Petitioner, an American manufacturer of consumer electronic
products, filed a petition with the Commissioner of Customs,
requesting assessment under § 303 of the Tariff Act of 1930 of
countervailing duties on various consumer electronic products
exported from Japan to this country. Petitioner contended that the
products benefited from bounties or grants paid or conferred by
Japan because Japan imposes a commodity tax (an "indirect" tax) on
those products when they are sold in that country, but "remits" the
tax when the products are exported, any tax paid on the shipment of
a product being refunded upon the subsequent exportation. Section
303 provides that, whenever a foreign country pays a "bounty or
grant" upon the exportation of a product from that country, the
Secretary of the Treasury (Secretary) must levy a countervailing
duty "equal to the net amount of such bounty or grant" upon the
importation of the product into the United States. After rejection
of its request, petitioner filed suit in the Customs Court,
claiming that the Treasury Department had erred in concluding that
remission of the Japanese tax was not a bounty or grant within the
purview of § 303. The Secretary contended that, since the
remission of the tax was "nonexcessive" (
i.e., not above
the amount of the tax paid or otherwise due), § 303 did not
require assessment of a countervailing duty. Relying on
Downs
v. United States, 187 U. S. 496, the
Customs Court ruled in petitioner's favor. The Court of Customs and
Patent Appeals reversed.
Held: Japan does not confer a "bounty or grant" within
the meaning of § 303 on the consumer electronic products by
failing to impose a commodity tax on those products when they are
exported to this country, while imposing the tax on the products
when they are sold in Japan.
Downs v. United States,
supra, distinguished. Pp.
437 U. S.
450-462.
(a) The Secretary's statutory interpretation that was followed
in this case has been consistently maintained since the basic
countervailing duty statute was enacted in 1897, and that
administrative interpretation is entitled to great weight.
See
Udall v. Tallman, 380 U. S. 1,
380 U. S. 16. Pp.
437 U. S.
450-451.
(b) The legislative history of the statute suggests that the
term
Page 437 U. S. 444
"bounty" was not intended to encompass the nonexcessive
remission of an indirect tax. Pp.
437 U. S.
451-455.
(c) The Secretary's interpretation was reasonable in light of
the statutory purpose of the countervailing duty,
viz.,
offsetting the unfair competitive advantage that foreign products
would otherwise enjoy from export subsidies paid by their
governments. In deciding in 1898 that a nonexcessive remission of
indirect taxes did not give the exporter an unfair competitive
advantage, the Secretary permissibly viewed the remission as a
reasonable measure for avoiding double taxation of exports -- once
by the foreign country and once upon sale in this country. Pp.
437 U. S.
455-457.
(d) The Secretary's interpretation is as permissible today as it
was in 1898. The statute has been reenacted five times with no
modification of the relevant language, and the Secretary's position
has been incorporated into an international agreement followed by
every major trading nation in the world. It is not for the
judiciary to substitute its views as to the fairness and economic
effect of remitting indirect taxes. Pp.
437 U. S.
457-459.
(e)
Downs v. United States, supra, did not involve the
issue of whether a nonexcessive remission of taxes, standing alone,
would have constituted a bounty on exportation, and is not
dispositive of this case. Pp.
437 U. S.
459-462.
64 C.C.P.A. 130, 562 F.2d 1209, affirmed.
MARSHALL, J., delivered the opinion for a unanimous Court.
Page 437 U. S. 445
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL delivered the opinion of the Court.
Under § 303(a) of the Tariff Act of 1930, 46 Stat. 687, as
amended, 19 U.S.C. § 1303(a) (1976 ed.), whenever a foreign
country pays a "bounty or grant" upon the exportation of a product
from that country, the Secretary of the Treasury is required to
levy a countervailing duty, "equal to the net amount of such bounty
or grant," upon importation of the product into the United States.
[
Footnote 1] The issue in this
case is whether Japan confers a "bounty" or "grant" on certain
consumer electronic products by failing to impose a commodity tax
on those products when they are exported, while imposing the tax on
the products when they are sold in Japan.
Page 437 U. S. 446
I
Under the Commodity Tax Law of Japan, Law No. 48 of 1962,
see App. 44-48, a variety of consumer goods, including the
electronic products at issue here, are subject to an "indirect" tax
-- a tax levied on the goods themselves, and computed as a
percentage of the manufacturer's sales price, rather than the
income or wealth of the purchaser or seller. The Japanese tax
applies both to products manufactured in Japan and to those
imported into Japan. [
Footnote
2] On goods manufactured in Japan, the tax is levied upon
shipment from the factory; imported products are taxed when they
are withdrawn from the customs warehouse. Only goods destined for
consumption in Japan are subject to the tax, however. Products
shipped for export are exempt, and any tax paid upon the shipment
of a product is refunded if the product is subsequently exported.
