Petitioner cities, which own and operate electric utility
systems both within and beyond their respective city limits as
authorized by Louisiana law, brought an action in District Court
against respondent investor-owned electric utility with which
petitioners compete, alleging that it committed various federal
antitrust offenses that injured petitioners in the operation of
their electric utility systems. Respondent counterclaimed, alleging
that petitioners had committed various antitrust offenses that
injured respondent in its business and property. Petitioners moved
to dismiss the counterclaim on the ground that, as cities and
subdivisions of the State, the "state action" doctrine of
Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341,
rendered federal antitrust laws inapplicable to them. The District
Court granted the motion, but the Court of Appeals reversed and
remanded.
Held: Apart from whether petitioners are exempt from
the antitrust laws as agents of the State under the
Parker
doctrine, there are insufficient grounds for inferring that
Congress did not intend to subject cities to antitrust liability.
Pp.
435 U. S.
394-408.
(a) The definition of "person" or "persons" covered by the
antitrust laws clearly includes cities, whether as municipal
utility operators suing as plaintiffs seeking damages for antitrust
violations or as such operators being sued as defendants.
Chattanooga Foundry & Pipe Works v. Atlanta,
203 U. S. 390;
Georgia v. Evans, 316 U. S. 159. Pp.
435 U. S.
394-397.
(b) Petitioners have failed to show the existence of any
overriding public policy inconsistent with a construction of
coverage of the antitrust laws. The presumption against implied
exclusion from such laws cannot be negated either on the ground
that it would be anomalous to subject municipalities to antitrust
liability or on the ground that the antitrust laws are intended to
protect the public only from abuses of private power, and not from
action of municipalities that exist to serve the public weal. Pp.
435 U. S.
400-408.
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN, joined by MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL, MR. JUSTICE
POWELL, and MR. JUSTICE STEVENS, concluded:
1.
Parker v. Brown does not automatically exempt from
the antitrust
Page 435 U. S. 390
laws all governmental entities, whether state agencies or
subdivisions of a State, simply by reason of their status as such,
but exempts only anticompetitive conduct engaged in as an act of
government by the State as sovereign, or by its subdivisions,
pursuant to state policy to displace competition with regulation or
monopoly public service. Pp.
435 U. S.
408-413.
2. The Court of Appeals did not err in holding that further
inquiry should be made to determine whether petitioners' actions
were directed by the State, since, when the State itself has not
directed or authorized an anticompetitive practice, the State's
subdivisions, in exercising their delegated power, must obey the
antitrust laws. While a subordinate governmental unit's claim to
Parker immunity is not as readily established as the same
claim by a state government, sued as such, an adequate state
mandate for anticompetitive activities of cities and other
subordinate governmental units exists when it is found,
"from the authority given a governmental entity to operate in a
particular area, that the legislature contemplated the kind of
action complained of."
Pp.
435 U. S.
413-417.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE, while agreeing with the directions for remand
in Part III because they represent, at a minimum, what is required
to establish an exemption, would insist that the State compel the
alleged anticompetitive activity, and that the cities demonstrate
that the exemption is essential to the state regulatory scheme. Pp.
435 U. S.
425-426, and n. 6.
532 F.2d 431, affirmed.
BRENNAN, J., announced the judgment of the Court and delivered
the opinion of the Court with respect to Part I, in which BURGER,
C.J., and MARSHALL, POWELL, and STEVENS, JJ., joined; and an
opinion with respect to Parts II and III, in which MARSHALL,
POWELL, and STEVENS, JJ., joined. MARSHALL, J., filed a concurring
opinion,
post, p.
435 U. S. 417. BURGER, C.J., filed an opinion concurring
in part and concurring in the judgment,
post, p.
435 U. S. 418.
STEWART, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which WHITE and
REHNQUIST, JJ., joined, and in all but Part II-B of which BLACKMUN,
J., joined,
post, p.
435 U. S. 426.
BLACKMUN, J., filed a dissenting opinion,
post, p.
435 U. S.
441.
Page 435 U. S. 391
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN delivered the opinion of the Court (Part I),
together with an opinion (Parts II and III), in which MR. JUSTICE
MARSHALL, MR. JUSTICE POWELL, and MR. JUSTICE STEVENS joined.
Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341
(1943), held that the federal antitrust laws do not prohibit a
State "as sovereign" from imposing certain anticompetitive
restraints "as an act of government." The question in this case is
the extent to which the antitrust laws prohibit a State's cities
from imposing such anticompetitive restraints.
Petitioner cities are organized under the laws of the State of
Louisiana, [
Footnote 1] which
grant them power to own and operate electric utility systems both
within and beyond their city limits. [
Footnote 2] Petitioners brought this action in the
District Court for the Eastern District of Louisiana, alleging
that, among others, [
Footnote
3] Louisiana Power & Light Co. (LP&L), an
investor-owned electric service utility with which petitioners
compete
Page 435 U. S. 392
in the areas beyond their city limits, [
Footnote 4] committed various antitrust offenses which
injured petitioners in the operation of their electric utility
systems. [
Footnote 5] LP&L
counterclaimed, seeking damages and injunctive relief for various
antitrust offenses which petitioners had allegedly committed and
which injured it in its business and property. [
Footnote 6]
Petitioners moved to dismiss the counterclaim on the ground
that, as cities and subdivisions of the State of Louisiana, the
"state action" doctrine of
Parker v. Brown rendered
federal antitrust laws inapplicable to them. The District Court
granted the motion, holding that the decision of the Court of
Appeals for the Fifth Circuit in
Saenz v. University
Interscholastic League, 487 F.2d 1026 (1973), required
dismissal, notwithstanding that "[t]hese plaintiff cities are
engaging in what is clearly a business activity . . . in which a
profit is realized," and "for this reason . . . , this court is
reluctant to
Page 435 U. S. 393
hold that the antitrust laws do not apply to
any state
activity." [
Footnote 7] App. 47
(emphasis in original). The District Court in this case read
Saenz to interpret the "state action" exemption [
Footnote 8] as requiring the "holding
that purely state government activities are not subject to the
requirements of the antitrust laws of the United States," App. 48,
thereby making petitioners' status as cities determinative against
maintenance of antitrust suits against them. The Court of Appeals
for the Fifth Circuit reversed and remanded for further
proceedings. [
Footnote 9] 532
F.2d 431 (1976). The Court of Appeals noted that the District Court
had acted before this Court's decision in
Goldfarb v. Virginia
State Bar, 421 U. S. 773
(1975), and held that, "taken together"
Parker v. Brown
and
Goldfarb "require the following analysis":
"A subordinate state governmental body is not
ipso
facto exempt from the operation of the antitrust laws. Rather,
a district court must ask whether the state legislature
contemplated a certain type of anticompetitive restraint. In our
opinion, though, it is not necessary to point to an
Page 435 U. S. 394
express statutory mandate for each act which is alleged to
violate the antitrust laws. It will suffice if the challenged
activity was clearly within the legislative intent. Thus, a trial
judge may ascertain, from the authority given a governmental entity
to operate in a particular area, that the legislature contemplated
the kind of action complained of. On the other hand, as in
Goldfarb, the connection between a legislative grant of
power and the subordinate entity's asserted use of that power may
be too tenuous to permit the conclusion that the entity's intended
scope of activity encompassed such conduct. Whether a governmental
body's actions are comprehended within the powers granted to it by
the legislature is, of course, a determination which can be made
only under the specific facts in each case. A district judge's
inquiry on this point should be broad enough to include all
evidence which might show the scope of legislative intent."
532 F.2d at 434-435 (footnotes omitted). We granted certiorari,
430 U.S. 944 (1977). We affirm.
I
Petitioners' principal argument is that,
"since a city is merely a subdivision of a state, and only
exercises power delegated to it by the state,
Parker's
findings regarding the congressionally intended scope of the
Sherman Act apply with equal force to such political
subdivisions."
Brief for Petitioners 5. Before addressing this question,
however, we shall address the contention implicit in petitioners'
arguments in their brief that, apart from the question of their
exemption as agents of the State under the
Parker
doctrine, Congress never intended to subject local governments to
the antitrust laws.
A
The antitrust laws impose liability on and create a cause of
action for damages for a "person" or "persons" as defined in
Page 435 U. S. 395
the Acts. [
Footnote 10]
Since the Court has held that the definition of "person" or
"persons" embraces both cities and States, it is understandable
that the cities do not argue that they are not "persons" within the
meaning of the antitrust laws.
Section 8 of the Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 210, 15 U.S.C.
§ 7 (1976 ed.), and § 1 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 730,
15 U.S.C. § 12 (1976 ed.), are general definitional sections
which define "person" or "persons,"
"wherever used in this [Act] . . . , to include corporations and
associations existing under or authorized by the laws of either the
United States, the laws of any of the Territories, the laws of any
State, or the laws of any foreign country. [
Footnote 11]"
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 731, 15 U.S.C. § 15
(1976 ed.), provides,
Page 435 U. S. 396
in pertinent part, that
"[a]ny person who shall be injured in his business or property
by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue
therefor in any district court . . . , and shall recover threefold
the damages by him sustained. . . . [
Footnote 12]"
Chattanooga Foundry & Pipe Works v. Atlanta,
203 U. S. 390
(196), held that a municipality is a "person" within the meaning of
§ 8 of the Sherman Act, the general definitional section, and
that the city of Atlanta therefore could maintain a treble damages
action under § 7, the predecessor of § 4 of the Clayton
Act, [
Footnote 13] against a
supplier from whom the city purchased water pipe which it used to
furnish water as a municipal utility service. Some 36 years later,
Georgia v. Evans, 316 U. S. 159
(1942), held that the words "any person" in § 7 of the Sherman
Act included States. Under that decision, the State of Georgia was
permitted to bring an action in its own name charging injury from a
combination to fix prices and suppress competition in the market
for asphalt which the
Page 435 U. S. 397
State purchased annually for use in the construction of public
roads. The Court reasoned that "[n]othing in the Act, its history,
or its policy, could justify so restrictive a construction of the
word
person' in § 7 as to exclude a State." 316 U.S. at
316 U. S.
162.
