Several major gypsum board manufacturers and various of their
officials were indicted for violations of § 1 of the Sherman
Act by allegedly engaging in a price-fixing conspiracy. One of the
types of actions allegedly taken in formulating and effectuating
the conspiracy was interseller price verification,
i.e.,
the practice of telephoning a competing manufacturer to determine
the price being currently offered on gypsum board to a specific
customer. After some of the defendants pleaded
nolo
contendere and were sentenced, the remaining defendants were
convicted after a trial of some 19 weeks. The Government's case
focused on the interseller price verification charge, which the
defendants defended on the ground that the price information
exchanges were to enable them to take advantage of the "meeting
competition" defense contained in § 2(b) of the Clayton Act,
as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act (which permits a seller to
rebut a
prima facie price discrimination charge by showing
that a lower price to a purchaser was made in good faith to meet an
equally low price of a competitor). On the verification issue, tho
trial judge charged the jury that, if the price information
exchanges were found to have been undertaken in good faith to
comply with the Robinson-Patman Act, verification alone would not
suffice to establish an illegal price-fixing agreement, but that,
if the jury found that the effect of verification was to fix
prices, then the parties would be presumed, as a matter of law, to
have intended that result. The judge further charged that, since
only a single conspiracy was alleged, liability could only be
predicated on the knowing involvement of each defendant, considered
individually, in the conspiracy alleged, the judge having refused
the defendants' requested charge directing the jury to determine
what kind of agreement, if any, existed as to each defendant before
any could be found to be a member of the conspiracy. With respect
to the defendants' evidence as to withdrawal from the conspiracy,
the judge instructed the jury that withdrawal had to be established
by either affirmative notice to every other member of the
conspiracy or by disclosure of the illegal enterprise to law
enforcement officials. The judge
Page 438 U. S. 423
refused the defendants' requested instruction that vigorous
price competition during the period in question could also be
considered as evidence of abandonment of the conspiracy. After all
the testimony had been presented, the jurors were sequestered for
deliberation, and apparently disagreement among them arose. After
approximately seven days of deliberations, the foreman of the jury
informed the judge that he wanted to discuss the jury's condition,
and this resulted, with the parties' consent, in an
ex
parte meeting between the judge and the foreman. Most of the
discussion at the meeting involved the jurors' deteriorating
health, but the foreman also referred to the jury's deadlock; there
followed an exchange strongly suggesting that the foreman may have
carried away from the meeting the impression that the judge wanted
a verdict "one way or the other." The jury rendered its guilty
verdict the following morning. The Court of Appeals reversed the
convictions on various grounds, holding,
inter alia, that
verification of price concessions with competitors for the sole
purpose of taking advantage of the "meeting competition" defense of
§ 2(b) constitutes a "controlling circumstance" precluding
liability under § 1 of the Sherman Act, and thus an
instruction allowing the jury to ignore the defendants' purpose in
engaging in the alleged misconduct could not be sustained.
Held:
1. A defendant's state of mind or intent is an element of a
criminal antitrust offense which must be established by evidence
and inferences drawn therefrom, and cannot be taken from the trier
of fact through reliance on a legal presumption of wrongful intent
from proof of an effect on prices. Since the trial judge's
instruction on the verification issue had this prohibited effect,
it was improper. Pp.
438 U. S.
434-446.
(a) The Sherman Act is not to be construed as mandating a regime
of strict liability crimes; rather, the criminal offenses defined
therein are to be construed as including intent as an element. Pp.
438 U. S.
436-443.
(b) Action undertaken with knowledge of its probable
consequences and having the requisite anticompetitive effects can
be a sufficient predicate for a finding of criminal liability under
the antitrust laws. Where carefully planned and calculated conduct
is being scrutinized in the context of a criminal prosecution, the
perpetrator's knowledge of the anticipated consequences is a
sufficient predicate for a finding of criminal intent. Pp.
438 U. S.
443-446.
2. A good faith belief, rather than an absolute certainty, that
a price concession is being offered to meet an equally low price
offered by a competitor suffices to invoke the § 2(b) defense;
exchanges of price information, even when putatively for the
purpose of Robinson-Patman Act compliance, must remain subject to
close scrutiny under the Sherman
Page 438 U. S. 424
Act. Therefore, the Court of Appeals erred in treating
interseller price verification even as a limited "controlling
circumstance" exception precluding Sherman Act liability. Pp.
438 U. S.
447-459.
3. The
ex parte meeting between the trial judge and the
jury foreman was improper, and the Court of Appeals would have been
justified in reversing the convictions solely because of the risk
that the foreman believed the judge was insisting on a dispositive
verdict. Such a meeting is pregnant with possibilities for error,
since it is difficult to contain, much less to anticipate, the
direction the conversation will take at such a meeting, any
occasion which leads to communication with the whole jury panel
through one juror inevitably risks innocent misstatements of the
law and misinterpretations despite the undisputed good faith of the
participants, and the absence of counsel from the meeting
aggravates the problems of having one juror serve as a conduit for
communication with the whole panel. Here the meeting was allowed to
drift into a supplemental instruction relating to the jury's
obligation to reach a verdict, and counsel were denied any chance
to correct whatever mistaken impression the foreman might have
taken from the meeting. Pp.
438 U. S.
459-462.
4. The trial judge's charge concerning participation in the
conspiracy, although perhaps not completely clear, was sufficient,
but his charge on withdrawal from the conspiracy was erroneous,
since it limited the jury's consideration to only two circumscribed
and arguably impractical methods of demonstrating withdrawal,
rather than permitting consideration of any affirmative acts
inconsistent with the object of the conspiracy and communicated in
a manner reasonably calculated to reach coconspirators. Pp.
438 U.S. 462-465.
550 F.2d 115, affirmed.
BURGER, C J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BRENNAN, MARSHALL, and WHITE, JJ., joined; in all but Part IV of
which STEWART, J., joined; in Parts I, II, V, and a portion of Part
III of which POWELL, J., joined; in Part I and a portion of Part V
of which REHNQUIST, J., joined; and in all but Part II of which
STEVENS, J., joined. POWELL, J., filed an opinion concurring in
part,
post, p.
438 U. S. 469.
REHNQUIST, J.,
post, p.
438 U. S. 471,
and STEVENS, J.,
post, p.
438 U. S. 474,
filed opinions concurring in part and dissenting in part. BLACKMUN,
J., took no part in the consideration or decision of the case.
Page 438 U. S. 426
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE BURGER delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case presents the following questions: (a) whether intent
is an element of a criminal antitrust offense; (b) whether an
exchange of price information for purposes of compliance with the
Robinson-Patman Act is exempt from Sherman Act scrutiny; (c) the
adequacy of jury instructions on membership in and withdrawal from
the alleged conspiracy; and (d) the propriety of an
ex
parte meeting between the trial judge and the foreman of the
jury.
I
Gypsum board, a laminated type of wallboard composed of paper,
vinyl, or other specially treated coverings over a gypsum core, has
in the last 30 years substantially replaced wet plaster as the
primary component of interior walls and ceilings in residential and
commercial construction. The product is essentially fungible;
differences in price, credit terms, and delivery services largely
dictate the purchasers' choice between competing suppliers. Overall
demand, however, is governed by the level of construction activity,
and is only marginally affected by price fluctuations.
The gypsum board industry is highly concentrated, with the
number of producers ranging from 9 to 15 in the period 1960-1973.
The eight largest companies accounted for some 94% of the national
sales, with the seven "single-plant producers" [
Footnote 1] accounting for the remaining 6%. Most
of the major producers and a large number of the single-plant
producers are members of the Gypsum Association, which, since 1930,
has served as a trade association of gypsum board
manufacturers.
Page 438 U. S. 427
A
Beginning in 1966, the Justice Department, as well as the
Federal Trade Commission, became involved in investigations into
possible antitrust violations in the gypsum board industry. In
1971, a grand jury was empaneled and the investigation continued
for an additional 28 months. In late 1973, an indictment was filed
in the United States District Court for the Western District of
Pennsylvania charging six major manufacturers and various of their
corporate officials with violations of § 1 of the Sherman Act,
ch. 647, 26 Stat. 209, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 1. [
Footnote 2]
The indictment charged that the defendants had engaged in a
combination and conspiracy "[b]eginning sometime prior to 1960 and
continuing thereafter at least until sometime in 1973," App. 34, in
restraint of interstate trade and commerce in the manufacture and
sale of gypsum board. The alleged combination and conspiracy
consisted of:
"[A] continuing agreement understanding and concert of action
among the defendants and coconspirators to (a) raise, fix, maintain
and stabilize the prices of gypsum board; (b) fix, maintain and
stabilize the terms and conditions of sale thereof; and (c) adopt
and maintain uniform methods of packaging and handling such gypsum
board."
Ibid.
Page 438 U. S. 428
The indictment proceeded to specify some 13 types of actions
taken by conspirators "[i]n formulating and effectuating" the
combination and conspiracy, the most relevant of which, for our
purposes, is specification (h), which alleged that the
conspirators
"telephoned or otherwise contacted one another to exchange and
discuss current and future published or market prices and published
or standard terms and conditions of sale and to ascertain alleged
deviations therefrom."
The bill of particulars provided additional details about the
continuing nature of the alleged exchanges of competitive
information and the role played by such exchanges in policing
adherence to the various other illegal agreements charged.
B
The first skirmish in the protracted litigation of this case was
a motion for dismissal filed by the defendants alleging that their
due process rights had been denied because of unreasonable
preindictment delay. The District Court, after holding a five-day
evidentiary hearing on the motion, concluded that there was "no
evidence of unreasonable delay on the part of the Government,"
383 F.
Supp. 462, 470 (WD Pa. 1974), and that the defendants were not
"prejudiced to any extraordinary degree whatsoever by the chain of
events leading to this indictment."
Ibid. The District
Court denied a motion to dismiss the indictment. Thereafter, nine
of the defendants entered pleas of
nolo contendere and
were sentenced. [
Footnote 3]
The trial of the remaining seven defendants commenced on March 3,
1975, and lasted some 19 weeks.
Page 438 U. S. 429
The focus of the Government's price-fixing case at trial was
interseller price verification -- that is, the practice allegedly
followed by the gypsum board manufacturers of telephoning a
competing producer to determine the price currently being offered
on gypsum board to a specific customer. The Government contended
that these price exchanges were part of an agreement among the
defendants, had the effect of stabilizing prices and policing
agreed-upon price increases, and were undertaken on a frequent
basis until sometime in 1973. Defendants disputed both the scope
and duration of the verification activities, and further maintained
that those exchanges of price information which did occur were for
the purposes of complying with the Robinson-Patman Act [
Footnote 4] and preventing customer
fraud. These purposes, in defendants' view, brought the disputed
communications among competitors within a "controlling
circumstance" exception to Sherman Act liability -- at the extreme,
precluding, as a matter of law, consideration of verification by
the jury in determining defendants' guilt on the price-fixing
charge, and, at the minimum, making the defendants' purposes in
engaging in such communications a threshold factual question.
The instructions on the verification issue given by the trial
judge provided that, if the exchanges of price information were
deemed by the jury to have been undertaken "in a good faith effort
to comply with the Robinson-Patman Act," verification, standing
alone, would not be sufficient to establish an illegal price-fixing
agreement. The paragraphs immediately following, however, provided
that the purpose was essentially irrelevant if the jury found that
the effect of verification was to raise,
Page 438 U. S. 430
fix, maintain, or stabilize prices. The instructions on
verification closed with the observation:
"The law presumes that a person intends the necessary and
natural consequences of his acts. Therefore, if the effect of the
exchanges of pricing information was to raise, fix, maintain, and
stabilize prices, then the parties to them are presumed, as a
matter of law, to have intended that result."