Thus, the tax is "remitted" on exports. [
Footnote 3]
In April, 1970, petitioner, an American manufacturer of consumer
electronic products, filed a petition with the Commissioner of
Customs, [
Footnote 4]
requesting assessment of countervailing duties on a number of
consumer electronic products exported from Japan to this country.
[
Footnote 5] Petitioner alleged
that Japan
Page 437 U. S. 447
had bestowed a "bounty or grant" upon exportation of these
products by,
inter alia, remitting the Japanese Commodity
Tax that would have been imposed had the products been sold within
Japan. In January, 1976, after soliciting the views of interested
parties and conducting an investigation pursuant to Treasury
Department regulations,
see 19 CFR § 159.47(c)
(1977), the Acting Commissioner of Customs published a notice of
final determination, rejecting petitioner's request. 41 Fed Reg.
1298 (1976). [
Footnote 6]
Petitioner then filed suit in the Customs Court, claiming that
the Treasury Department had erred in concluding that remission of
the Japanese Commodity Tax was not a bounty or grant within the
purview of the countervailing duty statute. [
Footnote 7] The Department defended on the ground
that, since the remission of indirect taxes was "nonexcessive," the
statute did not require assessment of a countervailing duty. In the
Department's terminology, a remission of taxes is "nonexcessive" if
it does not exceed the amount of tax paid or otherwise due; thus,
for example, if a tax of $5 is levied on goods at the factory, the
return of the $5 upon exportation would be "nonexcessive," whereas
a payment of $8 from the government to the manufacturer upon
exportation would be "excessive" by $3. The Department pointed out
that the current
Page 437 U. S. 448
version of § 303 is, in all relevant respects, unchanged
from the countervailing duty statute enacted by Congress in 1897,
[
Footnote 8] and that the
Secretary -- in decisions dating back to 1898 --has always taken
the position that the nonexcessive remission of an indirect tax is
not a bounty or grant within the meaning of the statute. [
Footnote 9]
On cross-motions for summary judgment, the Customs Court ruled
in favor of petitioner and ordered the Secretary to assess
countervailing duties on all Japanese consumer electronic
Page 437 U. S. 449
products specified in petitioner's complaint. 430 F. Supp. 242
(1977). The court acknowledged the Secretary's longstanding
interpretation of the statute. It concluded, however, that this
administrative practice could not be sustained in light of this
Court's decision in
Downs v. United States, 187 U.
S. 496 (1903), which held that an export bounty had been
conferred by a complicated Russian scheme for the regulation of
sugar production and sale, involving, among other elements,
remission of excise taxes in the event of exportation.
On appeal by the Government, the Court of Customs and Patent
Appeals, dividing 3-2, reversed the judgment of the Customs Court
and remanded for entry of summary judgment in favor of the United
States. 64 C.C.P.A. 130, 562 F.2d 1209 (1977). The majority opinion
distinguished
Downs on the ground that it did not decide
the question of whether nonexcessive remission of an indirect tax,
standing alone, constitutes a bounty or grant upon exportation. The
court then examined the language of § 303 and the legislative
history of the 1897 provision and concluded that,
"in determining whether a bounty or grant has been conferred, it
is the economic result of the foreign government's action which
controls."
64 C.C.P.A. at 138-139, 562 F.2d at 1216. Relying primarily on
the "long-continued" and "uniform" administrative practice,
id. at 142-143, 146-147, 562 F.2d at 1218-1219, 1222-1223,
and secondarily on congressional "acquiescence" in this practice
through repeated reenactment of the controlling statutory language,
id. at 143-144, 562 F.2d at 1220, the court held that
interpretation of "bounty or grant" so as not to include a
nonexcessive remission of an indirect tax is "a lawfully
permissible interpretation of § 303."
Id. at 147, 562
F.2d at 1223.
We granted certiorari, 434 U.S. 1060 (1978), and we now
affirm.
Page 437 U. S. 450
II
It is undisputed that the Treasury Department adopted the
statutory interpretation at issue here less than a year after
passage of the basic countervailing duty statute in 1897,
see T.D. 19321, 1 Synopsis of [Treasury] Decisions 696
(1898), and that the Department has uniformly maintained this
position for over 80 years. [
Footnote 10] This longstanding and consistent
administrative interpretation is entitled to considerable
weight.
"When faced with a problem of statutory construction, this Court
shows great deference to the interpretation given the statute by
the officers or agency charged with its administration."
"To sustain [an agency's] application of [a] statutory term, we
need not find that its construction is the only reasonable one, or
even that it is the result we would have reached had the question
arisen in the first instance in judicial proceedings."