Although both
Chattanooga Foundry and
Georgia v.
Evans involved the public bodies as plaintiffs, whereas
petitioners in the instant case are defendants to a counterclaim,
the basis of those decisions plainly precludes a reading of
"person" or "persons" to include municipal utility operators that
sue as plaintiffs, but not to include such municipal operators when
sued as defendants. Thus, the conclusion that the antitrust laws
are not to be construed as meant by Congress to subject cities to
liability under the antitrust laws must rest on the impact of some
overriding public policy which negates the construction of
coverage, and not upon a reading of "person" or "persons" as not
including them. [
Footnote
14]
B
Petitioners suggest several reasons why, in addition to their
arguments for exemption as agents of the State under the
Parker doctrine, a congressional purpose not to subject
cities
Page 435 U. S. 398
to the antitrust laws should be inferred. Those arguments, like
the
Parker exemption itself, necessarily must be
considered in light of the presumption against implied exclusions
from coverage under the antitrust laws.
(1)
The purposes and intended scope of the Sherman Act have been
developed in prior cases, and require only brief mention here.
Commenting upon the language of the Act in rejecting a claim that
the insurance business was excluded from coverage, the Court
stated:
"Language more comprehensive is difficult to conceive. On its
face, it shows a carefully studied attempt to bring within the Act
every person engaged in business whose activities might restrain or
monopolize commercial intercourse among the states."
United States v. South-Eastern Underwriters Assn.,
322 U. S. 533,
322 U. S. 553
(1944). That and subsequent cases reviewing the legislative history
of the Sherman Act have concluded that Congress, exercising the
full extent of its constitutional power, [
Footnote 15] sought to establish a regime of
competition as the fundamental principle governing commerce in this
country. [
Footnote 16]
For this reason, our cases have held that, even when Congress,
by subsequent legislation, establishes a regulatory regime over an
area of commercial activity, the antitrust laws will not be
displaced unless it appears that the antitrust and regulatory
provisions are plainly repugnant.
E.g., 374 U.
S.
Page 435 U. S. 399
Philadelphia Nat. Bank, 374 U.
S. 321,
374 U. S.
350-351, and n. 28 (1963) (collecting cases). The
presumption against repeal by implication reflects the
understanding that the antitrust laws establish overarching and
fundamental policies, a principle which argues with equal force
against implied exclusions.
See Goldfarb, 421 U.S. at
435 U. S.
786-788.
Two policies have been held sufficiently weighty to override the
presumption against implied exclusions from coverage of the
antitrust laws. In
Eastern Railroad Presidents Conf. v. Noerr
Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U. S. 127
(1961), the Court held that, regardless of anticompetitive purpose
or intent, a concerted effort by persons to influence lawmakers to
enact legislation beneficial to themselves or detrimental to
competitors was not within the scope of the antitrust laws.
Although there is nothing in the language of the statute or its
history which would indicate that Congress considered such an
exclusion, the impact of two correlative principles was held to
require the conclusion that the presumption should not support a
finding of coverage. The first is that a contrary construction
would impede the open communication between the polity and its
lawmakers which is vital to the functioning of a representative
democracy. Second, "and of at least equal significance," is the
threat to the constitutionally protected right of petition which a
contrary construction would entail.
Id. at
365 U. S.
137-138. [
Footnote
17]
Page 435 U. S. 400
Parker v. Brown [
Footnote 18] identified a second overriding policy,
namely that,
"[i]n a dual system of government in which, under the
Constitution, the states are sovereign, save only as Congress may
constitutionally subtract from their authority, an unexpressed
purpose to nullify a state's control over its officers and agents
is not lightly to be attributed to Congress."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
351.
Common to the two implied exclusions was potential conflict with
policies of signal importance in our national traditions and
governmental structure of federalism. Even then, however, the
recognized exclusions have been unavailing to prevent antitrust
enforcement which, though implicating those fundamental policies,
was not thought severely to impinge upon them.
See,
e.g.,Goldfarb, supra; California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking
Unlimited, 404 U. S. 508
(1972).
Petitioners' arguments therefore cannot prevail unless they
demonstrate that there are countervailing policies which are
sufficiently weighty to overcome the presumption. We now turn to a
consideration of whether, apart from the question of their
exemption as agents of the State under the
Parker
doctrine, petitioners have made that showing.
(2)
Petitioners argue that their exclusion must be inferred because
it would be anomalous to subject municipalities to the criminal and
civil liabilities imposed upon violators of the antitrust laws. The
short answer is that it has not been regarded as anomalous to
require compliance by municipalities with the substantive standards
of other federal laws which impose such sanctions upon "persons."
See Union Pacific
R.
Page 435 U. S. 401
Co. v. United States, 313 U. S. 450
(1941). [
Footnote 19]
See generally Ohio v. Helvering, 292 U.
S. 360,
292 U. S. 370
(1934); [
Footnote 20]
California v. United States, 320 U.
S. 577 (144). [
Footnote 21] But those cases do not
Page 435 U. S. 402
necessarily require the conclusion that remedies appropriate to
redress violations by private corporations would be equally
appropriate for municipalities; nor need we decide any question of
remedy in this case. [
Footnote
22]
Page 435 U. S. 403
Petitioners next argue that the antitrust laws are intended to
protect the public only from abuses of private power, and not from
actions of municipalities that exist to serve the public weal.
Petitioners' contention that their goal is not private profit,
but public service, is only partly correct. Every business
enterprise, public or private, operates its business in furtherance
of its own goals. In the case of a municipally owned utility, that
goal is likely to be, broadly speaking, the benefit of its
citizens. But the economic choices made by public corporations in
the conduct of their business affairs, designed as they are to
assure maximum benefits for the community constituency, are not
inherently more likely to comport with the broader interests of
national economic wellbeing than are those of private corporations
acting in furtherance of the interests of the organization and its
shareholders. The allegations of the counterclaim, which, for
present purposes, we accept as true, [
Footnote 23] aptly illustrate the impact which local
governments, acting as providers of services, may have on other
individuals and business enterprises with which they interrelate as
purchasers, suppliers, and sometimes, as here, as competitors.
[
Footnote 24]
LP&L alleged that the city of Plaquemine contracted to
provide LP&L's electric customers outside its city limits gas
and water service only on condition that the customers purchase
Page 435 U. S. 404
electricity from the city and not from LP&L. [
Footnote 25] The effect of such a tie-in is
twofold. First, the tying contract might injure former LP&L
customers in two ways. The net effect of the tying contract might
be to increase the cost of electric service to these customers.
Moreover, a municipality conceivably might charge discriminatorily
higher rates to such captive customers outside its jurisdiction
without a cost-justified basis. Both of these practices would
provide maximum benefits for its constituents, while disserving the
interests of the affected customers. Second, the practice would
necessarily have an impact on the regulated public utility whose
service is displaced. [
Footnote
26] The elimination of customers in an established service area
would likely reduce revenues, and possibly require abandonment or
loss of existing equipment the effect of which would be to reduce
its rate base and possibly affect its capital structure. The
surviving customers and the investor-owners would bear the brunt of
these consequences. The decision to displace existing service,
rather than being made on the basis of efficiency in the
distribution of services, may be made by the municipality in the
interest of realizing maximum benefits to itself without regard to
extraterritorial impact and regional efficiency. [
Footnote 27]
Page 435 U. S. 405
The second allegation of LP&L's counterclaim, [
Footnote 28] is that petitioners
conspired with others to engage in sham and frivolous litigation
against LP&L before various federal agencies [
Footnote 29] and federal courts for the
purpose, and with the effect, of delaying approval and construction
of LP&L's proposed nuclear electric generating plant. It is
alleged that this course of conduct was designed to deprive
LP&L of needed financing, and to impose delay costs, amounting
to $180 million, which would effectively block construction of the
proposed project. Such activity may benefit the citizens of
Plaquemine and Lafayette by eliminating a competitive threat to
expansion of the municipal utilities in still undeveloped areas
beyond the cities' territorial limits. But that kind of activity,
if truly anticompetitive, [
Footnote 30] may impose enormous unnecessary costs on the
potential customers of the nuclear generating facility both within
and beyond the cities' proposed area of expansion. In addition, it
may cause significant injury to LP&L, interfering with its
ability to provide expanded service.