The aspects of the charge dealing with the Government's burden
in linking a particular defendant to the conspiracy, and the kinds
of evidence the jury could properly consider in determining if one
or more of the alleged conspirators had withdrawn from or abandoned
the conspiracy were also a subject of some dispute between the
judge and defense counsel. On the former, the disagreement was
essentially over the proper specificity of the charge. Defendants
requested a charge directing the jury to determine "what kind of
agreement or understanding, if any, existed as to each defendant"
before any could be found to be a member of the conspiracy. The
trial judge was unwilling to give this precise instruction, and
instead emphasized at several points in the charge the jury's
obligation to consider the evidence regarding the involvement of
each defendant individually, and to find, as a precondition to
liability, that each defendant was a knowing participant in the
alleged conspiracy. [
Footnote
5]
On the matter of withdrawal from the conspiracy, defendants
sought an instruction stating explicitly that evidence of vigorous
price competition during the period covered by the indictment could
be considered by the jury as indicating abandonment of the charged
conspiracy by one or more of the defendants. Substantial evidence
on this subject had been
Page 438 U. S. 431
presented by the defendants in the course of the trial. The
judge again was unwilling to accept defendants' construction of the
applicable law, and substituted an instruction specifying that
withdrawal had to be established by either affirmative notice to
each other member of the conspiracy or by disclosure of the illegal
enterprise to law enforcement officials. The trial judge allowed
the defendants to argue their theory of withdrawal to the jury
despite his unwillingness to refer to it explicitly in his
charge.
C
The jury retired to deliberate early on the evening of Tuesday,
July 8, 1975. Supplemental instructions were given in response to
questions from the jury on Wednesday and Thursday, and the hours of
deliberation were shortened on Friday after the court was informed
that some of the jurors were exhausted, and not feeling well. On
Saturday, after responding to further requests from the jury, the
judge,
sua sponte, in open court, used the supplemental
instruction approved by the Court of Appeals [
Footnote 6] to remind the jurors of their
obligation to continue the deliberations. Essentially the same
instruction was given to the jury again on Sunday, after the judge
had received a note detailing the jury's inability to reach a
unanimous verdict.
On Monday, the court received yet another note from the jury,
this time stating that the foreman wished to "discuss the condition
of the Jury" and to seek "further guidance" from the judge. The
judge suggested to counsel that he confer privately with the
foreman and that a transcript of the meeting be kept, but
impounded. The judge indicated that, if his suggestion was rejected
he would simply deny the foreman's request for the meeting. In
response to questions from counsel, the judge stated that the
purpose of the meeting would be to determine if the jury was in
serious physical condition, and
Page 438 U. S. 432
he further indicated that no instructions on the law would be
given to the foreman without calling in the jury and instructing
them in open court with counsel present. [
Footnote 7] After further discussion, all counsel
agreed, albeit somewhat reluctantly, to the proposed meeting.
Most of the discussion between the jury foreman and the judge
concerned the deteriorating state of health of the jurors after
almost five months on the case followed by five days of intensive
deliberations and the existence of personality conflicts among the
members of the panel. The foreman also stressed at least twice
during the conversation with the judge his belief that the jury was
unable to reach a verdict, and that further discussion would not
eliminate the disagreements which existed. The judge indicated
that, while he would take into consideration what the foreman had
said, he wanted the jury to continue its deliberations. Near the
close of the meeting, the following colloquy took place:
"THE COURT. I would like to ask the jurors to continue their
deliberations, and I will take into consideration what you have
told me. That is all I can say."
"MR. RUSSELL. I appreciate it. It is a situation I don't know
how to help you get what you are after."
"THE COURT. Oh, I am not after anything."
"MR. RUSSELL. You are after a verdict one way or the other."
"THE COURT. Which way it goes doesn't make any difference to me.
[
Footnote 8]"
Shortly thereafter, the foreman returned to the jury room and
deliberations continued. The judge then informed counsel, in
abbreviated fashion, what had transpired at the meeting with the
foreman, and of his direction that the deliberations
Page 438 U. S. 433
continue. [
Footnote 9]
Defense counsel asked to see the transcript of the
in
camera meeting, and moved for a mistrial because of the jury's
apparent deadlock. These requests were denied, [
Footnote 10] although the judge indicated
that, if no verdict were rendered by the following Friday, he would
then reconsider the mistrial motions. The following morning, the
jury returned guilty verdicts against each of the defendants.
D
The Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit reversed the
convictions. 550 F.2d 115 (1977). The panel was unanimous in its
rejection of the claim of preindictment delay, but divided over the
proper disposition of the remaining issues.
Two judges agreed that the trial judge erred in instructing the
jury that an effect on prices resulting from an agreement to
exchange price information made out a Sherman Act violation
regardless of whether respondents' sole purpose in engaging in such
exchanges was to establish a defense to price discrimination
charges. Instead, they regarded such a purpose, if certain
conditions were met, [
Footnote
11] as constituting a "controlling
Page 438 U. S. 434
circumstance" which, under
United States v. Container
Corp., 393 U. S. 333
(1969), would excuse what might otherwise constitute an antitrust
violation. One judge considered the instructions regarding the
purpose and scope of the conspiracy and the kinds of conduct
necessary to demonstrate a withdrawal therefrom to be infirm, while
another concluded that the convictions should be reversed because
the trial judge "improperly induced" the jury into reaching a
verdict during the
in camera conversation with the
foreman.
One judge, in dissent, would have sustained the convictions. He
regarded the charge on verification to be consistent with
Container Corp., and rejected the notion that the
Robinson-Patman Act required the exchange of price information even
in the limited circumstances identified by the majority. Neither of
the alleged infirmities in the general conspiracy instructions, in
his view, afforded any basis for reversal, and he disagreed with
the characterization of the trial judge's conduct as coercing a
verdict.
We granted certiorari, 434 U.S. 815 (1977), and we affirm.
II
We turn first to consider the jury instructions regarding the
elements of the price-fixing offense charged in the indictment.
Although the trial judge's instructions on the price-fixing issue
are not without ambiguity, it seems reasonably clear that he
regarded an effect on prices as the crucial element of the charged
offense. The jury was instructed that, if it found interseller
verification had the effect of raising, fixing, maintaining, or
stabilizing the price of gypsum board, then such verification could
be considered as evidence of an agreement to so affect prices. They
were further charged, and it is this point which gives rise to our
present concern, that,
"if the effect of the exchanges of pricing information was to
raise, fix, maintain, and stabilize prices, then the parties to
them are presumed,
as a matter of law, to have intended
that result."
App. 1722. (Emphasis added.)
Page 438 U. S. 435
The Government characterizes this charge as entirely consistent
with
"this Court's longstanding rule that an agreement among sellers
to exchange information on current offering prices violates Section
1 of the Sherman Act if it has either the purpose or the effect of
stabilizing prices,"
Reply Brief for United States 1, and relies primarily on our
decision in
United States v. Container Corp., supra, a
civil case, to support its position.
See also American Column
& Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.
S. 377 (1921);
United States v. American Linseed Oil
Co., 262 U. S. 371
(1923);
Maple Flooring Mfg. Assn. v. United States,
268 U. S. 563
(1925);
Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn. v. United States,
268 U. S. 588
(1925). In this view, the trial court's instructions would not be
erroneous, even if interpreted, as they were by the Court of
Appeals, to
direct the jury to convict if it found that
verification had an effect on prices, regardless of the purpose of
the respondents. The Court of Appeals rejected the Government's
"effects alone" test, holding instead that, in certain limited
circumstances, a purpose of complying with the Robinson-Patman Act
would constitute a controlling circumstance excusing Sherman Act
liability, and hence an instruction allowing the jury to ignore
purpose could not be sustained.
We agree with the Court of Appeals that an effect on prices,
without more, will not support a criminal conviction under the
Sherman Act, but we do not base that conclusion on the existence of
any conflict between the requirements of the Robinson-Patman and
the Sherman Acts. [
Footnote
12] Rather, we hold that a defendant's state of mind or intent
is an element of a criminal antitrust offense which must be
established by evidence and inferences drawn therefrom, and cannot
be taken from the trier of fact through reliance on a legal
presumption of wrongful intent from proof of an effect on prices.
Cf. Morissette v. United States, 342 U.
S. 246,
342 U. S.
274-275 (1952). Since the challenged instruction, as we
read it, had this prohibited
Page 438 U. S. 436
effect, it is disapproved. We are unwilling to construe the
Sherman Act as mandating a regime of strict liability criminal
offenses. [
Footnote 13]
A
We start with the familiar proposition that "[t]he existence of
a
mens rea is the rule of, rather than the exception to,
the principles of Anglo-American criminal jurisprudence."
Dennis v. United States, 341 U. S. 494,
341 U. S. 500
(1951).
See also United States v. Freed, 401 U.
S. 601,
401 U. S. 613
(1971) (BRENNAN, J., concurring in judgment);
United States v.
Balint, 258 U. S. 250,
258 U. S.
251-253 (1922). In a much-cited passage in
Morissette v. United States, supra at
342 U. S.
250-251, Mr. Justice Jackson, speaking for the Court,
observed:
"The contention that an injury can amount to a crime only when
inflicted by intention is no provincial or transient notion. It is
as universal and persistent in mature systems of law as belief in
freedom of the human will and a consequent ability and duty of the
normal individual to choose between good and evil. A relation
between some mental element and punishment for a harmful act is
almost as instinctive as the child's familiar exculpatory 'But I
didn't mean to,' and has afforded the rational basis for a tardy
and unfinished substitution of deterrence and reformation in place
of retaliation and vengeance as the motivation for public
prosecution. Unqualified acceptance of this doctrine by English
common
Page 438 U. S. 437
law in the Eighteenth Century was indicated by Blackstone's
sweeping statement that, to constitute any crime, there must first
be a 'vicious will.'"
(Footnotes omitted.) Although Blackstone's requisite "vicious
will" has been replaced by more sophisticated and less colorful
characterizations of the mental state required to support
criminality,
see ALI, Model Penal Code § 2.02
(Prop.Off.Draft 1962), intent generally remains an indispensable
element of a criminal offense. This is as true in a sophisticated
criminal antitrust case as in one involving any other criminal
offense.
This Court, in keeping with the common law tradition and with
the general injunction that "ambiguity concerning the ambit of
criminal statutes should be resolved in favor of lenity,"
Rewis
v. United States, 401 U. S. 808,
401 U. S. 812
(1971), has on a number of occasions read a state-of-mind component
into an offense even when the statutory definition did not in terms
so provide.
See, e.g., Morissette v. United States, supra.
Cf. Lambert v. California, 355 U.
S. 225 (1957). Indeed, the holding in
Morissette can be fairly read as establishing, at least
with regard to crimes having their origin in the common law, an
interpretative presumption that
mens rea is required.
"[M]ere omission . . . of intent [in the statute] will not be
construed as eliminating that element from the crimes denounced";
instead Congress will be presumed to have legislated against the
background of our traditional legal concepts which render intent a
critical factor, and "absence of contrary direction [will] be taken
as satisfaction with widely accepted definitions, not as a
departure from them." 342 U.S. at
342 U. S.
263.
While strict liability offenses are not unknown to the criminal
law, and do not invariably offend constitutional requirements,
see Shevlin-Carpenter Co. v. Minnesota, 218 U. S.
57 (1910), the limited circumstances in which Congress
has created and this Court has recognized such offenses,
see
e.g.,
Page 438 U. S. 438
United States v. Balint, supra; United States v.
Behrman, 258 U. S. 280
(1922);
United States v. Dotterweich, 320 U.
S. 277 (1943);
United States v. Freed, supra,
attest to their generally disfavored status.
See generally
ALI, Model Penal Code, Comment on § 2.05, p. 140 (Tent. Draft
No. 4, 1955); W. LaFave & A. Scott, Criminal Law 222-223
(1972). Certainly far more than the simple omission of the
appropriate phrase from the statutory definition is necessary to
justify dispensing with an intent requirement. In the context of
the Sherman Act, this generally inhospitable attitude to
non-
mens rea offenses is reinforced by an array of
considerations arguing against treating antitrust violations as
strict liability crimes.
B
The Sherman Act, unlike most traditional criminal statutes, does
not, in clear and categorical terms, precisely identify the conduct
which it proscribes. [
Footnote
14] Both civil remedies and criminal sanctions are authorized
with regard to the same generalized definitions of the conduct
proscribed -- restraints of trade or commerce and illegal
monopolization -- without reference to or mention of intent or
state of mind. Nor has judicial elaboration of the Act always
yielded the clear and definitive rules of conduct which the statute
omits; instead open-ended and fact-specific standards like the
"rule of reason" have been applied to broad classes of conduct
falling within the purview of the Act's general provisions.
See, e.g., Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U. S.