Udall v. Tallman, 380 U. S. 1,
380 U. S. 16
(1965), quoting
Unemployment Compensation Comm'n v.
Aragon, 329 U. S. 143,
329 U. S. 153
(1946). Moreover, an administrative
"practice has peculiar weight when it involves a contemporaneous
construction of a statute by the [persons] charged with the
responsibility of setting its machinery in motion, of making the
parts work efficiently and smoothly while they are yet untried and
new."
Norwegian Nitrogen Products Co. v. United States,
288 U. S. 294,
288 U. S. 315
(1933);
see, e.g., Power Reactor Co. v. Electricians,
367 U. S. 396,
367 U. S. 408
(1961).
The question is thus whether, in light of the normal aids to
statutory construction, the Department's interpretation is
"sufficiently reasonable" to be accepted by a reviewing court.
Train v. Natural Resources Defense Council, 421 U. S.
60,
Page 437 U. S. 451
421 U. S. 75
(1975). Our examination of the language, the legislative history,
and the overall purpose of the 1897 provision persuades us that the
Department's initial construction of the statute was far from
unreasonable; and we are unable to find anything in the events
subsequent to that time that convinces us that the Department was
required to abandon this interpretation
A
The language of the 1897 statute evolved out of two earlier
countervailing duty provisions that had been applicable only to
sugar imports. The first provision was enacted in 1890, apparently
for the purpose of protecting domestic sugar refiners from unfair
foreign competition; it provided for a fixed countervailing duty on
refined sugar imported from countries that "pay, directly or
indirectly, a [greater] bounty on the exportation of" refined sugar
than on raw sugar. Tariff Act of 1890, 11237, 26 Stat. 584.
Although the congressional debates did not focus sharply on the
meaning of the word "bounty," what evidence there is suggests that
the term was not intended to encompass the nonexcessive remission
of an indirect tax. Thus, one strong supporter of increased
protection for American sugar producers heavily criticized the
export "bounties" conferred by several European governments, and
attached a concise description of "The Bounty Systems in Europe";
both the remarks and the description indicated that the "bounties"
consisted of the amounts by which government payments exceeded the
excise taxes that had been paid upon the beets from which the sugar
was produced.
See 21 Cong.Rec. 9529, 9532 (1890) (remarks
of Sen. Gibson);
id. at 9537 (description). According to
the description, for example, French sugar manufacturers paid
an
"excise tax [of] $97.06 per gross ton[,] [b]ut upon the export
of a ton of sugar . . . , received back as a drawback $117.60,
making a clear bounty of $20.54 per gross ton of sugar
exported."
Ibid.
Page 437 U. S. 452
This concept of a "net" bounty -- that is, a remission in excess
of taxes paid or otherwise due -- as the trigger for a
countervailing duty requirement emerged more clearly in the second
sugar provision, enacted in 1894. Tariff Act of 1894, � 182
1/2, 28 Stat. 521. The 1894 statute extended the countervailing
duty requirement to all imported sugar, raw as well as refined, and
provided for payment of a fixed duty on all sugar coming from a
country which "pays, directly or indirectly, a bounty on the export
thereof." A proviso to the statute made clear, however, that no
duties were to be assessed in the event that the "bounty" did not
exceed the amount of taxes already paid. [
Footnote 11] The author of the 1894 provision, Senator
Jones, expressly characterized this difference between the amounts
received upon exportation and the amounts already paid in taxes as
the "net bounty" on exportation. 26 Cong.Rec. 5705 (1894)
(discussing German export bounty system).
The 1897 statute greatly expanded upon the coverage of the 1894
provision by making the countervailing duty requirement applicable
to all imported products. Tariff Act of 1897, § 5, 30 Stat.
205, quoted in
n 8,
supra. There are strong indications, however, that
Congress intended to retain the "net bounty" concept of the 1894
provision as the criterion for determining when a countervailing
duty was to be imposed. Although the proviso in the 1894 law was
deleted, the 1897 statute did provide for levying of duties equal
to the "net amount" of any export bounty or grant. And the
legislative
Page 437 U. S. 453
history suggests that this language, in addition to establishing
a responsive mechanism for determining the appropriate amount of
countervailing duty, was intended to incorporate the prior rule
that nonexcessive remission of indirect taxes would not trigger the
countervailing duty requirement at all.
There is no question that the prior rule was carried forward in
the version of the 1897 statute that originally passed the House.
This version did not extend the countervailing duty requirement to
all imports. Instead, it merely modified the 1894 sugar provision
so that the amount of the countervailing duty, rather than being
fixed, would be
"equal to [the export] bounty, or so much thereof as may be in
excess of any tax collected by [the foreign] country upon [the]
exported [sugar], or upon the beet or cane from which it was
produced. . . ."