Another aspect of the public service argument [
Footnote 31] is that,
Page 435 U. S. 406
because government is subject to political control, the welfare
of its citizens is assured through the political process, and that
federal antitrust regulation is therefore unnecessary. The argument
that consumers dissatisfied with the service provided by the
municipal utilities may seek redress through the political process
is without merit. While petitioners recognize, as they must, that
those consumers living outside the municipality who are forced to
take municipal service have no political recourse at the municipal
level, they argue nevertheless that the customers may take their
complaints to the state legislature. It fairly may be questioned
whether the consumers in question or the Florida corporation of
which LP&L is a subsidiary have a meaningful chance of
influencing the state legislature to outlaw on an
ad hoc
basis whatever anticompetitive practices petitioners may direct
against them from time to time. More fundamentally, however, that
argument cuts far too broadly; the same argument may be made
regarding anticompetitive activity in which any corporation
engages. Mulcted consumers and unfairly displaced competitors may
always seek redress through the political process. In enacting the
Sherman Act, however, Congress mandated competition as the polestar
by which all must be guided in ordering their business affairs. It
did not leave this fundamental national policy to the vagaries of
the political process, but established a broad policy, to be
administered by neutral courts, [
Footnote 32] which
Page 435 U. S. 407
would guarantee every enterprise the right to exercise "whatever
economic muscle it can muster,"
United States v. Topco
Associates, 405 U. S. 596,
405 U. S. 610
(1972), without regard to the amount of influence it might have
with local or state legislatures. [
Footnote 33]
In 1972, there were 62,437 different units of local government
in this country. [
Footnote
34] Of this number 23,885 were special districts which had a
defined goal or goals for the provision of one or several services,
[
Footnote 35] while the
remaining 38,552 represented
Page 435 U. S. 408
the number of counties, municipalities, and townships, most of
which have broad authority for general governance subject to
limitations in one way or another imposed by the State. [
Footnote 36] These units may, and
do, participate in and affect the economic life of this Nation in a
great number and variety of ways. When these bodies act as owners
and providers of services, they are fully capable of aggrandizing
other economic units with which they interrelate, with the
potential of serious distortion of the rational and efficient
allocation of resources, and the efficiency of free markets which
the regime of competition embodied in the antitrust laws is thought
to engender. [
Footnote 37]
If municipalities were free to make economic choices counseled
solely by their own parochial interests and without regard to their
anticompetitive effects, a serious chink in the armor of antitrust
protection would be introduced at odds with the comprehensive
national policy Congress established. [
Footnote 38]
We conclude that these additional arguments for implying an
exclusion for local governments from the antitrust laws must be
rejected. We therefore turn to petitioners' principal argument,
that
"
Parker's findings regarding the congressionally
intended scope of the Sherman Act apply with equal force to such
political subdivisions."
Brief for Petitioners 5.
II
Plainly, petitioners are in error in arguing that
Parker held that all governmental entities, whether state
agencies or subdivisions of a State, are, simply by reason of their
status as such, exempt from the antitrust laws.
Parker v. Brown involved the California Agricultural
Prorate
Page 435 U. S. 409
Act enacted by the California Legislature as a program to be
enforced
"through action of state officials . . . to restrict competition
among the growers [of raisins] and maintain prices in the
distribution of their commodities to packers."
317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 346.
The Court held that the program was not prohibited by the federal
antitrust laws, since
"nothing in the language of the Sherman Act or in its history .
. . suggests that its purpose was to restrain a state or its
officers or agents from activities directed by its
legislature,"
id. at
317 U. S.
350-351, and "[t]he state . . . as sovereign, imposed
the restraint as an act of government which the Sherman Act did not
undertake to prohibit."
Id. at
317 U. S.
352.
Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar, 421 U.
S. 773 (1975), underscored the significance of
Parker's holding that the determinant of the exemption was
whether the challenged action was "an act of government" by the
State as "sovereign."
Parker repeatedly emphasized that
the anticompetitive effects of California's prorate program derived
from "the state['s] command"; the State adopted, organized, and
enforced the program "in the execution of a governmental policy."
[
Footnote 39] 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 352.
Goldfarb, on the other hand, presented the question
"whether a minimum fee schedule for lawyers published by the
Fairfax County Bar Association and enforced by the Virginia State
Bar," 421 U.S. at
421 U. S. 775,
violated the Sherman Act. Exemption was claimed on the ground that
the Virginia State Bar was "a state agency by law."
Id. at
421 U. S. 790.
The Virginia Legislature had empowered the Supreme Court of
Virginia to regulate the practice of law and had assigned the State
Bar a role in that regulation as an administrative agency of the
Virginia Supreme Court. But no Virginia statute referred to
lawyers' fees, and the Supreme Court of Virginia had taken no
action requiring the use of and adherence to minimum
Page 435 U. S. 410
fee schedules.
Goldfarb therefore held that it could
not be said that the anticompetitive effects of minimum fee
schedules were directed by the State acting as sovereign.
Id. at
421 U. S. 791.
The State Bar, though acting within its broad powers, had
"voluntarily joined in what is essentially a private
anticompetitive activity,"
id. at
421 U. S. 792,
and was not executing the mandate of the State. Thus, the actions
of the State Bar had failed to meet "[t]he threshold inquiry in
determining if an anticompetitive activity is state action of the
type the Sherman Act was not meant to proscribe. . . ."
Id. at
421 U. S. 790.
Goldfarb therefore made it clear that, for purposes of the
Parker doctrine, not every act of a state agency is that
of the State as sovereign.
Bates v. State Bar of Arizona, 433 U.
S. 350 (1977), involved the actions of a state agency to
which the
Parker exemption applied.
Bates
considered the applicability of the antitrust laws to a ban on
attorney advertising directly imposed by the Arizona Supreme Court.
In holding the antitrust laws inapplicable,
Bates noted
that
"[t]hat court is the ultimate body wielding the State's power
over the practice of law,
see Ariz.Const., Art. 3;
In
re Bailey, 30 Ariz. 407, 248 P. 29 (1926), and, thus, the
restraint is 'compelled by direction of the State acting as a
sovereign.'"
Id. at
433 U. S. 360,
quoting
Goldfarb, supra, at
421 U. S. 731.
We emphasized, moreover, the significance to our conclusion of the
fact that the state policy requiring the anticompetitive restraint
as part of a comprehensive regulatory system was one clearly
articulated and affirmatively expressed as state policy, and that
the State's policy was actively supervised by the State Supreme
Court as the policymaker. [
Footnote 40]
Page 435 U. S. 411
These decisions require rejection of petitioners' proposition
that their status as such automatically affords governmental
entities the "state action" exemption. [
Footnote 41]
Parker's limitation
Page 435 U. S. 412
of the exemption, as applied by
Goldfarb and
Bates, to "official action directed by [the] state,"
arises from the basis for the "state action" doctrine -- that,
given our
"dual system of government in which, under the Constitution, the
states are sovereign, save only as Congress may constitutionally
subtract from their authority,"
317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351,
a congressional purpose to subject to antitrust control the States'
acts of government will not lightly be inferred. To extend that
doctrine to municipalities would be inconsistent with that
limitation. Cities are not themselves sovereign; they do not
receive all the federal deference of the States that create them.
See, e.g., Edelman v. Jordan, 415 U.
S. 651,
415 U. S. 667
n. 12 (1974);
Lincoln County v. Luning, 133 U.
S. 529 (1890) (political subdivisions not protected by
Eleventh Amendment from immunity from suit in federal court).
Parker's limitation of the exemption to "official action
directed by a state," 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351,
is consistent with the fact that the States' subdivisions generally
have not been treated as equivalents of the States themselves.
[
Footnote 42] In light of
the serious economic dislocation which
Page 435 U. S. 413
could result if cities were free to place their own parochial
interests above the Nation's economic goals reflected in the
antitrust laws,
see supra at
435 U. S.
403-408, we are especially unwilling to presume that
Congress intended to exclude anticompetitive municipal action from
their reach.
On the other hand, the fact that municipalities, simply by their
status as such, are not within the
Parker doctrine does
not necessarily mean that all of their anticompetitive activities
are subject to antitrust restraints. Since "[m]unicipal
corporations are instrumentalities of the State for the convenient
administration of government within their limits,"
Louisiana ex
rel. Folsom v. Mayor of New Orleans, 109 U.
S. 285,
109 U. S. 287
(1883), the actions of municipalities may reflect state policy. We
therefore conclude that the
Parker doctrine exempts only
anticompetitive conduct engaged in as an act of government by the
State as sovereign, or, by its subdivisions, pursuant to state
policy to displace competition with regulation or monopoly public
service. There remains the question whether the Court of Appeals
erred in holding that further inquiry should be made to determine
whether petitioners' actions were directed by the State.
III
The petitioners and our Brother STEWART's dissent focus their
arguments upon the fact that municipalities may exercise the
sovereign power of the State, concluding from this that any actions
which municipalities take necessarily reflect state policy, and
must therefore fall within the
Parker doctrine.
Page 435 U. S. 414
But the fact that the governmental bodies sued are cities, with
substantially less than statewide jurisdiction, has significance.
When cities, each of the same status under state law, are equally
free to approach a policy decision in their own way, the
anticompetitive restraints adopted as policy by any one of them,
may express its own preference, rather than that of the State.
[
Footnote 43] Therefore, in
the absence of evidence that the State authorized or directed a
given municipality to act as it did, the actions of a particular
city hardly can be found to be pursuant to "the state['s] command,"
or to be restraints that "the state . . . as sovereign" imposed.
317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 352.
The most [
Footnote 44] that
could be said is that state policy may be neutral.
Page 435 U. S. 415
To permit municipalities to be shielded from the antitrust laws
in such circumstances would impair the goals Congress sought to
achieve by those laws,
see supra at
435 U. S.
403-408, without furthering the policy underlying the
Parker "exemption." This does not mean, however, that a
political subdivision necessarily must be able to point to a
specific, detailed legislative authorization before it properly may
assert a
Parker defense to an antitrust suit. While a
subordinate governmental unit's claim to
Parker immunity
is not as readily established as the same claim by a state
government, sued as such, we agree with the Court of Appeals that
an adequate state mandate for anticompetitive activities of cities
and other subordinate governmental units exits when it is
found,
"from the authority given a governmental entity to operate in a
particular area, that the legislature contemplated the kind of
action complained of. [
Footnote
45]"
532 F.2d at 434.
The
Parker doctrine, so understood, preserves to the
States their freedom under our dual system of federalism to use
their municipalities to administer state regulatory policies free
of the inhibitions of the federal antitrust laws without at the
Page 435 U. S. 416
same time permitting purely parochial interests to disrupt the
Nation's free market goals.
Our Brother STEWART's dissent argues that the result we reach
will "greatly . . . impair the ability of a State to delegate
governmental power broadly to its municipalities."