1,
221 U. S. 60
(1911);
United
Page 438 U. S. 439
States v. Topco Associates, 405 U.
S. 596,
405 U. S. 607
(1972);
Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc.,
433 U. S. 36,
433 U. S. 49
(1977). Simply put, the Act has not been interpreted as if it were
primarily a criminal statute; it has been construed to have a
"generality and adaptability comparable to that found to be
desirable in constitutional provisions."
Appalachian Coals,
Inc. v. United States, 288 U. S. 344,
288 U. S.
359-360 (1933).
See generally 2 P. Areeda &
D. Turner, Antitrust Law § 310 (1978).
Although, in
Nash v. United States, 229 U.
S. 373,
229 U. S.
376-378 (1913), the Court held that the indeterminacy of
the Sherman Act's standards did not constitute a fatal
constitutional objection to their criminal enforcement,
nevertheless, this factor has been deemed particularly relevant by
those charged with enforcing the Act in accommodating its criminal
and remedial sanctions. The 1955 Report of the Attorney General's
National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws concluded that the
criminal provisions of the Act should be reserved for those
circumstances where the law was relatively clear and the conduct
egregious:
"The Sherman Act, inevitably perhaps, is couched in language
broad and general. Modern business patterns, moreover, are so
complex that market effects of proposed conduct are only
imprecisely predictable. Thus, it may be difficult for today's
businessman to tell in advance whether projected actions will run
afoul of the Sherman Act's criminal strictures. With this hazard in
mind, we believe that criminal process should be used only where
the law is clear and the facts reveal a flagrant offense and plain
intent unreasonably to restrain trade."
Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the
Antitrust Laws 349 (1955). The Antitrust Division of the Justice
Department took a similar, though slightly more moderate, position
in its enforcement
Page 438 U. S. 440
guidelines issued contemporaneously with the 1955 Report of the
Attorney General's Committee:
"In general, the following types of offenses are prosecuted
criminally: (1) price-fixing; (2) other violations of the Sherman
Act where there is proof of a specific intent to restrain trade or
to monopolize; (3) a less easily defined category of cases which
might generally be described as involving proof of use of predatory
practices (boycotts for example) to accomplish the objective of the
combination or conspiracy; (4) the fact that a defendant has
previously been convicted of or adjudged to have been, violating
the antitrust laws may warrant indictment for a second offense. . .
. The Division feels free to seek an indictment in any case where a
prospective defendant has knowledge that practices similar to those
in which he is engaging have been held to be in violation of the
Sherman Act in a prior civil suit against other persons. [
Footnote 15]"
Id. at 350.
While not dispositive of the question now before us, the
recommendations of the Attorney General's Committee and the
guidelines promulgated by the Justice Department highlight the same
basic concerns which are manifested in our general requirement of
mens rea in criminal statutes and suggest that these
concerns are at least equally salient in the antitrust context.
Close attention to the type of conduct regulated by the Sherman
Act buttresses this conclusion. With certain exceptions for conduct
regarded as
per se illegal because of its unquestionably
anticompetitive effects,
see, e.g., United States v.
Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U. S. 150
(1940), the behavior
Page 438 U. S. 441
proscribed by the Act is often difficult to distinguish from the
gray zone of socially acceptable and economically justifiable
business conduct. Indeed, the type of conduct charged in the
indictment in this case -- the exchange of price information among
competitors -- is illustrative in this regard. [
Footnote 16] The imposition of criminal
liability on a corporate official, or for that matter on a
corporation directly, for engaging in such conduct which only after
the fact is determined to violate the statute because of
anticompetitive effects, without inquiring into the intent with
which it was undertaken, holds out the distinct possibility of
overdeterrence; salutary and procompetitive conduct lying close to
the borderline of impermissible conduct might be shunned by
businessmen who chose to be excessively cautious in the face of
uncertainty regarding possible exposure to criminal punishment for
even a good faith error of judgment. [
Footnote 17]
See 2 P. Areeda & D. Turner,
Antitrust Law 29
Page 438 U. S. 442
(1978); R. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 78 (1978); Kadish, Some
Observations On the Use of Criminal Sanctions in Enforcing Economic
Regulations, 30 U.Chi.L.Rev. 423, 441-442 (1963). Further, the use
of criminal sanctions in such circumstances would be difficult to
square with the generally accepted functions of the criminal law.
See Hart, The Aims of the Criminal Law, 23 Law &
Contemp. Prob. 401, 422-425 (1958); ALI, Model Penal Code, Comment
on § 2.05, p. 140 (Tent. Draft No. 4, 1955). The criminal
sanctions would be used not to punish conscious and calculated
wrongdoing at odds with statutory proscriptions, but instead simply
to regulate business practices regardless of the intent with which
they were undertaken. While, in certain cases, we have imputed a
regulatory purpose to Congress in choosing to employ criminal
sanctions,
see, e.g., United States v. Balint,
258 U. S. 250
(192), the availability of a range of nonpenal alternatives to the
criminal sanctions of the Sherman Act negates the imputation of any
such purpose to Congress in the instant context. [
Footnote 18]
See generally Baker,
To Indict or Not To Indict:
Page 438 U. S. 443
Prosecutorial Discretion in Sherman Act Enforcement, 63 Cornell
L.Rev. 405 (1978).
For these reasons, we conclude that the criminal offenses
defined by the Sherman Act should be construed as including intent
as an element. [
Footnote
19]
C
Having concluded that intent is a necessary element of a
criminal antitrust violation, the task remaining is to treat the
practical aspects of this requirement. [
Footnote 20] As we have noted, the language of the Act
provides minimal assistance in determining what standard of intent
is appropriate, and the sparse legislative
Page 438 U. S. 444
history of the criminal provisions is similarly unhelpful. We
must therefore turn to more general sources and traditional
understandings of the nature of the element of intent in the
criminal law. In so doing, we must try to avoid "the variety,
disparity and confusion" of judicial definitions of the "requisite
but elusive mental element" of criminal offenses.
Morissette v.
United States, 342 U.S. at
342 U. S.
252.
The ALI Model Penal Code is one source of guidance upon which
the Court has relied to illuminate questions of this type.
Cf.
Leary v. United States, 395 U. S. 6,
395 U. S. 46 n.
93 (1969);
Turner v. United States, 396 U.
S. 398,
396 U. S. 416
n. 29 (1970). Recognizing that "
mens rea is not a unitary
concept,"
United States v. Freed, 401 U.S. at
401 U. S. 613
(BRENNAN, J., concurring in judgment), the Code enumerates four
possible levels of intent -- purpose, knowledge, recklessness, and
negligence. In dealing with the kinds of business decisions upon
which the antitrust laws focus, the concepts of recklessness and
negligence have no place. Our question, instead, is whether a
criminal violation of the antitrust laws requires, in addition to
proof of anticompetitive effects, a demonstration that the disputed
conduct was undertaken with the "conscious object" of producing
such effects, or whether it is sufficient that the conduct is shown
to have been undertaken with knowledge that the proscribed effects
would most likely follow. While the difference between these
formulations is a narrow one,
see ALI, Model Penal Code,
Comment on § 2.02, p. 125 (Tent.Draft No. 4, 1955), we
conclude that action undertaken with knowledge of its probable
consequences and having the requisite anticompetitive effects can
be a sufficient predicate for a finding of criminal liability under
the antitrust laws. [
Footnote
21]
Page 438 U. S. 445
Several considerations fortify this conclusion. The element of
intent in the criminal law has traditionally been viewed as a
bifurcated concept embracing either the specific requirement of
purpose or the more general one of knowledge or awareness.
"[I]t is now generally accepted that a person who acts (or omits
to act) intends a result of his act (or omission) under two quite
different circumstances: (1) when he consciously desires that
result, whatever the likelihood of that result happening from his
conduct; and (2) when he knows that the result is practically
certain to follow from his conduct, whatever his desire may be as
to that result."
W. LaFave & A. Scott, Criminal Law 196 (1972).
See
also G. Williams, Criminal Law: The General Part §§
16, 18 (2d ed.1961); Cook, Act, Intention, and Motive in the
Criminal Law, 26 Yale L.J. 645, 653-65 (1917); Perkins, A Rationale
of
Mens Rea, 52 Harv.L.Rev. 905, 910-911 (1939). Generally
this limited distinction between knowledge and purpose has not been
considered important, since "there is good reason for imposing
liability whether the defendant desired or merely knew of the
practical certainty of the results." LaFave & Scott,
supra at 197.
See also ALI, Model Penal Code,
Comment on § 2.02, p. 125 (Tent.Draft No. 4, 1955). In either
circumstance, the defendants are consciously behaving in a way the
law prohibits, and such conduct is a fitting object of criminal
punishment.
See 1 Working Papers of the National
Commission on Reform of Federal Criminal Laws 124 (1970).
Nothing in our analysis of the Sherman Act persuades us that
this general understanding of intent should not be applied to
criminal antitrust violations such as charged here. The business
behavior which is likely to give rise to criminal antitrust charges
is conscious behavior normally undertaken
Page 438 U. S. 446
only after a full consideration of the desired results and a
weighing of the costs, benefits, and risks. A requirement of proof
not only of this knowledge of likely effects, but also of a
conscious desire to bring them to fruition or to violate the law
would seem, particularly in such a context, both unnecessarily
cumulative and unduly burdensome. Where carefully planned and
calculated conduct is being scrutinized in the context of a
criminal prosecution, the perpetrator's knowledge of the
anticipated consequences is a sufficient predicate for a finding of
criminal intent.
D
When viewed in terms of this standard, the jury instructions on
the price-fixing charge cannot be sustained. "A conclusive
presumption [of intent] which testimony could not overthrow would
effectively eliminate intent as an ingredient of the offense."
Morissette, supra at
342 U. S. 275.
The challenged jury instruction, as we read it, had precisely this
effect; the jury was told that the requisite intent followed, as a
matter of law, from a finding that the exchange of price
information had an impact on prices. Although an effect on prices
may well support an inference that the defendant had knowledge of
the probability of such a consequence at the time he acted, the
jury must remain free to consider additional evidence before
accepting or rejecting the inference. Therefore, although it would
be correct to instruct the jury that it may infer intent from an
effect on prices, ultimately the decision on the issue of intent
must be left to the trier of fact alone. The instruction given
invaded this factfinding function. [
Footnote 22]
Page 438 U. S. 447
III
Our construction of the Sherman Act to require proof of intent
as an element of a criminal antitrust violation leaves
Page 438 U. S. 448
unresolved the question upon which the Court of Appeals focused,
whether verification of price concessions with competitors for the
sole purpose of taking advantage of the § 2(b) "meeting
competition" defense should be treated as a "controlling
circumstance" precluding liability under § 1 of the Sherman
Act. We now turn to that question. [
Footnote 23]
A
In
Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn. v. United States,
268 U. S. 588
(1925), the Court held exempt from Sherman Act § 1 liability
an exchange of price information among competitors because the
exchange of information was necessary to protect the cement
manufacturers from fraudulent behavior by contractors. [
Footnote 24] Over 40 years later, in
United States v. Container Corp., 393 U.S. at
393 U. S. 335,
Mr. Justice Douglas characterized the
Cement holding in
the following terms:
"While there was present here, as in
Cement Mfrs. Protective
Assn. v. United States, 268 U. S. 588, an exchange of
prices to specific customers, there was absent the controlling
Page 438 U. S. 449
circumstance,
viz., that cement manufacturers, to
protect themselves from delivering to contractors more cement than
was needed for a specific job, and thus receiving a lower price,
exchanged price information as a means of protecting their legal
rights from fraudulent inducements to deliver more cement than
needed for a specific job."
The use of the phrase "controlling circumstance" in
Container Corp. implied that the exception from Sherman
Act liability recognized in
Cement Mfrs. was not
necessarily limited to the special circumstances of that case,
although the exact scope of the exception remained largely
undefined.
Since
Container Corp., several courts have read the
"controlling circumstance" exception as encompassing exchanges of
price information when undertaken for the purpose of compliance
with § 2(b) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the
Robinson-Patman Act.
See, e.g., Belliston v. Texaco, Inc.,
455 F.2d 175, 181-182 (CA10 1972);
Wall Products Co. v.
National Gypsum Co., 326 F.