See 30 Cong.Rec. 1634 (187). The House Report
unequivocally stated that the countervailing duty was intended to
be "equivalent to the
net export bounty paid by any
country." H.R.Rep. No. 1, 55th Cong., 1st Sess., 4-5 (1897)
(emphasis supplied).
The Senate deleted the House provision from the bill and
replaced it with the more general provision that was eventually
enacted into law.
See 30 Cong.Rec. 1733 (1897) (striking
House provision);
id. at 2226 (adopting general
provision);
id. at 2705, 2750 (House agreement to Senate
amendment). The debates in the Senate indicate, however, that --
aside from extending the coverage of the House provision -- the
Senate did not intend to change its substance. Senator Allison, the
sponsor of the Senate amendment, explained that the House provision
was being "stricken from the bill," because "the same paragraph in
substance [is] being inserted [in] section [5], making this
countervailing duty apply to all articles instead of to [sugar]
alone."
Id. at 1635.
See also id. at 1732
(remarks of Sen. White). Senator Allison twice remarked that the
countervailing duty that he was proposing was an "imitation" of the
one provided in the 1894 statute,
Page 437 U. S. 454
id. at 1719;
see id. at 1674, and later in the
debates he stated -- in response to a question as to whether the
countervailing duty would be equal to "the whole amount of the
export bounty" -- that "[the bounty contemplated] is the net bounty
less the taxes and reductions . . . ,"
id. at 1721
(answering question from Sen. Vest).
An additional indication of the Senate's intent can be found in
the extended discussion of the effect that the statute would have
with respect to German sugar exports. Time after time, the amount
of the German "bounty" -- and, correspondingly, the amount of the
countervailing duty that would be imposed under the statute -- was
stated to be 38c per 100 pounds of refined sugar, and 27c per 100
pounds of raw sugar.
See, e.g.,id. at 1650 (remarks of
Sens. Allison, Vest, and Caffery), 1658 (Sens. Allison and Jones),
1680 (Sen. Jones), 1719 (Sens. Allison and Lindsay), 1729 (Sen.
Caffery), 2823-2824 (Sens. Aldrich and Jones). These figures were
supplied by the Treasury Department itself,
see id. at
1719 (remarks of Sen. Allison), 1722 (letter from Treasury
Department to Sen. Caffery), and were utilized by both proponents
and opponents of the measure. And yet it was frequently
acknowledged during the debates that Germany exempted sugar exports
from its domestic consumption tax of $2.16 per 100 pounds, an
amount far in excess of the 38c and 27c figures.
See, e.g.,
id. at 1646 (remarks of Sen. Vest), 1651 (Sen. Caffery), 1697
(same), 2205 (same). Had the Senators considered the mere remission
of an indirect tax to be a "bounty," it seems unlikely that they
would have stated that the German "bounties" were only 38 and 27c
per 100 pounds. [
Footnote
12] Especially in
Page 437 U. S. 455
light of the strong opposition to countervailing duties even of
the magnitude of 38c and 27c,
see, e.g., id. at 1719
(remarks of Sen. Lindsay), 2203-2205 (remarks of Sen. Gray), it
seems reasonable to infer that Congress did not intend to impose
countervailing duties of many times this magnitude.
B
Regardless of whether this legislative history absolutely
compelled the Secretary to interpret "bounty or grant" so as not to
encompass any nonexcessive remission of an indirect tax, there can
be no doubt that such a construction was reasonable in light of the
statutory purpose.
Cf. Mourning v. Family Publications Service,
Inc., 411 U. S. 356,
411 U. S. 374
(1973). This purpose is relatively clear from the face of the
statute, and is confirmed by the congressional debates: the
countervailing
Page 437 U. S. 456
duty was intended to offset the unfair competitive advantage
that foreign producers would otherwise enjoy from export subsidies
paid by their governments.
See, e.g., 30 Cong Rec. 1674
(remarks of Sen. Allison), 2205 (Sen. Caffery), 2225 (Sen. Lindsay)
(1897). The Treasury Department was well positioned to establish
rules of decision that would accurately carry out this purpose,
particularly since it had contributed the very figures relied upon
by Congress in enacting the statute.
See Zuber v. Allen,
396 U. S. 168,
396 U. S. 192
(1969).
In deciding in 1898 that a nonexcessive remission of indirect
taxes did not result in the type of competitive advantage that
Congress intended to counteract, the Department was clearly acting
in accordance with the shared assumptions of the day as to the
fairness and economic effect of that practice. The theory
underlying the Department's position was that a foreign country's
remission of indirect taxes did not constitute subsidization of
that country's exports. Rather, such remission was viewed as a
reasonable measure for avoiding double taxation of exports -- once
by the foreign country and once upon sale in this country. As
explained in a recent study prepared by the Department for the
Senate Committee on Finance:
"[The Department's construction was] based on the principle
that, since exports are not consumed in the country of production,
they should not be subject to consumption taxes in that country.