Post at
435 U. S. 438
(footnote omitted). That, with respect, is simply hyperbole. Our
decision will render a State no less able to allocate governmental
power between itself and its political subdivisions. It means only
that, when the State itself has not directed or authorized an
anticompetitive practice, the State's subdivisions in exercising
their delegated power must obey the antitrust laws. The dissent
notwithstanding, it is far too late to argue that a State's desire
to insulate anticompetitive practices not imposed by it as an act
of government falls within the
Parker doctrine.
Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U.
S. 384 (1951). Moreover, by characterizing the
Parker exemption as fully applicable to local governmental
units simply by virtue of their status as such, the approach taken
by the dissent would hold anticompetitive municipal action free
from federal antitrust enforcement even when state statutes
specifically provide that municipalities shall be subject to the
antitrust laws of the United States.
See generally
La.Rev.Stat.Ann. § 33:1334(G) (West Supp. 1977), quoted in
n 44,
supra. That
result would be a perversion of federalism. [
Footnote 46]
Today's decision does not threaten the legitimate exercise of
governmental power, nor does it preclude municipal government
Page 435 U. S. 417
from providing services on a monopoly basis.
Parker and
its progeny make clear that a State properly may, as States did in
Parker and
Bates, direct or authorize its
instrumentalities to act in a way which, if it did not reflect
state policy, would be inconsistent with the antitrust laws.
Compare Bates with Goldfarb. True, even a lawful
monopolist may be subject to antitrust restraints when it seeks to
extend or exploit its monopoly in a manner not contemplated by its
authorization.
Cf. Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States,
410 U. S. 366,
410 U. S.
377-382 (1973). [
Footnote 47] But assuming that the municipality is
authorized to provide a service on a monopoly basis, these
limitations on municipal action [
Footnote 48] will not hobble the execution of legitimate
governmental programs.
Affirmed.
[
Footnote 1]
See La.Const., Art. 6, §§ 2, 7(A) (effective
Jan. 1, 1975); La.Const., Art. XIV, § 40(d) (1921) (effective
prior to Jan. 1, 1975);
see generally La.Rev.Stat.Ann.
§§ 33:621, 33:361, 33:506 (West 1951).
[
Footnote 2]
La.Rev.Stat.Ann. § 33:1326 (West 1951); §§
33:4162, 33:4163 (West 1966).
[
Footnote 3]
The complaint named as parties defendant Middle-South Utilities,
Inc., a Florida corporation of which LP&L is a subsidiary,
Central Louisiana Electric Co., Inc., and Gulf States Utilities,
Louisiana and Texas corporations respectively, engaged in the
generation, transmission, and sale of electric power at wholesale
and retail in Louisiana.
[
Footnote 4]
LP&L does not allege that it directly competes with the city
of Lafayette, but does allege that the city of Plaquemine imposed
tying arrangements which injured it.
See Respondent's
Second Amended Counterclaim, App. 33-34; Affidavit of J. M. Wyatt,
Senior Vice President of LP&L,
id. at 37.
[
Footnote 5]
Petitioners' complaint charged that the defendants conspired to
restrain trade and attempted to monopolize and have monopolized the
generation, transmission, and distribution of electric power by
preventing the construction and operation of competing utility
systems, by improperly refusing to wheel power, by foreclosing
supplies from markets served by defendants, by engaging in boycotts
against petitioners, and by utilizing sham litigation and other
improper means to prevent the financing of construction of electric
generation facilities beneficial to petitioners.
[
Footnote 6]
The counterclaim, as amended, alleged that the petitioners,
together with a nonparty electric cooperatives, had conspired to
engage in sham litigation against LP&L to prevent the financing
with the purpose and effect of delaying or preventing the
construction of a nuclear electric generating plant, to eliminate
competition within the municipal boundaries by use of covenants in
their respective debentures, to exclude competition in certain
markets by using long-term supply agreements, and to displace
LP&L in certain areas by requiring customers of LP&L to
purchase electricity from petitioners as a condition of continued
water and gas service.
[
Footnote 7]
Saenz was a treble damages action by a slide-rule
manufacturer who alleged a conspiracy between a state agency, the
University Interscholastic League (UIL), its director, and a
private competitor of Saenz to effect the rejection of Saenz
products for use in interscholastic competition among Texas public
schools. In
Saenz, the Court of Appeals affirmed the
District Court's dismissal of the action against the UIL and its
director on the ground that, as a state agency and a state
official, they were not answerable under the Sherman Act.
[
Footnote 8]
The word "exemption" is commonly used by courts as a shorthand
expression for
Parker's holding that the Sherman Act was
not intended by Congress to prohibit the anticompetitive restraints
imposed by California in that case.
[
Footnote 9]
In entering its order dismissing the counterclaim, the District
Court made an express determination that there was no just reason
for delay, and expressly directed the entry of judgment for
plaintiffs pursuant to Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 54(b). This action
designated the dismissal as a final appealable order.
See
Liberty Mutual Ins. Co. v. Wetzel, 424 U.
S. 737,
424 U. S.
742-743 (1976).
[
Footnote 10]
The word "person" or "persons" is used repeatedly in the
antitrust statutes. For examples,
see 15 U.S.C. § 1
(1976 ed.) ("Every person who shall make any contract or engage in
any combination or conspiracy hereby declared to be illegal shall
be deemed guilty of a felony. . . ."); 15 U.S.C. § 2 (1976
ed.) ("Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize,
or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to
monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several
States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a
felony. . . ."); 15 U.S.C. § 3 (1976 ed.) ("Every person
[making a contract or engaging in a combination or conspiracy in
restraint of trade in any Territory or the District of Columbia]
shall be deemed guilty of a felony. . . ."); 15 U.S.C. § 7
(1976 ed.) (defining the word "person" or "persons"); 15 U.S.C.
§ 8 (1976 ed.) (declaring illegal every contract, combination,
or conspiracy in restraint of trade by persons or corporations
engaged in importing articles into the United States, and providing
that any person so engaged shall be guilty of a misdemeanor).
[
Footnote 11]
Section 8 of the Sherman Act provides in full:
"That the word 'person,' or 'persons,' wherever used in this act
shall be deemed to include corporations and associations existing
under or authorized by the laws of either the United States, the
laws of any of the Territories, the laws of any State, or the laws
of any foreign country."
Section 8 has remained unchanged since its enactment in
1890.
Section 1 of the Clayton Act defines the word "person" or
"persons" in language identical to that of § 8 of the Sherman
Act, and it also has remained unchanged since its enactment in
1914.
[
Footnote 12]
Section 4 is quoted in full in
n 13,
infra.
[
Footnote 13]
Section 7 of the Sherman Act, ch. 647, 26 Stat. 210 (1890)
(repealed in 1955), provided in full:
"Any person who shall be injured in his business or property by
any other person or corporation by reason of anything forbidden or
declared to be unlawful by this act, may sue therefor in any
circuit court of the United States in the district in which the
defendant resides or is found, without respect to the amount in
controversy, and shall recover threefold the damages by him
sustained, and the costs of suit, including a reasonable attorney's
fee."
Section 4 of the Clayton Act provides in full:
"Any person who shall be injured in his business or property by
reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue therefor
in any district court of the United States in the district in which
the defendant resides or is found or has an agent, without respect
to the amount in controversy, and shall recover threefold the
damages by him sustained, and the cost of suit, including a
reasonable attorney's fee."
Section 4 has remained unchanged since its enactment in 1914. It
is made applicable to all of the antitrust statutes by § 1 of
the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C.§ 12 (1976 ed.).
[
Footnote 14]
When Congress wished to exempt municipal service operations from
the coverage of the antitrust laws, it has done so without
ambiguity. The Act of ay 26, 1938, ch. 283, 52 Stat. 446, 15 U.S.C.
§ 13c (1976 ed.), grants a limited exemption to certain
not-for-profit institutions for "purchases of their supplies for
their own use" from the provisions of the Clayton Act as amended by
the Robinson-Patman Act, 49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. §§ 13
to 13b and 21a (1976 ed.), which otherwise make it unlawful for a
supplier to grant, or for an institution to induce, a
discriminatory discount with respect to such supplies. Congress
expressly included public libraries in this exemption. (Public
libraries are, by definition, operated by local government.
See 1 U.S. Office of Education, Biennial Surveys of
Education in the United States, ch. 8 (Library Service 1938-1940),
p. 27 (1947); 2 U.S. Office of Education, ch. 2 (Statistical
Summary of Education, 1941-1942), p. 38; 32 Am.Library Assn.Bull.
272 (1938)).
[
Footnote 15]
See Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v. American Crystal Sugar
Co., 334 U. S. 219,
334 U. S.
229-235 (1948).
[
Footnote 16]
"Antitrust laws in general, and the Sherman Act in particular,
are the Magna Carta of free enterprise. They are as important to
the preservation of economic freedom and our free-enterprise system
as the Bill of Rights is to the protection of our fundamental
personal freedoms. And the freedom guaranteed each and every
business, no matter how small, is the freedom to compete -- to
assert with vigor, imagination, devotion, and ingenuity whatever
economic muscle it can muster."
United States v. Topco Associates, 405 U.
S. 596,
405 U. S. 610
(1972).
[
Footnote 17]
See also Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.
S. 657,
381 U.S.
669-672 (1965).
Pennington held that, regardless of
the anticompetitive purpose or effect on small competing mining
companies, the joint action of certain large mining companies and
labor unions in lobbying before the Secretary of Labor in favor of
legislation establishing a minimum wage for employees of
contractors selling coal to the Tennessee Valley Authority and in
lobbying before TVA to avoid coal purchases exempted from the
legislation was not subject to antitrust attack. Cases subsequent
to
Pennington have emphasized the possible constitutional
infirmity in the antitrust laws that a contrary construction would
entail in light of the serious threat to First Amendment freedoms
that would have been presented.