Supp. 295, 312-315 (ND Cal.1971). [
Footnote 25] The Court of Appeals in the instant case
essentially adopted the same tack -- albeit with some additional
limitations [
Footnote 26] --
finding such a step necessary to eliminate a perceived conflict
between the Sherman Act's proscriptions regarding the exchange of
price information among competitors and the claimed necessity of
such exchanges to perfect the § 2(b) defense. The Government
challenges that resolution on two grounds: first, that there is no
general "controlling circumstance" exception to the Sherman Act,
and second, that, in any event, there is no conflict between the
two antitrust statutes which would require the prohibitions of the
Sherman Act to
Page 438 U. S. 450
be tempered even to the degree mandated by the Court of Appeals'
carefully circumscribed holding in this case. We agree generally
with the Government as to the proper accommodation of the Sherman
and Robinson-Patman Acts, and therefore find it unnecessary to
address the more general question going to the existence and proper
scope of the so-called "controlling circumstance" exception.
B
Section 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the
Robinson-Patman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a) (1976 ed.), embodies a
general prohibition of price discrimination between buyers when an
injury to competition is the consequence. The primary exception to
the § 2(a) bar is the "meeting competition" defense which is
incorporated as a proviso to the burden of proof requirements set
out in § 2(b):
"
Provided, however, That nothing herein contained shall
prevent a seller rebutting the
prima facie case thus made
by showing that his lower price or the furnishing of services or
facilities to any purchaser or purchasers was made in good faith to
meet an equally low price of a competitor, or the services or
facilities furnished by a competitor."
The role of the § 2(b) proviso in tempering the § 2(a)
prohibition of price discrimination was highlighted in
Standard
Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U. S. 231
(1951). There we recognized the potential tension between the
rationales underlying the Sherman and Robinson-Patman Acts, and
sought to effect a partial accommodation by construing § 2(b)
to provide an absolute defense to liability for price
discrimination.
"We need not now reconcile, in its entirety, the economic theory
which underlies the Robinson-Patman Act with that of the Sherman
and Clayton Acts. It is enough to say that Congress did not seek by
the Robinson-Patman Act either to abolish competition or so
radically to curtail it that a seller would have no substantial
right of self-defense
Page 438 U. S. 451
against a price raid by a competitor. For example, if a large
customer requests his seller to meet a temptingly lower price
offered to him by one of his seller's competitors, the seller may
well find it essential, as a matter of business survival, to meet
that price, rather than to lose the customer. . . . There is . . .
plain language and established practice which permits a seller,
through § 2(b), to retain a customer by realistically meeting
in good faith the price offered to that customer, without
necessarily changing the seller's price to its other
customers."
340 U.S. at
340 U. S.
249-250.
In
FTC v. A. E. Staley Mfg. Co., 324 U.
S. 746 (1945), the Court provided the first and still
the most complete explanation of the kind of showing which a seller
must make in order to satisfy the good faith requirement of the
§ 2(b) defense:
"Section 2(b) does not require the seller to justify price
discriminations by showing that, in fact, they met a competitor's
price. But it does place on the seller the burden of showing that
the price was made in good faith to meet a competitor's. . . . We
agree with the Commission that the statute at least requires the
seller, who has knowingly discriminated in price, to show the
existence of facts which would lead a reasonable and prudent person
to believe that the granting of a lower price would in fact meet
the equally low price of a competitor."
Id. at
324 U. S.
759-760. Application of these standards to the facts in
Staley led to the conclusion that the § 2(b) defense
had not been made out. The record revealed that the lower price had
been based simply on reports of salesmen, brokers, or purchasers,
with no efforts having been made by the seller "to investigate or
verify" the reports or the character and reliability of the
informants. 324 U.S. at
324 U. S. 758.
Similarly, in
Corn Products Co. v. FTC, 324 U.
S. 726 (1945), decided the same day, the § 2(b)
defense was not allowed because
"[t]he only evidence said to
Page 438 U. S. 452
rebut the
prima facie case . . . of the price
discriminations was given by witnesses who had no personal
knowledge of the transactions, and was limited to statements of
each witness's assumption or conclusion that the price
discriminations were justified by competition."
324 U.S. at
324 U. S.
741.
Staley's "investigate or verify" language, coupled with
Corn Products' focus on "personal knowledge of the
transactions," have apparently suggested to a number of courts
that, at least in certain circumstances, direct verification of
discounts between competitors may be necessary to meet the burden
of proof requirements of the § 2(b) defense.
See Gray v.
Shell Oil Co., 469 F.2d 742, 746-747 (CA9 1972);
Belliston
v. Texaco, Inc., 455 F.2d at 181-182;
Webster v. Sinclair
Refining Co., 338 F.
Supp. 248, 251-252 (SD Ala. 1971);
Wall Products Co. v.
National Gypsum Co., 326 F.Supp. at 312-315;
Di-Wall, Inc.
v. Fibreboard Corp., 1970 Trade Cases � 73, 155 (ND
Cal.1970). In none of these cases were the courts called upon to
address directly the question of whether interseller verification
was actually
required to satisfy § 2(b)'s good faith
standard; instead, the issue was presented only obliquely in the
form of a defense to the alleged Sherman Act violation. The
Belliston and
Webster cases accepted the defense
despite the absence of evidence that alternative means of
corroborating the claimed price reduction had been exhausted, while
the
Gray and
Wall Products courts found the
communication between sellers permissible only after other
alternatives had been exhausted. [
Footnote 27] The Court of Appeals critically and
perceptively analyzed these cases and concluded that only a very
narrow exception to Sherman Act liability should be recognized;
that exception would cover the relatively few situations where the
veracity of the buyer seeking the matching discount was
legitimately in doubt, other
Page 438 U. S. 453
reasonable means of corroboration were unavailable to the
seller, and the interseller communication was for the sole purpose
of complying with the Robinson-Patman Act. Despite the court's
efforts to circumscribe the scope of the exception it was
constrained to recognize, we find its analysis unacceptable.
C
A good faith belief, rather than absolute certainty, that a
price concession is being offered to meet an equally low price
offered by a competitor is sufficient to satisfy the § 2(b)
defense. While casual reliance on uncorroborated reports of buyers
or sales representatives without further investigation may not, as
we noted earlier, be sufficient to make the requisite showing of
good faith, nothing in the language of § 2(b) or the gloss on
that language in
Staley and
Corn Products
indicates that direct discussions of price between competitors are
required. Nor has any court, so far as we are aware, ever imposed
such a requirement. [
Footnote
28]
See Rowe, Pricing and the Robinson-Patman Act, 41
A.B.A. Antitrust L.J. 98, 100 102 (1971); ABA Section of Antitrust
Law, Antitrust Law Developments 145 n. 241 (1975). On the contrary,
the § 2(b) defense has been successfully invoked in the
absence of interseller verification on numerous occasions,
see,
e.g., International Air Industries, Inc. v. American Excelsior
Co., 517 F.2d 714, 725-726 (CA5 1975);
Cadigan v. Texaco,
Inc.,
Page 438 U. S. 454
492 F.2d 383 (CA9 1974);
Jones v. Borden Co., 430 F.2d
568, 572-574 (CA5 1970);
National Dairy Products Corp. v.
FTC, 395 F.2d 517, 523 (CA7 1968). And in
Kroger Co. v.
FTC, 438 F.2d 1372, 1376-1377 (CA6 1971),
aff'g Beatrice
Foods Co., 76 F.T.C. 719 (1969), the defense was recognized
despite the fact that the price concession was ultimately found to
have undercut that of the competition, and thus technically to have
fallen outside the "meet not beat" strictures of the defense. As
these cases indicate, and as the Federal Trade Commission observed,
it is the concept of good faith which lies at the core of the
"meeting competition" defense, and good faith
"is a flexible and pragmatic, not technical or doctrinaire,
concept. . . . Rigid rules and inflexible absolutes are especially
inappropriate in dealing with the § 2(b) defense; the facts
and circumstances of the particular case, not abstract theories or
remote conjectures, should govern its interpretation and
application."
Continental Baking Co., 63 F.T.C. 2071, 2163
(1963).
The so-called problem of the untruthful buyer which concerned
the Court of Appeals does not, in our view, call for a different
approach to the § 2(b) defense. The good faith standard
remains the benchmark against which the seller's conduct is to be
evaluated, and we agree with the Government and the FTC that this
standard can be satisfied by efforts falling short of interseller
verification in most circumstances where the seller has only vague,
generalized doubts about the reliability of its commercial
adversary -- the buyer. [
Footnote 29] Given the
Page 438 U. S. 455
fact-specific nature of the inquiry, it is difficult to predict
all the factors the FTC or a court would consider in appraising a
seller's good faith in matching a competing offer in these
circumstances. Certainly evidence that a seller had received
reports of similar discounts from other customers,
cf. Jones v.
Borden Co., supra at 572-573; or was threatened with a
termination of purchases if the discount were not met,
cf.
International Air Industries, Inc. v. American Excelsior Co.,
supra at 726;
Cadigan v. Texaco, Inc., supra, at 386,
would be relevant in this regard. Efforts to corroborate the
reported discount by seeking documentary evidence or by appraising
its reasonableness in terms of available market data would also be
probative, as would the seller's past experience with the
particular buyer in question. [
Footnote 30]
There remains the possibility that, in a limited number of
situations, a seller may have substantial reasons to doubt the
accuracy of reports of a competing offer, and may be unable to
corroborate such reports in any of the generally accepted ways.
Thus, the defense may be rendered unavailable, since unanswered
Page 438 U. S. 456
questions about the reliability of a buyer's representations may
well be inconsistent with a good faith belief that a competing
offer had, in fact, been made. [
Footnote 31] As an abstract proposition, resort to
interseller verification as a means of checking the buyer's
reliability seems a possible solution to the seller's plight, but
careful examination reveals serious problems with the practice.
Both economic theory and common human experience suggest that
interseller verification -- if undertaken on an isolated and
infrequent basis with no provision for reciprocity or cooperation
-- will not serve its putative function of corroborating the
representations of unreliable buyers regarding the existence of
competing offers. Price concessions by oligopolists generally yield
competitive advantages only if secrecy can be maintained; when the
terms of the concession are made publicly known, other competitors
are likely to follow, and any advantage to the initiator is lost in
the process.
See generally F. Scherer, Industrial Market
Structure and Economic Performance 208-209, 449 (1970); P. Areeda,
Antitrust Analysis 230-231 (2d ed.1974); Note, Meeting Competition
Under the Robinson-Patman Act, 90 Harv.L.Rev. 1476, 1480-1481
(1977).
See also United States v. Container Corp., 393
U.S. at
393 U. S. 337.
Thus, if one seller offers a price concession for the purpose of
winning over one of his competitor's customers, it is unlikely that
the same seller will freely inform its competitor of the details of
the concession so that it can be promptly matched and diffused.
Instead, such a seller would appear to have at least as great an
incentive to misrepresent the existence
Page 438 U. S. 457
or size of the discount as would the buyer who received it.
Thus, verification, if undertaken on a one-shot basis for the sole
purpose of complying with the § 2(b) defense, does not hold
out much promise as a means of shoring up buyers'
representations.
The other variety of interseller verification is, like the
conduct charged in the instant case, undertaken pursuant to an
agreement, either tacit or express, providing for reciprocity among
competitors in the exchange of price information. Such an agreement
would make little economic sense, in our view, if its sole purpose
were to guarantee all participants the opportunity to match the
secret price concessions of other participants under § 2(b).
For in such circumstances, each seller would know that his price
concession could not be kept from his competitors, and no seller
participating in the information exchange arrangement would,
therefore, have any incentive for deviating from the prevailing
price level in the industry.
See United States v. Container
Corp., supra at
393 U. S.
336-337. Regardless of its putative purpose, the most
likely consequence of any such agreement to exchange price
information would be the stabilization of industry prices.
See
Scherer, supra at 449; Note, Antitrust Liability for an
Exchange of Price Information -- What Happened to
Container
Corp., 3 Va.L.Rev. 639, 666 (1977). Instead of facilitating
use of the § 2(b) defense, such an agreement would have the
effect of eliminating the very price concessions which provide the
main element of competition in oligopolistic industries and the
primary occasion for resort to the "meeting competition"
defense.