The theory has been that the application of countervailing duties
to the rebate of consumption [and other indirect] taxes would have
the effect of double taxation of the product, since the United
States would not only impose its own indirect taxes, such as
Federal and state excise taxes and state and local sales taxes, but
would also collect, through the use of the countervailing duty, the
indirect tax imposed by the
Page 437 U. S. 457
exporting country on domestically consumed goods."
Senate Committee on Finance, Executive Branch GATT Studies, 93d
Cong., 2d Sess., 17-18 (1974). This intuitively appealing principle
regarding double taxation had been widely accepted both in this
country and abroad for many years prior to enactment of the 1897
statute.
See, e.g., Act of July 4, 1789, § 3, 1 Stat.
26 (remission of import duties upon exportation of products); 4
Works and Correspondence of D. Ricardo 216-217 (pamphlets and
papers first published in 1822); A. Smith, An Inquiry Into the
Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, Book Four, ch. IV
(1776).
C
The Secretary's interpretation of the countervailing duty
statute is as permissible today as it was in 1898. The statute has
been reenacted five times by Congress without any modification of
the relevant language,
see n 8,
supra, and, whether or not Congress can be
said to have "acquiesced" in the administrative practice, it
certainly has not acted to change it. At the same time, the
Secretary's position has been incorporated into the General
Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), [
Footnote 13] which is followed by every major trading
nation in the world; foreign tax systems as well as private
expectations thus have been built on the assumption that
countervailing duties would not be imposed on nonexcessive
remissions of indirect taxes. In light of these substantial
reliance interests, the longstanding administrative construction of
the statute should "not be
Page 437 U. S. 458
disturbed except for cogent reasons."
McLaren v.
Flescher, 256 U. S. 477,
256 U. S. 481
(1921);
see Udall v. Tallman, 380 U.S. at
380 U. S. 18.
Aside from the contention, discussed in
437 U.
S. infra that the Department's construction is
inconsistent with this Court's decisions, petitioner's sole
argument is that the Department's position is premised on false
economic assumptions that should be rejected by the courts. In
particular, petitioner points to "modern" economic theory
suggesting that remission of indirect taxes may create an incentive
to export in some circumstances, and to recent criticism of the
GATT rules as favoring producers in countries that rely more
heavily on indirect than on direct taxes. [
Footnote 14] But, even assuming that these
arguments are at all relevant in view of the legislative history of
the 1897 provision and the longstanding administrative construction
of the statute, they do not demonstrate the unreasonableness of the
Secretary's current position. Even "modern" economists do not agree
on the ultimate economic effect of remitting indirect taxes, and --
given the present state of economic knowledge -- it may be
difficult, if not impossible, to measure the precise effect in any
particular case.
See, e.g., Executive Branch GATT Studies,
supra at 13-14, 17; Marks & Malmgren, Negotiating
Nontariff Distortions to Trade, 7 L. & Policy in Int'l Bus. 351
(1975). More fundamentally, as the Senate Committee with
responsibility in this
Page 437 U. S. 459
area recently stated,
"the issues involved in applying the countervailing duty law are
complex, and . . . internationally, there is [a] lack of any
satisfactory agreement on what constitutes a fair, as opposed to an
'unfair,' subsidy."
S.Rep. No. 93-1298, p. 183 (1974). In this situation, it is not
the task of the judiciary to substitute its views as to fairness
and economic effect for those of the Secretary.
III
Notwithstanding all of the foregoing considerations, this would
be a very different case if, as petitioner contends, the
Secretary's practice were contrary to this Court's decision in
Downs v. United States, 187 U. S. 496
(1903). [
Footnote 15] Upon
close examination of the admittedly opaque opinion in that case,
however, we do not believe that
Downs is controlling on
the question presented here.
The Russian sugar laws at issue in
Downs were, as the
Court noted, "very complicated."
Id. at
187 U. S. 502.
Much of the Court's opinion was devoted to an exposition of these
provisions,
see id. at
187 U. S.
502-512, but, for present purposes, only two features
are relevant: (1) excise taxes imposed on sugar sales within Russia
were remitted on exports; and (2) the exporter received, in
addition, a certificate entitling its bearer to sell an amount of
sugar in Russia, equal to the quantity exported, without paying the
full excise tax otherwise due. This certificate was transferable,
and had a substantial market value related to the amount of tax
forgiveness that it carried with it.
