subsidies.
MR. JUSTICE POWELL, concurring.
The Court today holds that prices for in-plant cafeteria and
vending machine food and beverages are "terms and conditions of
employment" subject to mandatory collective bargaining under the
National Labor Relations Act. Although this view of the Act has
been taken consistently by the National Labor Relations Board, none
of the courts of appeals
Page 441 U. S. 504
has agreed with the absolute approach of the Board. Rather,
these courts in general have taken the position that whether
bargaining with respect to in-plant food service was required
depends upon the facts and circumstances ' of each case. Although
the Court of Appeals for the Seventh Circuit enforced the Board's
order in this case, it did so on a "facts and circumstances"
basis.
I had thought that the case-by-case approach was more likely to
be fair to both employer and union than is the mandatory bargaining
rule adopted today. The conditions and circumstances under which
in-plant food service is provided can and do vary widely among the
thousands of enterprises subject to the Act. Yet, curiously enough,
neither petitioner nor respondent union in this case supports the
"facts and circumstances" approach of the Court of Appeals. On
balance, I suppose there is merit in having a "bright line" with
respect to this issue. This does put the parties to all collective
bargaining on prior notice, with a reasonable expectation that the
issue usually will be resolved in advance at the bargaining table.
I am, therefore, persuaded to join the Court's opinion.
MR JUSTICE BLACKMUN, concurring in the result.
I am in accord with much -- indeed with most -- of what the
Court pronounces in its opinion, and I join its judgment.
My concern is with the last two sentences of the penultimate
paragraph of the Court's opinion.
Ante at
441 U. S. 503.
The Court there says that, "[i]n any event" an employer, by
initiating or altering a subsidy to a third-party supplier, "can
always affect prices," and "will typically have the right to change
suppliers at some point in the future." Thus, to this extent, "the
employer holds future, if not present, leverage over in-plant food
services and prices." To me, this language seems to say that Ford's
control over prices under the facts of this case is really
irrelevant to the "mandatory subject" inquiry, and seems to imply
that an employer must bargain about prices even if he has no actual
control over them at all.
Page 441 U. S. 505
Any employer, of course, could achieve some measure of future
control over prices by initiating a subsidy or by changing
suppliers. That future possibility, however, should not be
enough.
If the employer has no control over prices, bargaining about
them is futile. If the employer rents space in a corner of the
plant to a restaurateur, and thereafter maintains a "hands off"
attitude and has no input into the food operation, it is difficult
for me to see how bargaining about food prices makes any sense. The
employer has no more control over prices by virtue of its landlord
status than it has over prices charged at the hamburger shop across
the street. If the employer really has no control over prices,
moreover, it is not obvious that the prices charged "settle an
aspect of the relationship between the employer and employees,"
Chemical & Alkali Workers v. Pittsburgh Plate Glass
Co., 404 U. S. 157,
404 U. S. 178
(1971), a precondition for mandatory bargaining status. The
pertinent relationship is then between the restaurateur and the
employees. If the employer has no control over prices and services
whatsoever, and if he nevertheless is required to bargain about
them because in the future he might be able to exercise some
control over them, the employer's "managerial decisionmaking" may
well be usurped, and we are close to the basic concern of the
concurrence in
Fibreboard Paper Products Corp. v. NLRB,
379 U. S. 203,
379 U. S. 222
(1964).
I think it is unwise to go out of our way to hold -- if the
Court does so here -- that an employer with no present actual
influence or control over food prices should be forced to bargain
about them because of the mere possibility that he might have
"future leverage." That situation is not presented in this case,
and I see no need for the Court to decide it. For now, I prefer
only a general rule that food prices are mandatorily bargainable so
long as the employer, as here, has some measure of actual influence
over the prices charged.
I thus join the Court in the result it reaches in this case. I
would reserve other situations for another day.