Especially in oligopolistic industries such as the gypsum board
industry, the exchange of price information among competitors
carries with it the added potential for the development of
concerted price-fixing arrangements which lie at the core of the
Sherman Act's prohibitions. The Department of Justice's 1977 Report
on the Robinson-Patman Act focused on the growing use of the Act as
a cover for price-fixing; former
Page 438 U. S. 458
Antitrust Division Assistant Attorney General Kauper discussed
the mechanics of the process:
"And thus you find in some industries relatively extensive
exchanges of price information for the purpose, at least the stated
purpose, of complying with the Robinson-Patman Act. . . . "
"Now, the mere exchange of price information itself may tend to
stabilize prices. But I think it is also relatively common that,
once that exchange process begins, certain understandings go along
with it -- that we will exchange prices, but it will be understood,
for example, you will not undercut my prices."
"And from there it is a rather easy step into a full-fledged
price-fixing agreement. I think we have seen that from time to
time, and I suspect we will continue to see it as long as there
continues to be a need to justify particular price discriminations
in the terms of the Robinson-Patman Act."
United States Department of Justice, Report on the
Robinson-Patman Act 561 (1977).
We are left, therefore, on the one hand, with doubts about both
the need for and the efficacy of interseller verification as a
means of facilitating compliance with § 2(b), and, on the
other, with recognition of the tendency for price discussions
between competitors to contribute to the stability of oligopolistic
prices and open the way for the growth of prohibited
anticompetitive activity. To recognize even a limited "controlling
circumstance" exception for interseller verification in such
circumstances would be to remove from scrutiny under the Sherman
Act conduct falling near its core with no assurance, and indeed
with serious doubts, that competing antitrust policies would be
served thereby. In Automatic Canteen Co. v. FTC,
346 U. S.
61,
346 U. S. 74
(1953), the Court suggested that as a general rule the
Robinson-Patman Act should be construed so as to insure its
coherence with "the broader antitrust policies that have been laid
down by Congress"; that observation
Page 438 U. S. 459
buttresses our conclusion that exchanges of price information --
even when putatively for purposes of Robinson-Patman Act compliance
-- must remain subject to close scrutiny under the Sherman Act.
[
Footnote 32]
IV
One judge of the Court of Appeals was of the view that reversal
was required not only because of infirmities in the antitrust
instruction, but also because the trial judge had "encroach[ed] on
[the] jury['s] authority" and had foreclosed "a possible
no
verdict' outcome." 550 F.2d at 134 (Adams, J., concurring). Our own
review of the record and the circumstances surrounding the
deliberations of the jury, and in particular the ex parte
communications between the judge and jury foreman, leads us to the
same conclusion.
After hearing a mass of testimony for nearly five months, the
jurors were sequestered when deliberations commenced. On the second
and third days of deliberations, supplemental instructions were
given in response to jury questions; on the fourth day, the hours
of deliberations were shortened because of reported nervous tension
among the jurors; on the fifth day, the judge
sua sponte
delivered what amounted to a modified
Page 438 U. S. 460
Allen charge [
Footnote 33] in the course of providing further answers
to questions from the jury; and on the sixth day, the modified
Allen charge was repeated, this time in response to a note
from the jury that it was unable to reach a verdict. Against this
background of internal pressures and apparent disagreements and
confusion among the jurors, the jury foreman, on the morning of the
seventh day of deliberations, requested a meeting with the judge
"to discuss the condition of the jury and further guidance." The
District Judge suggested that he meet alone with the jury foreman,
and counsel acquiesced. The transcript of the meeting, which was
initially impounded but released for purposes of the appeal,
contained several references by the foreman to the jury's deadlock,
as well as an exchange suggesting the strong likelihood that the
foreman carried away from the meeting the impression that the judge
wanted a verdict "one way or the other." The judge's report to
counsel summarizing the discussion made no reference to either of
these matters. [
Footnote
34]
We find this sequence of events disturbing for a number of
reasons. Any
ex parte meeting or communication between the
judge and the foreman of a deliberating jury is pregnant with
possibilities for error. This record amply demonstrates that even
an experienced trial judge cannot be certain to avoid all the
pitfalls inherent in such an enterprise. First, it is difficult to
contain, much less to anticipate, the direction the conversation
will take at such a meeting. Unexpected questions or comments can
generate unintended and misleading impressions of the judge's
subjective personal views which have no place in his instruction to
the jury -- all the more so when counsel are not present to
challenge the statements. Second,
Page 438 U. S. 461
any occasion which leads to communication with the whole jury
panel through one juror inevitably risks innocent misstatements of
the law and misinterpretations despite the undisputed good faith of
the participants. Here, there developed a set of circumstances in
which it can fairly be assumed that the foreman undertook to
restate to his fellow jurors what he understood the judge to have
implied regarding the resolution of the case in a definite verdict
"one way or the other." There is, of course, no way to determine
precisely what the foreman said when he returned to the jury
room.
Finally, the absence of counsel from the meeting and the
unavailability of a transcript or full report of the meeting
aggravate the problems of having one juror serve as a conduit for
communicating instructions to the whole panel. While all counsel
acquiesced to the judge's
ex parte conference with the
jury foreman, they did so on the express understanding that the
judge merely intended -- as no doubt at the time he did -- to
receive from the foreman a report on the state of affairs in the
jury room and the prospects for a verdict. Certainly none of the
parties waived the right to a full and accurate report of what
transpired at the meeting, nor did they agree that the judge was to
repeat the instructions as to his understandable reluctance to
accept the jury's inability to reach a verdict. Because neither
counsel received a full report from the judge, they were not aware
of the scope of the conversation between the foreman and the judge,
of the judge's statement that the jury should continue to
deliberate in order to reach a verdict, or of the real risk that
the foreman's impression was that a verdict "one way or the other"
was required. Counsel were thus denied any opportunity to clear up
the confusion regarding the judge's direction to the foreman, which
could readily have been accomplished by requesting that the whole
jury be called into the courtroom for a clarifying instruction.
See Rogers v. United States, 422 U. S.
35,
422 U. S. 38
(1975);
Fillippon v. Albion Vein Slate
Co., 250 U.S.
Page 438 U. S. 462
76,
250 U. S. 81
(1919). Thus, it is not simply the action of the judge in having
the private meeting with the jury foreman, standing alone --
undesirable as that procedure is -- which constitutes the error;
rather, it is the fact that the
ex parte discussion was
inadvertently allowed to drift into what amounted to a supplemental
instruction to the foreman relating to the jury's obligation to
return a verdict, coupled with the fact that counsel were denied
any chance to correct whatever mistaken impression the foreman
might have taken from this conversation, that we find most
troubling.
While it is, of course, impossible to gauge what part the
disputed meeting played in the jury's action of returning a verdict
the following morning, this swift resolution of the issues in the
face of positive prior indications of hopeless deadlock, at the
very least gives rise to serious questions in this regard.
Cf.
Rogers v. United States, supra at
422 U. S. 40-41.
In
Jenkins v. United States, 380 U.
S. 445 (1965), we held an instruction directing the jury
that it had to reach a verdict was reversible error; the logic of
Jenkins cannot be said to be inapposite here, given the
peculiar circumstances in which discussions between the judge and
the foreman took place.
We are persuaded that the Court of Appeals would have been
justified in reversing the convictions solely because of the risk
that the foreman believed the court was insisting on a dispositive
verdict; a belief which we must assume was promptly conveyed to the
jurors. The unintended direction of the colloquy between the judge
and the jury foreman illustrates the hazards of
ex parte
communications with a deliberating jury or any of its members.
V
Respondents also challenged in the Court of Appeals the jury
instructions regarding participation in the conspiracy and
withdrawal therefrom; one judge on the panel concluded that these
instructions were infirm. We agree with the Government
Page 438 U. S. 463
that the charge concerning participation in the conspiracy,
while perhaps not as clear as it might have been, was sufficient.
The jury was informed repeatedly that only a single conspiracy was
alleged, and that liability could only be predicated on the knowing
involvement of each defendant, considered individually, in the
conspiracy charged. As given, [
Footnote 35] the instruction was substantially in accord
with those generally given in similar antitrust cases.
See
ABA Antitrust Section, Jury Instructions in Criminal Antitrust
Cases 1964-1976, chs. 10, 28 (1978); 2 E. Devitt & C. Blackmar,
Federal Jury Practice and Instructions §§ 55.09, 55.17
(3d ed., 1977). And in any event, the disputed instruction differed
in only minor and immaterial respects from the instruction
requested by respondents. [
Footnote 36]
We have more difficulty with the instruction on withdrawal from
the conspiracy. The jury was charged in the following terms:
"In order to find that a defendant abandoned or withdrew from a
conspiracy prior to December 27, 1968, you must find, from the
evidence, that he or it took some affirmative action to disavow or
defeat its purpose. Mere inaction would not be enough to
demonstrate abandonment. To withdraw, a defendant
either must
have affirmatively notified each other member of the
conspiracy
Page 438 U. S. 464
he will no longer participate in the undertaking, so they
understand they can no longer expect his participation or
acquiescence, or he must make disclosures of the illegal scheme to
law enforcement officials."
"Thus, once a defendant is shown to have joined a conspiracy, in
order for you to find he abandoned the conspiracy, the evidence
must show that the defendant took some definite, decisive step
indicating a complete disassociation from the unlawful
enterprise."
(Emphasis added.) Respondents had requested a more expansive
instruction which would have specifically allowed the jury to
consider a "p[r]esumption of competitive behavior, such as
intensified price-cutting or price wars," as affirmative action
showing a withdrawal from the price-fixing enterprise. While the
judge allowed this theory to be argued to the jury, he declined to
include it in his instructions. The Government now seeks to defend
the charge as given on the ground that the first sentence was
sufficiently broad to satisfy respondents' concerns, and the third
sentence, to which respondents principally object, did not in any
meaningful way detract from the generality of the first.
We cannot agree. The charge, fairly read, limited the jury's
consideration to only two circumscribed and arguably impractical
methods of demonstrating withdrawal from the conspiracy. [
Footnote 37] Nothing that we have
been able to find in the case law suggests, much less commands,
that such confining blinders be placed on the jury's freedom to
consider evidence regarding the continuing participation of alleged
conspirators in the charged conspiracy. Affirmative acts
inconsistent with the object of the conspiracy and communicated in
a manner reasonably calculated to reach coconspirators have
generally
Page 438 U. S. 465
been regarded as sufficient to establish withdrawal or
abandonment.
See, e.g., Hyde v. United States,
225 U. S. 347,
225 U. S. 369
(1912);
United States v. Borelli, 336 F.2d 376, 385 (CA2
1964).
See also Note, Developments in the Law -- Criminal
Conspiracy, 72 Harv.L.Rev. 920, 958 (195). We conclude that the
unnecessarily confining nature of the instruction, standing alone,
constituted reversible error. [
Footnote 38] If a new trial takes place, an instruction
correcting this error and giving the jury broader compass on the
question of withdrawal must be given.
Accordingly, the judgment of the Court of Appeals is
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins all but Part IV of this opinion.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN took no part in the consideration or
decision of this case.
|
438
U.S. 422app|
APPENDIX TO OPINION OF THE COURT
[Present: The foreman of the jury and the Court.]
The COURT. What is your problem, sir?
Mr. RUSSELL. I have two problems. And first of all, if I refer
to a juror with a sexual gender, I would like it struck, because I
would like to say juror.
The COURT. In other words, if he says he or she, make it
neutral.
Mr. RUSSELL. The two problems are health and the status of the
count.
The COURT. You can't tell me that now.
Mr. RUSSELL. I am not going to tell you what the status is in no
way. In fact, I can't tell you, because I can't remember.
Page 438 U. S. 466
The COURT. All right.
Mr. RUSSELL. But first of all, I would like to thank you for
that 6:30, because I don't think you would have a jury left. I am
not a doctor, but these people are getting very distraught. It is
not that they go into a depression and stay there; they go into a
depression and they're coming out high. Now I would say at least
eight of the jurors are taking some kind of pill. Some of the pills
have been even issued by the doctor downstairs. I am not a doctor,
and I can't judge these things, but I have seen one of [3] these
jurors at one time I thought she was going to jump out the window.
And I, just for my own sake, without telling you this, I cannot
take the responsibility that this could happen. I know this is part
of Mr. Keene's job, but like I say, they go high and low, and
sometimes by the time I get to Mr. Keene and get him down there,
they are perfectly normal again.