Page 437 U. S. 460
The Secretary, following the same interpretation of the statute
that he followed here, imposed a countervailing duty based on the
value of the certificates alone, and not on the excise taxes
remitted on the exports themselves. [
Footnote 16] Downs, the importer, sought review, claiming
that the Russian system did not confer any countervailable bounty
or grant within the meaning of the 1897 statute. He did not
otherwise challenge the amount of the duty assessed by the
Secretary. [
Footnote 17]
The issue as it came before this Court, therefore, was whether a
nonexcessive remission of an indirect tax, together with the
granting of an additional benefit represented by the value of the
certificate, constituted a "bounty or grant." Since the amount of
the bounty was not in question, neither the parties nor this Court
focused carefully on the distinction between remission of the
excise tax and conferral of the certificate. Petitioner argues,
however, that certain broad language in the Court's opinion
suggests that mere remission of a tax, even if nonexcessive, must
be considered a bounty or grant within the meaning of the statute.
Petitioner relies in particular on the following language:
"The details of this elaborate procedure for the production,
sale, taxation and exportation of Russian sugar are of much less
importance than the two facts which appear clearly through this
maze of regulations,
viz.: that no sugar is permitted to
be sold in Russia that does not pay an excise tax of R. 1.75 per
pood, and that sugar exported pays no tax at all. . . . When a tax
is imposed
Page 437 U. S. 461
upon all sugar produced, but is remitted upon all sugar
exported, then, by whatever process, or in whatever manner, or
under whatever name it is disguised, it is a bounty upon
exportation."
Id. at
187 U. S.
515.
This passage is inconsistent with both preceding and subsequent
language which suggests that the Court understood the "bounty" to
reside in the value of the certificates. At one point, the Court
stated that
"[t]he amount [the exporter] receives for his export certificate
[on the market], say, R. 1.25, is the exact amount of the bounty he
receives upon exportation. . . ."
Ibid. [
Footnote
18] And the Court in conclusion specifically endorsed the
Fourth Circuit's holding to the same effect,
see n 17,
supra:
"[T]he Circuit Court of Appeals found: 'That the Russian
exporter of sugar obtained from his government a certificate,
solely because of such exportation, which is worth in the open
market of that country from R. 1.25 to R. 1.64 per pood, or from
1.8 to 2.35 cents per pound. Therefore we hold that the government
of Russia does secure to the exporter of that country, as the
inevitable result of its action, a money reward or gratuity
whenever he exports sugar from Russia.' We all concur in this
expression of opinion."
187 U.S. at
187 U. S. 516.
Given this other language, we cannot read for its broadest
implications the passage on which petitioner relies. In our view,
the passage does no more than establish the proposition
Page 437 U. S. 462
that an excessive remission of taxes -- there, the combination
of the exemption with the certificates -- is an export bounty
within the meaning of the statute.
As the court below noted,
"'[i]t is a maxim not to be disregarded that general expressions
in every opinion are to be taken in connection with the case in
which those expressions are used.'"
64 C.C.P.A. at 134, 62 F.2d at 1213, quoting
Cohens v.
Virginia, 6 Wheat. 264,
19 U. S. 399
(1821). No one argued in
Downs that a nonexcessive
remission of taxes, standing alone, would have constituted a bounty
on exportation, and indeed that issue was not presented on the
facts of the case. It must also be remembered, of course, that the
Court did affirm the Secretary's decision, and that decision rested
on the conclusion that a bounty had been paid only to the extent
that the remission exceeded the taxes otherwise due. In light of
all these circumstances, the isolated statement in
Downs
relied upon by petitioner cannot be dispositive here.
The judgment of the Court of Customs and Patent Appeals is,
accordingly,
Affirmed.
[
Footnote 1]
Section 303(a) provides in relevant part:
"(1) Whenever any country, dependency, colony, province, or
other political subdivision of government, person, partnership,
association, cartel, or corporation, shall pay or bestow, directly
or indirectly, any bounty or grant upon the manufacture or
production or export of any article or merchandise manufactured or
produced in such country, dependency, colony, province, or other
political subdivision of government, then upon the importation of
such article or merchandise into the United States, whether the
same shall be imported directly from the country of production or
otherwise, and whether such article or merchandise is imported in
the same condition as when exported from the country of production
or has been changed in condition by remanufacture or otherwise,
there shall be levied and paid, in all such cases, in addition to
any duties otherwise imposed, a duty equal to the net amount of
such bounty or grant, however the same be paid or bestowed."
"
* * * *"
"(5) The Secretary shall from time to time ascertain and
determine, or estimate, the net amount of each such bounty or
grant, and shall declare the net amount so determined or
estimated."
"(6) The Secretary shall make all regulations he deems necessary
for the identification of articles and merchandise subject to
duties under this section and for the assessment and collection of
such duties. All determinations by the Secretary under this
section, and all determinations by the Commission under subsection
(b)(1) of this section (whether affirmative or negative) shall be
published in the Federal Register."