See Continental Ore Co. v.
Union Carbide & Carbon Corp., 370 U.
S. 690,
370 U. S.
707-708 (1962);
California Motor Transport Co. v.
Trucking Unlimited, 404 U. S. 508,
404 U. S. 516
(1972) (STEWART, J., concurring in judgment).
[
Footnote 18]
See also Olsen v. Smith, 195 U.
S. 332,
195 U. S.
344-345 (1904).
[
Footnote 19]
Union Pacific considered the applicability to a city of
§ 1 of the Elkins Act, 32 Stat. 847, as amended, 34 Stat. 587,
49 U.S.C. § 41(1). That statute, in definitional language
similar to that used in § 8 of the Sherman Act, makes it
unlawful for
"
any person, persons, or corporation to offer, grant,
or give, or to solicit, accept, or receive any rebate, concession,
or discrimination in respect to the transportation of any property
in interstate or foreign commerce by any [covered] common carrier.
. . ."
(Emphasis added.) Kansas City, Kan. (hereinafter Kansas),
decided to develop its Public Levee as a metropolitan rail food
terminal with wholesale and retail produce markets. Kansas
constructed, operated, and owned the market, financing the
development with municipal revenue bonds.
Another city, Kansas City, Mo. (hereinafter Missouri), also
operated a rail food terminal within the same metropolitan area.
Because Kansas believed that there was insufficient business in the
metropolitan area to support both markets, it developed a plan to
induce Missouri produce dealers to lease its facilities by offering
cash payments and temporary reduction or abatement of rent. These
payments exceeded the amounts needed to compensate the merchants
for the costs of moving, settlement of existing leases, and
disruption to business. Kansas adopted the payment plan by
resolution, and its legality under Kansas law was sustained by the
Kansas Supreme Court in a
quo warranto proceeding.
State ex rel. Parker v. Kansas City, 151 Kan. 1, 97 P.2d
104, 98 P.2d 101 (1939).
The Missouri terminal was served by a number of railroads, but
the Kansas terminal was served virtually exclusively by the Union
Pacific Railroad. As merchants moved from Missouri to Kansas, the
Union Pacific's traffic necessarily increased, while that of the
other railroads shrank. The United States charged that the effect
of Kansas' concessions to merchants was to permit them to ship
produce over the Union Pacific more cheaply than on the competing
railroads serving the Missouri terminal and, in effect, amounted to
a rebate from Union Pacific's tariffs. The District Court
permanently enjoined Kansas from giving cash or rental credits to
Missouri dealers to move or for moving to Kansas.
On appeal to this Court, Kansas argued that, because the
concessions were lawful under state law, it could not be enjoined
from making them, and the United States argued that the
municipality was a "person" within the meaning of the statute, and
therefore subject to the Act on the same terms as a private
corporation.
See Brief for Appellants, O.T. 1940, No. 594,
pp. 233-235, 244-256; Brief for United States, O.T. 1940, No. 594,
p. 72.
See generally id. at 59-68, 69-75.
The Court held that the municipality was a "person" subject to
the Act, and, with a modification not important here, upheld the
permanent injunction against it. Mr. Justice Roberts, in dissent,
made the argument made by the cities here, that the statutory
phrase "every person" was not sufficiently specific to justify the
conclusion that Congress wished to subject municipal corporations
and their officers to the criminal penalties for which the Act
provided. It is significant that the cities' argument was rejected
in the context of the anti-rebate provisions of the Elkins Act, a
statute which essentially is an antitrust provision serving the
same purposes as the anti-price discrimination provisions of the
Robinson-Patman Act.
Accord, Slater, Antitrust and
Government Action: A Formula For Narrowing
Parker v.
Brown, 69 Nw.U.L.Rev. 71, 89 n. 100 (1974).
[
Footnote 20]
Ohio v. Helvering sustained a federal tax liability
imposed upon the State of Ohio in its business as a distributor of
alcoholic beverages. The statute, Rev.Stat. § 3244 (1878),
imposed a tax upon "[e]very person who sells or offers for sale
[alcoholic beverages]." The applicable definitional section,
Rev.Stat. § 3140 (1878), provided:
"[W]here not otherwise distinctly expressed or manifestly
incompatible with the intent thereof, the word 'person,' as used in
this title, shall be construed to mean and include a partnership,
association, company, or corporation, as well as a natural
person."
Helvering stated that
"[w]hether the word 'person' or 'corporation' includes a state
or the United States depends upon the connection in which the word
is found,"
292 U.S. at
292 U. S. 370,
and held that
"the state itself, when it becomes a dealer in intoxicating
liquors, falls within the reach of the tax either as a 'person'
under the statutory extension of that word to include a
corporation, or as a 'person' without regard to such
extension."
Id. at
292 U. S. 371.
[
Footnote 21]
California held that a city and State are subject to
§§ 16 and 17 of the Shipping Act, 1916, 39 Stat. 734, as
amended, 46 U.S.C. §§ 815, 816, making unlawful certain
practices of "person[s]," defined by § 1, 46 U.S.C. §
801, as including "corporations, partnerships, and associations,
existing under or authorized by the laws of the United States, or
any State. . . ."
[
Footnote 22]
The question of remedy can arise only if the District Court, on
the Court of Appeals remand, determines that petitioners'
activities are prohibited by the antitrust laws.
[
Footnote 23]
Cf. Hospital Building Co. v. Rex Hospital Trustees,
425 U. S. 738,
425 U. S. 740
(1976). We use the allegations of the counterclaim only as a ready
and convenient example of the kinds of activities in which a
municipality may engage in the operation of its utility business
which would have an anticompetitive effect transcending its
municipal borders.
[
Footnote 24]
See generally Duke & Co. v. Foerster, 521 F.2d 1277
(CA3 1975);
New Mexico v. American Petrofina, Inc., 501
F.2d 363 (CA9 1974);
Hecht v. Pro-Football, Inc., 144
U.S.App.D.C. 56, 444 F.2d 931 (1971).
[
Footnote 25]
See Respondent's Second Amended Counterclaim, App.
33.
[
Footnote 26]
As one commentator has noted, our cases indicate that the
protection against injury to the buyer is only one purpose of the
rule against tying arrangements. Equally important is the need to
protect competing sellers from competition unrelated to the merits
of the product involved, and, concomitantly, to protect the market
from distortion. Turner, The Validity of Tying Arrangements Under
the Antitrust Laws, 72 Harv.L.Rev. 50, 60 (1958).
[
Footnote 27]
While the investor-owned utilities in Louisiana are subject to
regulation by the Louisiana Public Utilities Commission,
municipally owned utilities are not subject to the jurisdiction of
the PUC, and hence apparently need not conform their expansion
policies to whatever plans the PUC might deem advisable for
coordinating service.
See n 44,
infra.
[
Footnote 28]
See Respondent's Answer & Counterclaim, App.
18-20.
[
Footnote 29]
The counterclaim alleged that petitioners engaged in sham
litigation before the Securities and Exchange Commission, the
Federal Power Commission, the Atomic Energy Commission, and the
United States Department of Justice.
[
Footnote 30]
See generally California Motor Transport Co. v. Trucking
Unlimited, 404 U. S. 508
(1972).
[
Footnote 31]
Petitioners have urged that the anti-monopoly principles of the
antitrust laws are inconsistent with the very nature of government
operating as a monopoly in the public interest. They suggest that
to apply antitrust principles to local governments will necessarily
interfere with the execution of governmental programs. We do not
agree. Acting as agents at the direction of the State, local
governments are free to implement state policies without being
subject to the antitrust laws to the same extent as would the State
itself.
See infra at
435 U. S.
413-417. On the other hand, it would not hinder
governmental programs to require that cities authorized to provide
services on a monopoly basis refrain from, for example, predatory
conduct not itself directed by the State.
[
Footnote 32]
"The prohibitions of the Sherman Act were not stated in terms of
precision or of crystal clarity, and the Act itself did not define
them. In consequence of the vagueness of its language, perhaps not
uncalculated,[*] the courts have been left to give content to the
statute, and, in the performance of that function, it is
appropriate that courts should interpret its word in the light of
its legislative history and of the particular evils at which the
legislation was aimed. . . ."
"[*]
See Debates, 21 Cong.Rec. 2460, 3148; 2 Hoar,
Autobiography of Seventy Years 364; Senator Edmunds,
The
Interstate Trust and Commerce Act of 1890, 194 No.Am.Rev. 801,
813,"
"after most careful and earnest consideration by the Judiciary
Committee of the Senate, it was agreed by every member that it was
quite impracticable to include by specific description all the acts
which should come within the meaning and purpose of the words
'trade' and 'commerce' or 'trust,' or the words 'restraint' or
'monopolize,' by precise and all-inclusive definitions; and that
these were truly matters for judicial consideration."
"
See also Senator Hoar, who, with Senator Edmunds
probably drafted the bill (
see A. H. Walker, History of
the Sherman Law (1910), p. 2728) in 36 Cong.Rec. 522, Jan. 6,
1903:"
"We undertook by law to clothe the courts with the power and
impose on them and the Department of Justice the duty of preventing
all combinations in restraint of trade. . . ."
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.
S. 469,
310 U. S. 489,
and n. 10 (1940).
[
Footnote 33]
The political redress argument could also be made in the context
of anticompetitive actions engaged in by the State itself. Our
rejection of the argument here is not, however, inconsistent with
the
Parker doctrine.
Parker did not reason that
political redress is an adequate substitute for direct enforcement
of the antitrust laws. Rather,
Parker held that, in the
absence of congressional intent to the contrary, a purpose that the
antitrust laws be used to strike down the State's regulatory
program imposed as an act of government would not be inferred. To
the extent that the actions of a State's subdivisions are the
actions of the State, the
Parker exemption applies.