In fact, one of the instances was when I saw this one girl
--
The COURT. May I ask this: if we discharged -- we can excuse one
juror for health reasons. Is there any juror we could excuse that
would help the situation? If it is more than that, there is no
point.
Mr. RUSSELL. I think there is more than that, Judge. I am not a
doctor, so I can't say. I'm not even sure these are true
sicknesses. They seem -- I mean, with the high and low, they seem
induced, but when a person thinks they are sick, they're generally
sick.
The COURT. It is just as bad if they think they are.
Mr. RUSSELL. As I say, I am not a doctor. I don't like to be a
judge, but I think for my own sake, my feelings, it is my
responsibility as foreman to tell you these things. I do not want
to be responsible for anybody's health.
The COURT. I don't, either.
[4] You recall, though, that before -- when I had two alternate
jurors, I asked all the jurors if there was anybody who was not
physically able to go ahead and everybody wanted to do it.
Page 438 U. S. 467
Mr. RUSSELL. I realize that. I think every juror out there wants
to do their duty.
The COURT. See, we have tried this case now for four months.
Mr. RUSSELL. This is part of it, I will grant you, but it is not
the whole part of it. There is some personality conflicts on the
jury that have led to certain situations, and I think we have
overcome those.
The COURT. If we continue to deliberate from 9 to 6:30, with a
lunch hour, for a while longer --
Mr. RUSSELL. What I want to tell you next is -- and that is,
again, my opinion -- and you can tell me I am wrong -- and I have
to look at it in a different way. We have taken enough ballots now,
and we have had enough discussions, and the way it is divided is
not going to be settled by any document, any remembrance of
testimony. It is based on a belief, and even if they -- even if
they would sign a document today, and you would ask me to get up in
the jury box and swear I think this is a true and just verdict, I
would have to say no, because I believe in the twelve or multiple
system of a jury; that, if we are to decide beyond a [5] reasonable
doubt, when you get twelve, or whatever the number has to be --
The COURT. That is what you have to decide.
Mr. RUSSELL. -- it proves it beyond a shadow of a doubt.
The COURT. Not beyond a shadow of a doubt.
Mr. RUSSELL. I know. Each individual proves it to himself, but
for a man to be convicted guilty, or the company, we do it beyond a
reasonable doubt, but if you have twelve, you know it is beyond a
shadow of a doubt and you cannot have any conscience over it as far
as a juror or anything else. That is the way I feel, Judge.
The COURT. What are you suggesting?
Mr. RUSSELL. I am asking you what I should do. I am to the point
--
The COURT. I would like this jury to deliberate longer. I
Page 438 U. S. 468
say that because, as I say, we have tried it for a considerable
period of time.
Mr. RUSSELL. Everybody realizes that, and I do.
The COURT. We have individual people here who are concerned, and
the jury has now deliberated -- they deliberated three full days,
Wednesday, Thursday and [6] Friday. They deliberated a half a day
on Saturday and a half day on Sunday. They are not deliberating a
full day because jurors usually deliberate until eleven or ten at
night.
Mr. RUSSELL. We know that, and we want to thank you.
The COURT. You have not deliberated that long yet.
Mr. RUSSELL. I know that is the way you would like it, but what
I am trying to tell you is I don't think deliberation is going to
change it. It is not a matter of time anymore.
The COURT. Are you telling me this jury is hopelessly
deadlocked, and will never reach a verdict?
Mr. RUSSELL. In my opinion, it is. I have to rely on that. I
have no experience in this kind of thing. I don't know what people
go through in a jury. This is the first time I have ever served on
one, and it is a new experience, and I will never forget it. But it
is a terrible responsibility, and what I said, if it was a matter
of finding a document or finding a part of a testimony that would
convince somebody, I would say sure, and good.
The COURT. All right.
For the time being continue your deliberations. I will take into
consideration what you have told me.
[7] Mr. RUSSELL. As I said, the health problem is something that
I think has to be looked at. I don't know how you are going to
judge this or whether you call Mr. Keene and ask him or the
Marshal's opinion, but I think something ought to be done.
The COURT. All right. I will take it into consideration. I have
to talk to counsel.
Mr. RUSSELL. I appreciate that. I didn't expect a decision, but
I would like some kind of guidance.
Page 438 U. S. 469
The COURT. I would like to ask the jurors to continue their
deliberations, and I will take into consideration what you have
told me. That is all I can say.
Mr. RUSSELL. I appreciate it. It is a situation I don't know how
to help you get what you are after.
The COURT. Oh, I am not after anything.
Mr. RUSSELL. You are after a verdict one way or the other.
The COURT. Which way it goes doesn't make any difference to
me.
Mr. RUSSELL. They keep saying, "If you will tell him what the
situation is, he might accept it."
I said, "He doesn't want to know. He told me that he doesn't
want to know what the decision is."
[8] The COURT. No, I don't want to know that. It would not be
proper for me to know.
Mr. RUSSELL. You may imply something from what I said.
The COURT. I can imply something from just watching, but I don't
want you to tell me. That would be a breach of your duty.
Mr. RUSSELL. I have told you as best I can.
The COURT. Thank you. You tell them to keep deliberating and see
if they can come to a verdict.
[At 12:04 p.m., the jury foreman returned to the deliberation
room.]
Certified true and correct transcript.
/s/ MARION C. WIKE
Marion C. Wike
Official Reporter
[App. 1837-1840.]
[
Footnote 1]
The major producers operate numerous plants to serve a wide
range of geographical markets. The single-plant producers are
limited in terms of the markets they can serve because of the
difficulties and expense involved in long-distance transportation
of gypsum board.
[
Footnote 2]
The corporate defendants named in the indictment were: United
States Gypsum Co., National Gypsum Co., Georgia Pacific Corp.,
Kaiser-Gypsum Co., Inc., Celotex Corp., and Flintkote Co. The
individual defendants included: the Chairman of the Board and the
Executive Vice-President of United States Gypsum, the Chairman of
the Board and Vice-President for Sales of National Gypsum, the
President of Georgia Pacific, the President and the Vice-President
and General Manager of Kaiser-Gypsum, the President of Celotex, and
the Chairman of the Board and the President of Flintkote. The
Gypsum Association was named as an unindicted coconspirator, as
were two other gypsum board producers -- Johns-Manville Corp. and
Fibreboard Corp.
[
Footnote 3]
The remaining corporate defendants were United States Gypsum,
National Gypsum, Georgia Pacific, and Celotex, and the remaining
individual defendants were the Chairman of the Board and the
Vice-President of Sales of National Gypsum and the Executive
Vice-President of United States Gypsum.
[
Footnote 4]
Defendants contended that the exchange of price information or
verification was necessary to enable them to take advantage of the
"meeting competition" defense contained in § 2(b) of the
Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 730, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act,
49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. § 13(b) (1976 ed.); see Part III,
infra.
[
Footnote 5]
Relevant portions of the charge dealing with this issue are
excerpted in the opinion of the Court of Appeals. 550 F.2d 115, 127
n. 12 (1977);
id. at 137-138 (Weis, J., dissenting).
[
Footnote 6]
See United States v. Fioravanti, 412 F.2d 407 (CA3),
cert. denied sub nom. Panaccione v. United States, 396
U.S. 837 (1969).
[
Footnote 7]
The judge observed that the only instruction he might give the
foreman was "to go back and continue his deliberations." App.
1823.
[
Footnote 8]
The complete colloquy between the foreman and the judge is
reproduced as an
438
U.S. 422app|>appendix to this opinion.
[
Footnote 9]
"Significantly, the judge did not tell counsel about the
foreman's opinion that the jury was hopelessly deadlocked; did not
indicate that the foreman was under the impression that the court
wanted a definite verdict either for the prosecution or the
defendants; and did not mention the directive to the jury that it
should 'see if [it] can come to a verdict.'"
550 F.2d at 132 (Adams, J., concurring).
[
Footnote 10]
After the conclusion of the trial, the Court of Appeals ordered
the transcript of the meeting between the judge and the foreman
released to counsel to aid them in preparation of the appeal.
[
Footnote 11]
"Therefore, appellants were entitled to an instruction that
their verification practice would not violate the Sherman Act if
the jury found: (1) the appellants engaged in the practice solely
to comply with the strictures of Robinson-Patman; (2) they had
first resorted to all other reasonable means of corroboration,
without success; (3) they had good, independent reason to doubt the
buyers' truthfulness; and (4) their communication with competitors
was strictly limited to the one price and one buyer at issue."
Id. at 126.
[
Footnote 12]
See 438 U. S.
infra.
[
Footnote 13]
Our analysis focuses solely on the elements of a criminal
offense under the antitrust laws, and leaves unchanged the general
rule that a civil violation can be established by proof of either
an unlawful purpose or an anticompetitive effect.
See United
States v. Container Corp., 393 U. S. 333,
393 U. S. 337
(1969);
id. at
393 U. S. 341
(MARSHALL, J., dissenting). Of course, consideration of intent may
play an important role in divining the actual nature and effect of
the alleged anticompetitive conduct.
See Chicago Board of Trade
v. United States, 246 U. S. 231,
246 U. S. 238
(1918).
[
Footnote 14]
Senator Sherman adverted to the open texture of the statutory
language in 1890 and accurately forecast its consequence -- a
central role for the courts in giving shape and content to the
Act's proscriptions.
"I admit that it is difficult to define in legal language the
precise line between lawful and unlawful combinations. This must be
left for the courts to determine in each particular case. All that
we, as lawmakers, can do is to declare general principles, and we
can be assured that the courts will apply them so as to carry out
the meaning of the law. . . ."
21 Cong.Rec. 2460 (1890).
[
Footnote 15]
In 1967, the Antitrust Division refined its guidelines to
emphasize that criminal prosecutions should only be brought against
willful violations of the law.
See The President's
Commission on Law Enforcement and Administration of Justice, Task
Force Report: Crime and Its Impact -- An Assessment 110 (1967).
[
Footnote 16]
The exchange of price data and other information among
competitors does not invariably have anticompetitive effects;
indeed such practices can in certain circumstances increase
economic efficiency and render markets more, rather than less,
competitive. For this reason, we have held that such exchanges of
information do not constitute a
per se violation of the
Sherman Act.
See, e.g., United States v. Citizens &
Southern Nat. Bank, 422 U. S. 86,
422 U. S. 113
(1975);
United States v. Container Corp., 393 U.S. at
393 U. S. 338
(Fortas, J., concurring). A number of factors, including most
prominently the structure of the industry involved and the nature
of the information exchanged, are generally considered in divining
the procompetitive or anticompetitive effects of this type of
interseller communication.
See United States v. Container
Corp., supra. See generally L. Sullivan, Law of
Antitrust 265-274 (1977). Exchanges of current price information,
of course, have the greatest potential for generating
anticompetitive effects and, although not
per se unlawful,
have consistently been held to violate the Sherman Act.
See
American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States,
257 U. S. 377
(1921);
United States v. American Linseed Oil Co.,
262 U. S. 371
(1923);
United States v. Container Corp., supra.
[
Footnote 17]
The possibility that those subjected to strict liability will
take extraordinary care in their dealings is frequently regarded a
one advantage of a rule of strict liability.
See J. Hall,
General Principles of Criminal Law 344 (2d ed.1960); W. LaFave
& A. Scott, Criminal Law 222-223 (1972). However, where the
conduct proscribed is difficult to distinguish from conduct
permitted and indeed encouraged, as in the antitrust context, the
excessive caution spawned by a regime of strict liability will not
necessarily redound to the public's benefit. The antitrust laws
differ in this regard from, for example, laws designed to insure
that adulterated food will not be sold to consumers. In the latter
situation, excessive caution on the part of producers is entirely
consistent with the legislative purpose.
See United States v.
Park, 421 U. S. 658,
421 U. S.
671-672 (1975).
[
Footnote 18]
Congress has recently increased the criminal penalties for
violation of the Sherman Act. Individual violations are now treated
as felonies punishable by a fine not to exceed $100,000, or by
imprisonment for up to three years, or both. Corporate violators
are subject to a $1 million fine. 15 U.S.C. § 1 (1976 ed.).
The severity of these sanctions provides further support for our
conclusion that the Sherman Act should not be construed as creating
strict liability crimes.