19 U.S.C. § 1303(a) (176 ed.).
[
Footnote 2]
See App. 12-13, 30-31; An Outline of Japanese Taxes
128-129 (Tax Bureau, Japanese Ministry of Finance, 1976). For the
products at issue here, the rate of taxation apparently ranges from
15% to 20%.
See App. 13-14; An Outline of Japanese Taxes,
supra at 131.
[
Footnote 3]
For purposes of this opinion, we adopt the convention followed
by the parties and use the term "remission" to encompass both the
exemption of exports from initial taxation and the refund to the
exporter of any taxes already paid.
[
Footnote 4]
The Secretary of the Treasury has delegated the authority to
make countervailing duty determinations to the Commissioner of
Customs, subject to the Secretary's approval.
See 19 CFR
§ 159.47 (1977).
[
Footnote 5]
The products included television receivers, radio receivers,
radiophonograph combinations, radio-television-phonograph
combinations, radio-tape-recorder combinations, record players and
phonographs complete with amplifiers and speakers, tape recorders,
tape players, and color television picture tubes.
See 37
Fed.Reg. 10087, App. A (1972), as amended, 37 Fed.Reg. 11487
(1972).
[
Footnote 6]
The notice stated in relevant part that,
"on the basis of the . . . facts gathered and the investigation
conducted pursuant to . . . Customs Regulations . . . , a final
determination is hereby made . . . that . . . no bounty or grant is
being paid or bestowed, directly or indirectly, within the meaning
of section 303 . . . upon the . . . exportation of certain consumer
electronic products from Japan."
41 Fed.Reg. 1298 (1976).
[
Footnote 7]
Suit was filed pursuant to a provision, enacted in 1975,
authorizing American manufacturers, producers, and wholesalers to
seek review in the Customs Court of administrative decisions not to
impose countervailing duties under § 303. Tariff Act of 1930,
as amended, § 516(d), 19 U.S.C. § 1516(d) (1976 ed.).
[
Footnote 8]
Section 5 of the Tariff Act of July 24, 1897, 30 Stat. 205,
provided in full:
"That whenever any country, dependency, or colony shall pay or
bestow, directly or indirectly, any bounty or grant upon the
exportation of any article or merchandise from such country,
dependency, or colony, and such article or merchandise is dutiable
under the provisions of this Act, then upon the importation of any
such article or merchandise into the United States, whether the
same shall be imported directly from the country of production or
otherwise, and whether such article or merchandise is imported in
the same condition as when exported from the country of production
or has been changed in condition by remanufacture or otherwise,
there shall be levied and paid, in all such cases, in addition to
the duties otherwise imposed by this Act, an additional duty equal
to the net amount of such bounty or grant, however the same be paid
or bestowed. The net amount of all such bounties or grants shall be
from time to time ascertained, determined, and declared by the
Secretary of the Treasury, who shall make all needful regulations
for the identification of such articles and merchandise and for the
assessment and collection of such additional duties."
The current version of § 303 represents the fifth
reenactment of the 1897 provision without any changes relevant
here. Tariff Act of 1909, § 6, 36 Stat. 85; Tariff Act of
1913, § IV(E), 38 Stat. 193; Tariff Act of 1922, § 303,
42 Stat. 935; Tariff Act of 1930, § 303, 46 Stat. 687; Trade
Act of 1974, § 331(a), 88 Stat. 2049.
[
Footnote 9]
There is no dispute here regarding either the nonexcessive
nature of the remission or the indirect nature of the tax.
Moreover, although the Department did not so state in the notice of
final determination,
see n 6,
supra, petitioner does not dispute that the
Department's decision in this case was based on its longstanding
position that the nonexcessive remission of an indirect tax is not
a bounty or grant.
[
Footnote 10]
See, e.g., T.D.19729, 2 Synopsis of Decisions 157
(1898); T.D. 20039, 2 Synopsis of Decisions 534 (1898); T.D. 43634,
56 Treas.Dec. 342 (1929); T.D. 49355, 73 Treas. Dec. 107
(1938).
[
Footnote 11]
The proviso specified that
"the importer of sugar produced in a foreign country, the
Government of which grants such direct or indirect bounties, may be
relieved from this additional duty under such regulations as the
Secretary of the Treasury may prescribe, in case said importer
produces a certificate of said Government that
no indirect
bounty has been received upon said sugar in excess of the tax
collected upon the beet or cane from which it was produced,
and that no direct bounty has been or shall be paid. . . ."
28 Stat. 521 (emphasis added).
[
Footnote 12]
The figures of 38 and 27c per 100 pounds apparently represented
the amount of direct bounty paid upon exportation.