See infra at
435 U. S.
413-417.
[
Footnote 34]
1 U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1972 Census of Governments,
Governmental Organization 1 (1973). This figure (62,437) represents
the total of county, municipal, township, and special district
governments, but does not include the 15,781 independent school
districts in the United States, which, of course, have a much more
narrowly defined range of functions and powers than those of local
governmental units generally.
See id. at 1-5.
[
Footnote 35]
See id. at 4-5
[
Footnote 36]
See id. at 1-3.
[
Footnote 37]
See, e.g., Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, supra at
310 U. S.
493-495, n. 15 (reviewing legislative history).
[
Footnote 38]
See United States v. Topco Associates, 405 U.S. at
405 U. S. 610;
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, supra at
310 U. S.
492-495, and n. 15;
Mandeville Island Farms, Inc. v.
American Crystal Sugar Co., 334 U. S. 219,
334 U. S.
229-235 (1948).
[
Footnote 39]
The state regulatory program involved in
Parker
furthered an important state interest which was consistent with
federal policy.
See Parker, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
352-359.
[
Footnote 40]
The plurality opinion in
Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co.,
428 U. S. 579
(1976), also analyzed a "state action" exemption claim in terms of
whether the challenged anticompetitive action was taken pursuant to
state command. Detroit Edison, an electric utility regulated by
Michigan, was charged by an independent seller of light bulbs with
antitrust violations in the operation of a program which provided
light bulbs without extra cost to electricity customers. Detroit
Edison, relying on
Parker, defended on the ground that the
light bulb program was included in its rate filed with and approved
by the State Public Service Commission, and that state law required
it to follow the terms of the tariff as long as it was in effect.
Cantor rejected the claim, holding that, since no Michigan
statutes regulated the light bulb industry, and since neither the
Michigan Legislature nor the Public Service Commission had passed
upon the desirability of such a light bulb program, the
Commission's approval of Detroit Edison's program did not
"implement any statewide policy relating to light bulbs" and that
"the State's policy is neutral on the question whether a utility
should, or should not, have such a program." 428 U.S. at
428 U. S. 585.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE, while not joining all of the plurality opinion,
agreed with this analysis.
Id. at
428 U. S.
604-605.
Cantor's analysis is not, however, necessarily
applicable here.
Cantor was concerned with whether
anticompetitive activity in which purely private parties engaged
could, under the circumstances of that case, be insulated from
antitrust enforcement. The situation involved here, on the other
hand, presents the issue of under what circumstances a State's
subdivisions engaging in anticompetitive activities should be
deemed to be acting as agents of the State.
[
Footnote 41]
Petitioners argue that
Goldfarb, like
Cantor v.
Detroit Edison Co., supra, expresses a limitation upon the
circumstances under which private parties may be immunized from
suit under the antitrust laws. They seek to avoid our holding in
Goldfarb by suggesting that the State Bar, although a
state agency by law acting in its official capacity, was somehow
not a state agency because its official actions in issuing ethical
opinions,
see 421 U.S. at 791 n. 21, benefited its member
lawyers by discouraging price competition. We think it obvious that
the fact that the ancillary effect of the State Bar's policy, or
even the conscious desire on its part, may have been to benefit the
lawyers it regulated cannot transmute the State Bar's official
actions into those of a private organization. In addition to the
decision in this case, every other Court of Appeals which has
considered the immunity of state instrumentalities after
Goldfarb has regarded it as having held that
anticompetitive actions of a state instrumentality not compelled by
the State acting as sovereign are not immune from the antitrust
laws.
Fairfax v. Fairfax Hospital Assn., 562 F.2d 280,
284-285 (CA4 1977);
id. at 288 (concurring opinion);
Kurek v. Pleasure Driveway & Park Dist., 557 F.2d 580,
588-591 (CA7 1977),
cert. pending, No. 77-440;
Duke
& Co. v. Foerster, 521 F.2d at 1280.
The acknowledgment of our Brother STEWART's dissent,
post at
435 U. S. 433,
that, as noted in
Indian Towing Co. v. United States,
350 U. S. 61,
350 U. S. 67-68
(1955),
"'Government is not partly public or partly private, depending
upon the governmental pedigree of the type of a particular activity
or the manner in which the Government conducts it,'"
(citation omitted), discloses the fallacy of his effort to
distinguish
Goldfarb on the ground that, although the
State Bar was
"'a state agency for some limited purposes,' . . . the
price-fixing it fostered was for the private benefit of its
members, and its actions were essentially those of a private
professional group."
Post at
435 U. S.
431.
[
Footnote 42]
Without explication, our Brother STEWART's dissent states that
our "reliance . . . on the basically irrelevant body of law under
the Eleventh Amendment" is unfounded.
Ibid. Rather, it is
the statement that is unfounded. For the longstanding principle, of
which Congress in 1890 was well aware,
see Lincoln County v.
Luning, 133 U. S. 529
(1890), is that political subdivisions are not, as such, sovereign.
Certainly, nothing in
National League of Cities v. Usery,
426 U. S. 833
(1976), even remotely suggested the contrary; we search in vain for
anything in that case that establishes a constructional principle
of presumptive congressional deference in behalf of cities. Indeed
our emphasis today in our conclusion, that municipalities are
"exempt" from antitrust enforcement when acting as state agencies
implementing state policy to the same extent as the State itself,
makes it difficult to see how
National League of Cities is
even tangentially implicated.
[
Footnote 43]
"While state legislatures exercise extensive power over their
constituents and over the various units of local government, the
States universally leave much policy and decisionmaking to their
governmental subdivisions. Legislators enact many laws, but do not
attempt to reach those countless matters of local concern
necessarily left wholly or partly to those who govern at the local
level."
Avery v. Midland County, 390 U.
S. 474,
390 U. S. 481
(1968).
Although
Avery concluded that the actions of local
government are the actions of the State for purposes of the
Fourteenth Amendment, state action required under
Parker
has different attributes.
Cf. Edelman v. Jordan,
415 U. S. 651,
415 U. S. 667
n. 12 (1974).
[
Footnote 44]
Indeed, state policy may be contrary to that adopted by a
political subdivision, yet, for a variety of reasons, might not
render the local policy unlawful under state law. For example, a
state public utilities commission might adopt, though we are not
aware that the Louisiana PUC has done so, a policy prohibiting the
specific anticompetitive practices in which the municipality
engages, yet be unable to enforce that policy with respect to
municipalities because it lacks jurisdiction over them. (The
Louisiana PUC, in litigation unrelated to this case, has been held
to lack jurisdiction over municipal utility systems, whether
operating within or without the municipality.
City of Monroe v.
Louisiana Public Serv. Comm'n, No. 177,757 -- Div. "I" (19th
Jud. Dist. Ct., Sept. 14, 1976).) If that were the case, and
assuming that there were no other evidence to the contrary, it
would be difficult to say that state policy fosters, much less
compels, the anticompetitive practices.
Louisiana Rev.Stat.Ann. § 33:1334(G) (West Supp. 1977)
provides another illustration of the fact that a particular
activity in which a subdivision technically has power to engage
does not necessarily conform to, and may conflict with, state
policy. Louisiana has authorized municipalities to create
intergovernmental commissions as municipal instrumentalities
jointly to construct and operate public services including
utilities. §§ 33:1324. 33:1331-33:1334 (West Supp. 1977).
Such commissions are, by definition, political subdivisions of the
State. § 33:1334(D) (West Supp. 1977). Section 1334(G)
nevertheless provides that
"[n]othing in this Chapter shall be construed to grant an
immunity to or on behalf of any [such] public instrumentality . . .
from any antitrust laws of the state or of the United States."
[
Footnote 45]
We reject petitioners' fallback position that an antitrust claim
will not lie for anticompetitive municipal action which, though not
state directed, is lawful under state law.
See Schwegmann Bros.
v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U. S. 384
(151);
Northern Securities Co. v. United States,
193 U. S. 197,
193 U. S.
344-351 (1904);
cf. Union Pacific R. Co. v. United
States, 313 U. S. 450
(1941) (discussed in n.
19
supra).
See also n 44,
supra.
[
Footnote 46]
Restating a theme made and rejected before,
see Cantor v.
Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.S. at
428 U. S. 640
(STEWART, J., dissenting), our Brother STEWART's dissent,
post at
435 U. S.
438-440, likens judicial enforcement of the antitrust
laws to a regime of substantive due process used by federal judges
to strike down state and municipal economic regulation thought by
them unfair. That analogy, of course, ignores the congressional
judgment mandating broad scope in enforcement of the antitrust
laws, and simply reflects the dissent's view that such enforcement
with respect to cities is unwise.
[
Footnote 47]
While the majority and dissent disagreed in
Otter Tail
over whether the specific practices of which plaintiffs complained
could be regarded as unlawful anticompetitive restraints in light
of the existence of federal regulation, there was agreement that a
lawful monopolist could violate the antitrust laws.
Compare 410 U.S. at
410 U. S.
377-382
with id. at
410 U. S.
390-391, n. 7 (STEWART, J., concurring in part and
dissenting in part).
[
Footnote 48]
It may be that certain activities which might appear
anticompetitive when engaged in by private parties take on a
different complexion when adopted by a local government.
See
generally Posner, The Proper Relationship Between State
Regulation and the Federal Antitrust Laws, 49 N.Y.U.L.Rev. 693, 705
(1974).
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL, concurring.
I agree with THE CHIEF JUSTICE,
post at
435 U. S.
425-426, that any implied "state action" exemption from
the antitrust laws should be no broader than is necessary to serve
the State's legitimate purposes. I join the plurality opinion,
however, because the test there established, relating to whether it
is "state policy to displace competition,"
ante at
435 U. S. 413,
incorporates within it the core of THE CHIEF JUSTICE's concern. As
the plurality opinion makes clear, it is not enough that the
State
Page 435 U. S. 418
"desire[s] to insulate anticompetitive practices."