Cf. Morissette v. United States,
342 U. S. 246,
342 U. S. 256
(1952); Sayre, Public Welfare Offenses, 33 Colum.L.Rev. 55, 72
(1933) (strict liability generally inappropriate when offense
punishable by imprisonment). Respondents here were not prosecuted
under the new penalty provisions, since they were indicted prior to
the December 21, 1974, effective date for the increased
sanctions.
[
Footnote 19]
An accommodation of the civil and criminal provisions of the Act
similar to that which we approve here was suggested by Senator
Sherman in response to Senator George's argument during floor
debate that the Act was primarily a penal statute to be construed
narrowly in accord with traditional maxims:
"The first section, being a remedial statute, would be construed
liberally with a view to promote its object. It defines a civil
remedy, and the courts will construe it liberally. . . . "
"In providing a remedy, the intention of the combination is
immaterial. . . ."
"The third section is a criminal statute, which would be
construed strictly, and is difficult to be enforced. In the present
state of the law, it is impossible to describe, in precise
language, the nature and limits of the offense in terms specific
enough for an indictment."
21 Cong.Rec. 2456 (1890).
Although the bill being debated by Senators George and Sherman
differed in form from the Act as ultimately passed, the colloquy
between them indicates that Congress was fully aware of the
traditional distinctions between the elements of civil and criminal
offenses, and apparently did not intend to do away with them in the
Act.
[
Footnote 20]
In a conspiracy, two different types of intent are generally
required -- the basic intent to agree, which is necessary to
establish the existence of the conspiracy, and the more traditional
intent to effectuate the object of the conspiracy.
See W.
LaFave & A. Scott, Criminal Law 464-465 (1972). Our discussion
here focuses only on the second type of intent.
[
Footnote 21]
In so holding, we do not mean to suggest that conduct undertaken
with the purpose of producing anticompetitive effects would not
also support criminal liability, even if such effects did not come
to pass.
Cf. United States v. Griffith, 334 U.
S. 100,
334 U. S. 105
(1948). We hold only that this elevated standard of intent need not
be established in cases where anticompetitive effects have been
demonstrated; instead, proof that the defendant's conduct was
undertaken with knowledge of its probable consequences will satisfy
the Government's burden.
[
Footnote 22]
Respondents contend that,
"prior to the trial of this case, no court had ever held that a
mere exchange of information which had a stabilizing effect on
prices violated the Sherman Act, regardless of the purpose for the
exchange."
Joint Brief for Respondents 50. Retroactive application of "this
judicially expanded definition of the crime" would, the argument
continues, contravene the "principles of fair notice embodied in
the Due Process Clause."
Ibid. While we have rejected on
other grounds the "effects only" test in the context of criminal
proceedings, we do not agree with respondents that the prior case
law dealing with the exchange of price information required proof
of a purpose to restrain competition in order to make out a Sherman
Act violation.
Certainly our decision in
United States v. Container
Corp., 393 U. S. 333
(1969), is fairly read as indicating that proof of an
anticompetitive effect is a sufficient predicate for liability. In
that case, liability followed from proof that "the exchange of
price information has had an anticompetitive effect in the
industry,"
id. at
393 U. S. 337, and no suggestion was made that proof of
a purpose to restrain trade or competition was also required. Thus,
at least in the post-
Container period, which comprises
almost the entire time period at issue here, respondents' claimed
lack of notice cannot be credited.
Nor are the prior cases treating exchanges of information among
competitors more favorable to respondents' position.
See
American Column & Lumber Co. v. United States, 257 U.S. at
257 U. S. 400
("[A]ny concerted action . . . to cause, or which in fact does
cause, . . . restraint of competition . . . is unlawful");
United States v. American Linseed Oil Co., 262 U.
S. 371,
262 U. S. 389
(1923) ("[A] necessary tendency . . . to suppress competition . . .
[is] unlawful");
Maple Flooring Mfrs. Assn. v. United
States, 268 U. S. 563,
268 U. S. 585
(1925) (purpose to restrain trade or conduct which "had resulted,
or would necessarily result, in tending arbitrarily to lessen
production or increase prices" sufficient for liability). While in
Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn. v. United States,
268 U. S. 588
(1925), an exception from Sherman Act liability was recognized for
conduct intended to prevent fraud, we do not read that case as
repudiating the rule set out in prior cases; instead,
Cement highlighted a narrow limitation on the application
of the general rule that either purpose or effect will support
liability.
We do not understand respondents to be making the related claim
that they relied on the several lower court cases exempting
interseller verification for purposes of complying with the
Robinson-Patman Act from scrutiny under the Sherman Act,
see
infra at
438 U. S.
452-453, and thus should not be penalized if those
decisions turn out to have been incorrect. Whatever the merits of
such an argument, respondents would appear unable to invoke it
since the initiation of their verification practices antedated
those lower court decisions.
[
Footnote 23]
This question was not resolved by the prior discussion because a
purpose of complying with the Robinson-Patman Act by exchanging
price information is not inconsistent with knowledge that such
exchanges of information will have the probable effect of fixing or
stabilizing prices. Since we hold knowledge of the probable
consequences of conduct to be the requisite mental state in a
criminal prosecution, like the instant one, where an effect on
prices is also alleged, a defendant's purpose in engaging in the
proscribed conduct will not insulate him from liability unless it
is deemed of sufficient merit to justify a general exception to the
Sherman Act's proscriptions.
Cf. Cement Mfrs. Protective Assn.
v. United States, supra.
[
Footnote 24]
Respondents maintain that their verification practices not only
were for the purpose of complying with the Robinson-Patman Act, but
also served to protect them from fraud on the part of their
customers, and thus fall squarely within the
Cement
exception. The Court of Appeals rejected this claim, 550 F.2d at
123 n. 9, and we find no reason to upset this determination.
[
Footnote 25]
Although the
Belliston court did not specifically refer
to Cement's "controlling circumstance" exception, it adopted the
rationale of the
Wall Products case where that exception
was explicitly relied upon to immunize verification from the
proscriptions of the Sherman Act.
[
Footnote 26]
See n 11,
supra.
[
Footnote 27]
The decision in
Di-Wall is ambiguous on the question of
whether alternatives short of verification were exhausted prior to
the exchange of price information. 1970 Trade Cases, �
73,155, p. 88,557.
[
Footnote 28]
In
Viviano Macaroni Co. v. FTC, 411 F.2d 255 (CA3
1969), the § 2(b) defense was not recognized because the
seller had relied solely on the report of its customer regarding
other competitive offers without undertaking any investigation to
corroborate the offer or the reliability of the customer. The Court
of Appeals in the instant case read
Viviano as at least
suggesting, if not requiring, interseller verification when the
veracity of the buyer was in doubt. As we read that case, however,
it simply reaffirms the teaching of
Staley, and does not
compel the further conclusion that only interseller verification
will satisfy the good faith requirement, even in the particular
circumstances identified by the Court of Appeals.
See 550
F.2d at 135 (Weis, J., dissenting).
[
Footnote 29]
"Although a seller may take advantage of the 'meeting
competition' defense only if it has a commercially reasonable
belief that its price concession is necessary to meet an equally
low price of a competitor, a seller may acquire this belief, and
hence perfect its defense, by doing everything reasonably feasible
-- short of violating some other statute, such as the Sherman Act
-- to determine the veracity of a customer's statement that he has
been offered a lower price. If, after making reasonable, lawful,
inquiries, the seller cannot ascertain that the buyer is lying, the
seller is entitled to make the sale. . . . There is no need for a
seller to discuss price with his competitors to take advantage of
the 'meeting competition' defense."
(Citations omitted.) Brief for United States 86-87, and n. 78.
See also App. to Pet. for Cert. 97a-99a.
[
Footnote 30]
It may also turn out that sustained enforcement of § 2(f)
of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, which
imposes liability on buyers for inducing illegal price discounts,
will serve to bolster the credibility of buyers' representations
and render reliance thereon by sellers a more reasonable and secure
predicate for a finding of good faith under § 2(b).
See
generally Note, Meeting Competition Under the Robinson-Patman
Act, 90 Harv.L.Rev. 1476, 1495-1496 (1977). In both
Great
Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. v. FTC, 557 F.2d 971 (CA2
1977), and
Kroger v. FTC, 438 F.2d 1372 (CA6 1971), buyers
have been held liable under § 2(f) despite the fact that the
sellers were either found not to have violated the Robinson-Patman
Act (
Kroger) or were not charged with such a violation
(
A&P). Certiorari has been granted in
Great
Atlantic & Pacific Tea Co. to consider the permissibility
of enforcing the Robinson-Patman Act in this manner. 435 U.S. 922
(1978).
[
Footnote 31]
We need not and do not decide that, in all such circumstances,
the defense would be unavailable. The case-by-case interpretation
and elaboration of the § 2(b) defense is properly left to the
other federal courts and the FTC in the context of concrete fact
situations. We note also that our conclusions regarding the proper
interpretation of § 2(f),
see n 30,
supra, may well affect subsequent
application of the § 2(b) defense.
[
Footnote 32]
That the § 2(b) defense may not be available in every
situation where a competing offer has in fact been made is not, in
our view, a meaningful objection to our holding. The good faith
requirement of the § 2(b) defense implicitly suggests a
somewhat imperfect matching between competing offers actually made
and those allowed to be met. Unless this requirement is to be
abandoned, it seems clear that inadequate information will, in a
limited number of cases, deny the defense to some who, if all the
facts had been known, would have been entitled to invoke it. For
reasons already discussed, interseller verification does not
provide a satisfactory solution to this seemingly inevitable
problem of inadequate information. Moreover, § 2(b) affords
only a defense to liability, and not an affirmative right under the
Act. While sellers are, of course, entitled to take advantage of
the defense when they can satisfy its requirements, efforts to
increase its availability at the expense of broader, affirmative
antitrust policies must be rejected.
[
Footnote 33]
Allen v. United States, 164 U.
S. 492 (1896). An injunction to the jury "to deliberate
with a view toward reaching an agreement if you can, without
violence, to individual judgment," was also included in the judge's
original instruction prior to the commencement of deliberation.
[
Footnote 34]
See n 9,
supra.
[
Footnote 35]
See n 5,
supra.
[
Footnote 36]
The requested charge was as follows:
"Because the gist of the offense charged is a continuing
agreement to raise, fix, maintain and stabilize prices of gypsum
products, it is essential for you to determine what kind of
agreement or understanding, if any, existed as to each defendant.
Each defendant is chargeable with the acts of his or its fellow
defendants and alleged coconspirators only if the acts are done in
furtherance of the joint venture as he or it understood it. No
defendant is to be held responsible for what some of the alleged
conspirators, unknown to the rest, do beyond the reasonable
intendment of the common agreement or understanding, if any, to
which you may find him or it a party."
550 F.2d at 128-129, n. 13 (emphasis omitted).
[
Footnote 37]
In this case the obligation to notify "each other member" of the
charged conspiracy would be a manageable task; in other situations,
all "other" members might not be readily identifiable.
[
Footnote 38]
The instruction on withdrawal and proper evidence thereof may
have been of particular importance here, because respondents
vigorously argued throughout the trial that competition within the
industry resumed before December 27, 1968, the critical date for
purposes of the applicable five-year statute of limitations.
MR. JUSTICE POWELL, concurring in part.
I join the judgment and Parts I, II, and V of the Court's
opinion. [
Footnote 2/1] I also join
so much of Part III as holds that a
Page 438 U. S. 470
seller's intention to establish a "meeting competition" defense
under § 2(b) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the
Robinson-Patman Act, to a charge of price discrimination under
§ 2(a) is not, in itself, a "controlling circumstance"
excusing liability under § 1 of the Sherman Act for otherwise
unlawful direct price verification practices.
I do not join those portions of Part III, however, that might be
read as suggesting that there are cases where the § 2(b)
defense is unavailable even though a seller made every reasonable,
lawful effort to corroborate his buyer's report that a competitor
had offered a lower price before reducing his own price to that
buyer.
See, e.g., ante at
438 U. S.
455-456,
438 U. S. 459
n. 32. [
Footnote 2/2] In my view, a
proper accommodation between the policies of the Robinson-Patman
Act and the Sherman Act would result in recognition of the §
2(b) defense in such cases. Otherwise, sellers sometimes would face
the unenviable choice of reducing prices to one buyer and risking
Robinson-Patman Act liability, refusing to do so and losing the
sale, or reducing prices to all buyers.