See,
e.g., 30 Cong.Rec. 1722 (1897) (letter from Treasury
Department).
Petitioner argues that the Senate must have intended the term
"bounty" to include nonexcessive remissions of indirect taxes,
since Germany collected a tax on the output of sugar factories that
was not remitted upon exportation and yet was not subtracted from
the figures of 38c and 27c cited as the "bounties" paid by Germany.
The sole evidence cited by petitioner to show that Germany in fact
collected such a tax is an exhibit to the testimony of a single
witness during hearings conducted by the House in 1896.
See Tariff Hearings before the House Committee on Ways and
Means, 54th Cong., 2d Sess., 617-618 (1896-1897). We have been
unable to find any references to this tax anywhere in the Senate
debates; moreover, to the extent that anyone contemplated the
existence of German taxes that were not remitted upon exportation,
the assumption appears to have been that they would be deducted
from the 38c and 27c figures in determining the net amount of the
bounty to be countervailed. The following exchange between Senators
Allison and Vest is illustrative:
"Mr. VEST. What . . . is the amount of export bounty, taking out
taxes, etc., granted by Germany?"
"Mr. ALLISON. . . . Of course, it can not exceed three-eighths
of a cent a pound -- thirty-eight one-hundredths on refined sugar
-- nor can it exceed twenty-seven one-hundredths upon raw sugar.
But it may be very much less."
30 Cong.Rec. 1721 (1897). We note in any event that the amount
of the tax cited by petitioner was less than 2c per 100 pounds,
see Tariff Hearings,
supra at 617, whereas the
consumption tax -- which concededly was remitted upon exportation
and yet not added to the figures of 38c and 27c -- was in the
vicinity of $2.16 per 100 pounds.
[
Footnote 13]
Article VI(3) of the GATT, adopted in 1947, 61 Stat. A24,
provides that
"[n]o product . . . imported into the territory of any other
contracting party shall be subject to . . . countervailing duty by
reason of the exemption of such product from . . . taxes borne by
the like product when destined for consumption in the country of
origin or exportation, or by reason of the refund of such . . .
taxes."
The Government does not contend that the GATT provision would
supersede § 303 in the event of conflict between the two.
Brief for United States 19 n. 11.
[
Footnote 14]
See, e.g., Marks & Malmgren, Negotiating Nontariff
Distortions to Trade, 7 L. & Policy in Int'l Bus. 327, 351-355
(1975); The United States Submission on Border Tax Adjustments to
Working Party No. 4 of the Council on Border Tax Adjustments,
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (1966),
reprinted in App. 93-116; Paper Submitted by John R. Petty, Ass't
Sec'y of the Treasury, Twenty-First Annual Conference of the
Canadian Tax Foundation (1968), reprinted in App. 117-138. Both the
Secretary and GATT apparently consider remissions of direct taxes
(
e.g., income taxes) to be countervailable export
subsidies.
See Brief for United States 18 n. 10, 37-38;
GATT, Basic Instrument and Selected Documents 186-187 (Supp.
1961).
[
Footnote 15]
Petitioner also relies on language in
G. S. Nicholas &
Co. v. United States, 249 U. S. 34
(1919), suggesting that the countervailing duty statute was
intended to be read broadly.
See id. at
249 U. S. 39-41.
As petitioner concedes, however, the only question before the Court
in that case was whether a direct bounty on exportation of liquor
from Great Britain was a "bounty or grant" within the meaning of
the statute,
see Brief for Petitioner 117, and the Court
did not address the question of whether nonexcessive remission of
an indirect tax fell within the statute.
[
Footnote 16]
See Memorandum from the Secretary of the Treasury
(1901), reprinted in App. 49-51; T.D. 20407, 2 Synopsis of
Decisions 996, 997-998 (1898); T.D. 22814, 4 Treas.Dec. 184 (1901);
Downs v. United States, 113 F. 144, 145 (CA4 1902).
[
Footnote 17]
In rejecting Downs' claim, both the United States Board of
General Appraisers and the Fourth Circuit Court of Appeals
identified the "bounty" as residing in the value of the
certificates granted upon exportation.
See T.D. 22984, 4
Treas.Dec. 405, 410-411, 413 (1901);
Downs v. United States,
supra, at 145.
[
Footnote 18]
The Court also noted that
"[i]t is practically admitted in this case that a bounty equal
to the value of [the] certificates is paid by the Russian
government, and the main argument of the petitioner is addressed to
the proposition that this bounty is paid not upon exportation, but
upon production."
187 U.S. at
187 U. S. 512.
This latter argument was based on the fact that the 1897 statute
covered only bounties on exportation, and not those on production.
In 1922, Congress amended the statute to cover bounties on
production and manufacture as well as exportation. Tariff Act of
1922,
supra, n 8.