Ante
at
435 U. S. 416.
For there to be an antitrust exemption, the State must "impose" the
practices "as an act of government."
Ibid. State action
involving more anticompetitive restraint than necessary to
effectuate governmental purposes must be viewed as inconsistent
with the plurality's approach.
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE BURGER, concurring in the Court's opinion in
Part I and in the judgment.
This case turns, or ought to, on the District Court's explicit
conclusion, [
Footnote 2/1]
unchallenged here, that "[t]hese plaintiff cities are engaging in
what is clearly a business activity; activity in which a profit is
realized." There is nothing in
Parker v. Brown,
317 U. S. 341
(1943), or its progeny which suggests that a proprietary enterprise
with the inherent capacity for economically disruptive
anticompetitive effects should be exempt from the Sherman Act
merely because it is organized under state law as a municipality.
Parker was a case involving a suit against state officials
who were administering a state program which had the conceded
purpose of replacing competition in a segment of the agricultural
market with a regime of governmental regulation. The instant
lawsuit is entirely different. It arises because respondent took
the perfectly natural step of answering a federal antitrust
complaint --
Page 435 U. S. 419
filed by competitors -- with a counterclaim alleging serious
violations of the Sherman Act.
There is nothing in this record to support any assumption other
than that this is an ordinary dispute among competitors in the same
market. It is true that petitioners are municipalities, but we
should not ignore the reality that this is the only difference
between the Cities and any other entrepreneur in the economic
community. Indeed, the injuries alleged in petitioners' complaint
read as a litany of economic woes suffered by a business which has
been unfairly treated by a competitor:
"As a direct and proximate result of the unlawful conduct
hereinabove alleged, plaintiffs have: (1) been prevented from and
continue to be prevented from
profitably expanding their
businesses; (2)
lost and continue to lose the profits
which would have resulted from the operation of an expanded,
more efficient and lower cost business; (3) been deprived
of and continue to be deprived of economies in the financing and
operation of their systems; (4)
sustained and continue to
sustain losses in the value of their businesses and
properties; and (5) incurred and continue to incur excessive
costs and expenses they otherwise would not have incurred."
App. 14. (Emphasis added.)
It strikes me as somewhat remarkable to suggest that the same
Congress which "meant to deal comprehensively and effectively with
the evils resulting from contracts, combinations and conspiracies
in restraint of trade,"
Atlantic Cleaner & Dyers, Inc. v.
United States, 286 U. S. 427,
286 U. S. 435
(1932), would have allowed these petitioners to complain of such
economic damage while baldly asserting that any similar harms they
might unleash upon competitors or the economy are absolutely beyond
the purview of federal law. To allow the defense asserted by the
petitioners in this case would inject a wholly arbitrary variable
into a "fundamental national economic policy,"
Page 435 U. S. 420
Carnation Co. v. Pacific Conference, 383 U.
S. 213,
383 U. S. 218
(1966), which strongly disfavors immunity from its scope.
See
United States v. Philadelphia Nat. Bank, 374 U.
S. 321,
374 U. S.
350-351 (1963);
California v. FPC, 369 U.
S. 482,
369 U. S. 485
(1962).
As I indicated, concurring in
Cantor v. Detroit Edison
Co., 428 U. S. 579,
428 U. S. 604
(1976),
"in interpreting
Parker, the Court has heretofore
focused on the challenged activity, not upon the identity of the
parties to the suit."
Such an approach is surely logical in light of the fact that the
Congress which passed the Sherman Act very likely never considered
the kinds of problems generated by
Parker and the cases
which have arisen in its wake.
E.g., Bates v. State Bar of
Arizona, 433 U. S. 350
(1977);
Cantor, supra; Goldfarb v. Virginia State Bar,
421 U. S. 773
(1975);
see Slater, Antitrust and Government Action: A
Formula for Narrowing
Parker v. Brown, 69 Nw.U.L.Rev. 71,
84 (1974). It is even more dubious to assume that the Congress
specifically focused its attention on the possible liability of a
utility operated by a subdivision of a State. Not only were the
States generally considered free to regulate commerce within their
own borders,
see, e.g., United States v. E. C. Knight Co.,
156 U. S. 1 (1895);
Kidd v. Pearson, 128 U. S. 1 (1888),
but manufacturing enterprises, in and of themselves, were not taken
to be interstate commerce.
Id. at
128 U. S. 20.
By the time
Parker was decided, however, this narrow
view of "interstate commerce" had broadened via the "affection
doctrine" to include intrastate events which had a sufficient
effect on interstate commerce.
See NLRB v. Fainblatt,
306 U. S. 601,
306 U.S. 605, and n. 1
(1939);
cf. Hospital Building Co. v. Rex Hospital
Trustees, 425 U. S. 738,
425 U. S. 743
(1976). Given this development, and the Court's interpretation of
"person" or "persons" in the Sherman Act to include States and
municipalities,
ante at
435 U. S.
394-397, along with the trend of allowing the reach of
the Sherman Act to expand with broadening conceptions of
congressional power under the Commerce Clause,
see
Page 435 U. S. 421
Rex Hospital Trustees, supra, at
425 U. S. 743
n. 2, one might reasonably wonder how the Court reached its result
in
Parker.
The holding in
Parker is perfectly understandable,
though, in light of the historical period in which the case was
decided. The Court had then but recently emerged from the era of
substantive due process, and was undoubtedly not eager to commence
a new round of invalidating state regulatory laws on federal
principles.
See Verkuil, State Action, Due Process and
Antitrust: Reflections on
Parker v. Brown, 75 Colum.L.Rev.
328, 331-334 (1975). Responding to this concern, the
Parker Court's interpretation of legislative intent
reflects a "polic[y] of signal importance in our national
traditions and governmental structure of federalism."
Ante
at
435 U. S.
400.
"In a dual system of government in which, under the
Constitution, the states are sovereign, save only as Congress may
constitutionally subtract from their authority, an unexpressed
purpose to nullify a state's control over its officers and agents
is not lightly to be attributed to Congress."
Parker, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351.
The
Parker decision was thus firmly grounded on principles
of federalism, the ambit of its inquiry into congressional purpose
being defined by the Court's view of the requirements of "a dual
system of government." [
Footnote
2/2]
This mode of analysis is as sound today as it was then, and I am
surprised that neither the plurality opinion nor the dissents focus
their attention on this aspect of
Parker. Indeed,
Page 435 U. S. 422
it is even more puzzling that much judicial energy is expended
here on deciding a question not presented by the parties or by the
facts of this case: that is, to what extent the Sherman Act
impinges generally upon the monopoly powers of state and local
governments. As I suggested at the outset, the issue here is
whether the Sherman Act reaches the proprietary enterprises of
municipalities. [
Footnote 2/3]
The answer to the question presented ought not to be so
difficult. When
Parker was decided, there was certainly no
question that a State's operation of a common carrier, even without
profit and as a "public function," would be subject to federal
regulation under the Commerce Clause.
United States v.
California, 297 U. S. 175,
297 U. S.
183-186 (1936) ("[W]e think it unimportant to say
whether the state conducts its railroad in its
sovereign' or in
its `private' capacity." Id. at 297 U. S.
183); see Parden v. Terminal R. Co.,
377 U. S. 184,
377 U. S.
189-193 (1964); California v. Taylor,
353 U. S. 553,
353 U. S. 568
(1957). Likewise, it had been held in Ohio v. Helvering,
292 U. S. 360
(1934), that a State, upon engaging in business, became subject to
a federal statute imposing a tax on those dealing in intoxicating
liquors, although States were not specifically mentioned in the
statute. In short, the Court had already recognized, for purposes
of federalism, the difference between a State's entrepreneurial
personality and a sovereign's decision -- as in Parker --
to replace competition with regulation. [Footnote 2/4]
Page 435 U. S. 423
I see nothing in the last 35 years to question this conclusion.
In fact, the Court's recent decision in
National League of
Cities v. Usery, 426 U. S. 833
(1976), which rekindled a commitment to tempering the Commerce
Clause power with the limits imposed by our structure of
government, employs language strikingly similar to the words of Mr.
Chief Justice Stone in
Parker:
"It is one thing to recognize the authority of Congress to enact
laws regulating individual businesses necessarily subject to the
dual sovereignty of the government of the Nation and of the State
in which they reside. It is quite another to uphold a similar
exercise of congressional authority directed not to private
citizens, but to States as States. We have repeatedly recognized
that there are attributes of sovereignty attaching to every state
government which may not be impaired by Congress, not because
Congress may lack an affirmative grant of legislative authority to
reach the matter, but because the Constitution prohibits it from
exercising the authority in that manner."
426 U.S. at
426 U. S. 845.
The
National League of Cities opinion focused its
delineation of the "attributes of sovereignty" alluded to above on
a determination as to whether the State's interest involved
"
functions essential to separate and independent existence.'"
Ibid.,
Page 435 U. S. 424
quoting
Coyle v. Oklahoma, 221 U.
S. 559,
221 U. S. 58
(1911). It should be evident, I would think, that the running of a
business enterprise is not an integral operation in the area of
traditional government functions.
See Alfred Dunhill of London,
Inc. v. Cuba, 425 U. S. 682,
425 U. S.
695-69 (1976);
Bank of United States v.
Planters' Bank of Georgia, 9 Wheat. 904,
22 U. S. 907
(1824). Indeed, the reaffirmance of the holding in
United
States v. California, supra, by
National League of Cities,
supra at
426 U. S. 854
n. 18, strongly supports this understanding. Even if this
proposition were not generally true, the particular undertaking at
issue here -- the supplying of electric service -- has not
traditionally been the prerogative of the State.