A prudent businessman faced with this choice often would forgo
the price reduction altogether. This reaction would disserve the
procompetitive policy of the Sherman Act without advancing
materially the antidiscrimination policy of the Robinson-Patman
Act. The Court already has made clear that the Robinson-Patman Act
"does not require the seller to justify price discriminations by
showing that in fact they met a competitive price."
FTC v. A.
E. Staley Mfg. Co., 324 U. S. 746,
324 U. S. 759
(1945). Today the Court confirms that
"it is the concept of good faith which lies at the core of the
'meeting competition' defense, and good faith 'is a flexible and
pragmatic, not technical or doctrinaire, concept.'"
Ante at
438 U. S. 454,
quoting
Continental Baking Co., 63 F.T.C. 2071, 2163
(1963). A seller who has attempted to verify his buyer's
Page 438 U. S. 471
report by every reasonable, lawful means before reducing his
price to meet a competitor's price, in my view, has met the test of
"good faith." In such a case, if the buyer's report proves to have
been untruthful, it is the buyer alone, not the seller, who has
acted in bad faith.
[
Footnote 2/1]
Because the issue discussed in Part IV of the Court's opinion is
unlikely to arise at any retrial, I find it unnecessary to express
a view as to it.
[
Footnote 2/2]
I do not understand the Court to take a firm position on this
issue.
See ante at
438 U. S. 456
n. 31.
MR. JUSTICE REHNQUIST concurring in part and dissenting in
part.
I concur in Part I and in the first portion of Part V of the
Court's opinion approving the jury instruction on participation in
the conspiracy. I dissent from the remaining portions of the
opinion, and set forth as briefly as possible my reasons for doing
so.
Part II of the Court's opinion uses as its point of departure
jury instructions on price-fixing which the Court correctly
characterizes as "not without ambiguity."
Ante at
438 U. S. 434.
However, these jury instructions are but a starting point for the
discourse in Part II of the Court's opinion dealing with the
element of intent in a criminal case, a discourse which I believe
goes beyond any reasoning necessary to dispose of the contentions
with respect to that point in this case.
I do not find it necessary to decide the intent which Congress
required as a prerequisite for criminal liability under the Sherman
Act, because I believe that the instructions given by the District
Court, when considered as a whole and in connection with the
objections made to them, are sufficiently close to respondents'
tendered instructions so as to afford respondents no basis upon
which to challenge the verdict. The jury instructions in this case
take up some 40 pages of the record, and are both detailed and
complex. The judge instructed the jury as to both respondents'
contention that they exchanged price information solely to comply
with the Robinson-Patman Act and the Government's contention
that
"the Defendants' purpose was not merely to establish their good
faith under the Robinson-Patman Act, but that
Page 438 U. S. 472
they exchanged competitive information for the purpose of
raising, fixing, maintaining, and stabilizing prices."
"It will be up to you, members of the jury, to resolve these
issues."
"First, you must determine whether there was an agreement,
either implied or express, to engage in the practice of price
checking or verification. . . ."
"
* * * *"
"Secondly, you must determine whether the purpose for the
exchange of competitive information between the Defendants and
their alleged coconspirators was to insure a good faith meeting of
competition, as a defense to the Robinson-Patman Act."
"If you decide that, if you decide that this was
merely done
in a good faith effort to comply with the Robinson-Patman Act, then
you could not consider verification, standing alone, as
establishing an agreement to fix, raise, maintain, and stabilize
prices as charged."
"However, if you decide that the effect of these exchanges was
to raise, fix, maintain, and stabilize the price of gypsum
wallboard, then you may consider these changes [
sic] as
evidence of the mutual agreement or understanding alleged in the
indictment to raise, fix, maintain, and stabilize list prices."
App. 1720-1721 (emphasis added). Read in conjunction with the
above, the portions of the instructions quoted by the Court,
ante at
438 U. S. 430,
are not reversible error. The Jury was instructed that it must find
a purpose "to raise, fix, maintain, and stabilize list prices," and
that this purpose could be presumed from the effect of respondents'
agreement. Respondents' proposed instruction
* does not
Page 438 U. S. 473
significantly differ from that given by the District Court. I
might add that, in my view, it would take plainly erroneous
instructions, the error of which was both quite precisely and
reasonably pointed out to the District Court, to warrant reversal
of a judgment entered upon a jury's verdict following five months
of trial.
The portions of Part II which I find most troubling are not
those which expressly address the congressionally prescribed
requirement of intent for criminal liability under the Sherman Act,
but those which discourse at length upon the role of intent in the
imposition of criminal liability in general, particularly those
which might be taken to import any special constitutional
difficulty if criminal liability is imposed without fault. While
the Court emphasizes that its result is not constitutionally
required,
ante at
438 U. S. 437, the Court's broad policy statements may
be misread by the lower courts. I also feel bound to say that,
while I am willing to respectfully defer to the views of the
distinguished authors of the American Law Institute's Model Penal
Code, and to the authors of law review articles and treatises such
as those sprinkled throughout the text of Part II of the Court's
opinion, I have serious reservations about the undiscriminating
emphasis and weight which the Court appears to give them in this
case.
For similar reasons, I do not believe that it is necessary in
this case to address the interrelationship of the Robinson-Patman
Act's "meeting competition" defense and the Sherman Act, and I
cheerfully refrain from that task. The jury was clearly instructed
that, if price information was exchanged "in a good faith effort to
comply with the Robinson-Patman Act,"
Page 438 U. S. 474
this exchange, by itself, would not make out a violation of the
Sherman Act: I believe that the communications between the judge
and the jury foreman described in Part IV of the Court's opinion,
having been consented to by all parties to the case, would not
justify a reversal of the verdict of the jury. I agree with that
portion of Part V of the Court's opinion which approves the charge
given the jury concerning participation in the conspiracy, but
disagree with that portion of Part V which seems to approve a more
expansive instruction with respect to withdrawal from the
conspiracy. In my opinion, neither of these instructions of the
District Court was sufficient, either separately or together, to
warrant reversal of the jury's verdict of guilty.
I therefore conclude that the judgment of the Court of Appeals
should be reversed, and the judgment of the District Court based
upon the jury's verdict should be reinstated.
*
"There has been evidence in this case of a defendant's
contacting a competitor to verify the existence or nonexistence of
a reported lower price or other competitive condition in the market
place. This practice has been referred to as 'verification.' There
is evidence that verification was engaged in by defendants for the
purpose of compliance with the Robinson-Patman Act, one of the
federal antitrust laws. I charge you as a matter of law that no
finding of guilt may be made in this case based on verification
engaged in for the purpose of compliance with the Robinson-Patman
Act. Further, to consider verification as any evidence whatsoever
of an alleged price-fixing conspiracy, you must first determine
beyond a reasonable doubt that the purpose of verification was not
compliance with the Robinson-Patman Act."
App. 1857.
MR. JUSTICE STEVENS, concurring in part and dissenting in
part.
There are three reasons why I am unable to subscribe to the
bifurcated construction of § 1 of the Sherman Act which the
Court adopts in Part II of its opinion.
In 1955, I subscribed to the view that criminal enforcement of
the Sherman Act is inappropriate unless the defendants have
deliberately violated the law. [
Footnote 3/1] I adhere to that view today. But since
1890, when the Sherman Act was enacted, the statute has had the
same substantive reach in criminal and civil cases. No matter how
wise the new rule that the Court adopts today may be, I believe it
is an amendment only Congress may enact.
If I were fashioning a new test of criminal liability, I would
require proof of a specific purpose to violate the law, rather than
mere knowledge that the defendants' agreement has had
Page 438 U. S. 475
an adverse effect on the market. [
Footnote 3/2] Under the lesser standard adopted by the
Court, I believe MR. JUSTICE REHNQUIST is quite right in viewing
the error in the trial judge's instructions as harmless.
Ante at
438 U. S.
471-473. There is, of course, a theoretical possibility
that defendants could engage in a practice of exchanging current
price information that was sufficiently prevalent to have had a
marketwide impact that they did not know about, but, as a practical
matter, that possibility is surely remote.
Finally, I am afraid that the new civil-criminal dichotomy may
work mischief in the civil enforcement of the prohibition against
tampering with prices in a free market. Conclusive presumptions
play a central role in the enforcement, both civil and criminal, of
the Sherman Act. Thus, an agreement to charge the same price,
[
Footnote 3/3] or to adopt a common
purchasing policy that determines the market price, [
Footnote 3/4] is unreasonable, and
therefore unlawful, without any proof of the purpose or the actual
effect of the agreement. The law presumes that those who entered
the price-fixing agreement knew that forbidden effects would
follow, and it also presumes, conclusively, that those effects will
follow. In a criminal prosecution for price fixing in violation of
the Sherman Act, it is, therefore, irrelevant whether the prices
fixed were reasonable, or whether the defendant's intentions were
good. [
Footnote 3/5]
See United States
v.
Page 438 U. S. 476
Trenton Potteries Co., 273 U.
S. 392. As Mr. Justice Stone explained for the Court in
that case,
"the Sherman law is not only a prohibition against the
infliction of a particular type of public injury. It 'is a
limitation of rights, . . . which may be pushed to evil
consequences, and therefore restrained.'"
Id. at
273 U. S. 398
(citation omitted).
To be sure, cases such as
Trenton Potteries involved
conduct that was determined to be illegal on its face, while, in
this case, the trial court appraised respondents' agreement under
"rule of reason" analysis. [
Footnote
3/6] But properly understood, rule of reason analysis is not
distinct from "
per se" analysis. On the contrary,
agreements that are illegal
per se are merely a species
within the broad category of agreements that unreasonably restrain
trade; less proof is required to establish their illegality, but
they nonetheless violate the basic rule of reason. [
Footnote 3/7]
As applied to an agreement among major producers to exchange
current price information, the rule of reason requires an element
in addition to proof of the agreement itself -- either an actual
market effect or an express purpose to affect market price -- but,
once that element is shown, any additional showing of intent is
unnecessary.
See United States v. Container Corp.,
393 U. S. 333. The
rule is premised on the assumption that, if the practice of
exchanging current price information is sufficiently prevalent to
affect the market price, then there is
Page 438 U. S. 477
an extremely high probability that the sales representatives of
these companies had actual knowledge of that fact. Given the
language of § 1, that premise is as valid in the context of a
criminal prosecution as it is in the context of a treble damages
civil action.
Accordingly, although I agree with much of the abstract
discussion in Part II of the Court's opinion, I concur only in
Parts I, III, IV, and V, and in the judgment.
[
Footnote 3/1]
Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the
Antitrust Laws 349-351 (1955).
[
Footnote 3/2]
The distinction between the two standards is explained
ante at
438 U. S.
444-445. The Report of the Attorney General's Committee
recommended that
"criminal process should be used only where the law is clear and
the facts reveal a flagrant offense and plain intent unreasonably
to restrain trade."
Report,
supra, 438
U.S. 422fn3/1|>n. 1, at 349.
[
Footnote 3/3]
United States v. Trenton Potteries Co., 273 U.
S. 392.
[
Footnote 3/4]
United States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.
S. 150.
[
Footnote 3/5]
In fact, early in the development of criminal enforcement of the
Sherman Act, this Court stated:
"[T]he conspirators must be held to have intended the necessary
and direct consequences of their acts, and cannot be heard to say
the contrary. In other words, by purposely engaging in a conspiracy
which necessarily and directly produces the result which the
statute is designed to prevent, they are, in legal contemplation,
chargeable with intending that result."
United States v. Patten, 226 U.
S. 525,
226 U. S.
543.
[
Footnote 3/6]
An argument can be made that an agreement among the major
producers in the market to exchange current price information
should be considered illegal on its face. As the Court points
out,
"[e]xchanges of current price information . . . have the
greatest potential for generating anticompetitive effects, and . .
. have consistently been held to violate the Sherman Act."
Ante at
438 U. S. 441
n. 16.
[
Footnote 3/7]
Rahl, Price Competition and the Price Fixing Rule -- Preface and
Perspective, 57 Nw.L.Rev. 137, 139 (1962).