Jackson v.
Metropolitan Edison Co., 419 U. S. 345,
419 U. S.
352-353 (1974). [
Footnote
2/5]
Following the path outlined above should lead us to a logical
destination: Petitioners should be treated, for purposes of
applying the federal antitrust laws, in essentially the same manner
as respondent. This is not to say, of course, that the conduct in
which petitioners allegedly engaged is automatically subject to
condemnation under the Sherman Act. As the Court recognized in
Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.S. at
428 U. S.
592-598, state-regulated utilities pose special
analytical problems under
Parker. It may very well be, for
example, that a State, acting as sovereign, has imposed a system of
governmental control in order "to avoid the consequences of
unrestrained
Page 435 U. S. 425
competition."
Cantor, supra at
428 U. S. 595.
This is precisely what occurred in
Parker, and there is no
question that a utility's action taken pursuant to the command of
such an "act of government,"
Parker, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 352,
would not be prohibited by the Sherman Act.
I agree with the plurality, then, that
"[t]he
threshold inquiry in determining if an
anticompetitive activity is state action of the type the Sherman
Act was not meant to proscribe is whether the
activity is
required by the State acting as sovereign."
Goldfarb, 421 U.S. at
421 U. S. 790.
(Emphasis added.) But this is only the first, not the final, step
of the inquiry, for
Cantor recognized that "all economic
regulation does not necessarily suppress competition." 428 U.S. at
428 U. S.
595.
"There is no logical inconsistency between requiring such a firm
to meet regulatory criteria insofar as it is exercising its natural
monopoly powers and also to comply with antitrust standards to the
extent that it engages in business activity in competitive areas of
the economy."
Id. at
428 U. S.
596.
I would therefore remand, directing the District Court to take
an additional step beyond merely determining -- as the plurality
would -- that any area of conflict between the State's regulatory
policies and the federal antitrust laws was the result of a "state
policy to displace competition with regulation or monopoly public
service." [
Footnote 2/6]
Ante at
435 U. S. 413.
This supplemental
Page 435 U. S. 426
inquiry would consist of determining whether the implied
exemption from federal law "was necessary in order to make the
regulatory Act work,
and, even then, only to the minimum extent
necessary.'" 428 U.S. at 428 U. S. 597.
[Footnote 2/7]
[
Footnote 2/1]
The District Court did not, of course, make a formal finding of
fact to this effect, since the counterclaim was disposed of on the
basis of pleadings. Nonetheless, the District Court could
reasonably conclude, as a matter of law, that these Cities are
engaging in business activities which have as their aim the
production of revenues in excess of costs. It certainly is the case
that the Cities are attempting to provide a public service, but it
is likewise undeniable that they seek to do so in the most
profitable way. The Cities allege in their complaint, for example,
that they have "been prevented from profitably expanding their
businesses." App. 14. While it is correct that the Cities are
ordinarily constrained from applying their net earnings as a
private corporation would, this does not detract from their
competitive posture and resulting incentive to engage in
anticompetitive practices.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Our conceptions of the limits imposed by federalism are bound to
evolve, just as our understanding of Congress' power under the
Commerce Clause has evolved. Consequently, since we find it
appropriate to allow the ambit of the Sherman Act to expand with
evolving perceptions of congressional power under the Commerce
Clause, a similar process should occur with respect to "state
action" analysis under
Parker. That is, we should not
treat the
result in the
Parker case as case in
bronze; rather, the scope of the Sherman Act's power should
parallel the developing concepts of American federalism.
[
Footnote 2/3]
I use the term "proprietary" only to focus attention on the fact
that all of the parties are in a competitive relationship such that
each should be constrained, when necessary, by the federal
antitrust laws. It is highly unlikely that Congress would have
meant to impose liability only on some of these parties, when each
possesses the means to thwart federal antitrust policy.
[
Footnote 2/4]
MR. JUSTICE STEWART's dissent,
post at
435 U. S.
433-434, attempts to blunt this analysis by noting that
the "nongovernmental-governmental" distinction was criticized in
Indian Towing Co. v. United States, 350 U. S.
61 (1955). I suggest no more, however, than what is
obvious from our past cases: Petitioners' business activities are
not entitled to
per se exemption from the Sherman Act.
This much ought to be quite clear from
United States v.
California, 297 U. S. 175
(1936), where the State operated a railroad, albeit without profit,
and as a "public function." I cannot comprehend why the Cities here
should be treated in a different manner. The only authority which
MR. JUSTICE STEWART cites to the contrary,
Lowenstein v.
Evans, 69 F. 908 (CC SC 1895), was a case in which a State's
complete monopolization of the liquor industry was challenged as
violating the Sherman Act. But in that circumstance, the State
clearly directed the creation of a monopoly, thus bringing the
matter within the
Parker rationale.
Compare Ohio v.
Helvering, 292 U. S. 360
(1934).
[
Footnote 2/5]
Such an ascertainment dovetails precisely with the law of
Louisiana. There it is recognized that the powers of a municipal
corporation are both public and private: as to the former, the city
represents the State, discharging duties incumbent upon the State;
as to the latter, it represents pecuniary and proprietary interests
of individuals, and is held to the same responsibility as a private
person.
Hall v. Shreveport, 157 La. 589, 594, 102 So. 680,
681 (1925). A long line of Louisiana cases dealing explicitly with
the subject of municipally owned electrical utilities holds that
cities are to be governed by the same rules applicable to private
corporations and individuals.
See Hicks v. City of Monroe
Utilities Comm'n, 237 La. 848,
112 So. 2d
635 (1959);
Elias v. Mayor of New Iberia, 137 La. 691,
69 So. 141 (1915);
Hart v. Lake Providence, 5 La.App. 294
(1926);
Bannister v. City of Monroe, 4 La.App. 182
(1926).
[
Footnote 2/6]
While I agree with the plurality that a State may cause certain
activities to be exempt from the federal antitrust laws by virtue
of an articulated policy to displace competition with regulation, I
would require a strong showing on the part of the defendant that
the State so intended. Thus, I would not be satisfied, as the
plurality and Court of Appeals apparently are, that the highest
policymaking body in the State of Louisiana merely "contemplated"
the activities being undertaken by the cities.
See ante at
435 U. S. 415.
I would insist, as the Court did in
Goldfarb v. Virginia State
Bar, 421 U. S. 773,
421 U. S. 791
(1975), that the State
compel the anticompetitive
activity. Moreover, I would have the Cities demonstrate that the
exemption was not only part of a regulatory scheme to supersede
competition, but that it was
essential to the State's
plan. Consequently, I do not disagree with the terms of the
plurality's remand as such; I would simply ask for a stronger
showing on the part of the Cities. I join the judgment, however,
and the directions of the remand, because they represent, at a
minimum, what I believe we should demand of petitioners.
[
Footnote 2/7]
In
Cantor, this mode of analysis effectively answered
Detroit Edison's claim that it was required by state law to engage
in the allegedly anticompetitive activities. We "infer[red] that
the State's policy [was]
neutral on the question whether a
utility should, or should not, have such a program," 428 U.S. at
428 U. S. 585
(opinion of STEVENS, J.) (emphasis added),
428 U. S.
604-605 (opinion of BURGER, C.J.), and, consequently, it
could not be said that an exemption "was necessary in order to make
the regulatory Act work."
MR. JUSTICE STEWART, with whom MR. JUSTICE WHITE, MR. JUSTICE
BLACKMUN,
* and MR. JUSTICE
REHNQUIST join, dissenting.
In
Parker v. Brown, 317 U. S. 341, a
California statute restricted competition among raisin growers in
order to keep the price of raisins artificially high. The Court
found that California's program did not violate the antitrust laws,
but was "an act of government which the Sherman Act did not
undertake to prohibit."
Id. at
317 U. S. 352.
Parker v. Brown thus made clear that,
"where a restraint upon trade or monopolization is the result of
valid governmental action, as opposed to private action, no
violation of the [Sherman] Act can be made out."
Eastern Railroad Presidents Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight,
Inc., 365 U. S. 127,
365 U. S.
136.
The principle of
Parker v. Brown controls this case.
The petitioners are governmental bodies, not private persons, and
their actions are "act [s] of government" which
Parker v.
Brown held are not subject to the Sherman Act. But, instead of
applying the
Parker doctrine, the Court today imposes
new
Page 435 U. S. 427
and unjustifiable limits upon it. According to the plurality,
governmental action will henceforth be immune from the antitrust
laws [
Footnote 3/1] only when
"authorized or directed" by the State "pursuant to state policy to
displace competition with regulation or monopoly public service."
Ante at
435 U. S. 414,
435 U. S. 413.
Such a "direction" from the State apparently will exist only when
it can be shown
"'from the authority given a governmental entity to operate in a
particular area, that the legislature contemplated the kind of
action complained of.'"
Ante at
435 U. S. 415.
By this exclusive focus on a legislative mandate, the plurality has
effectively limited the governmental action immunity of the
Parker case to the acts of a state legislature. This is a
sharp, and, I think, unjustifiable, departure from our prior
cases.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE adopts a different approach, at once broader
and narrower than the plurality's. In his view, municipalities are
subject to antitrust liability when they engage in "proprietary
enterprises,"
ante at
435 U. S. 422,
but apparently retain their antitrust immunity for other types of
activity. But a city engaged in proprietary activity is to be
treated as if it were a private corporation: that is, it is immune
from the antitrust laws only if it shows not merely that its action
was "
required by the State acting as sovereign,'" but also that
such immunity is "`necessary in order to make the [State's]
regulatory Act work.'" Ante at 435 U. S. 425,
435 U. S. 426.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE's approach seems to me just as mistaken as the
plurality's.
Page 435 U. S. 428
I
The fundamental error in the opinions of the plurality and THE
CHIEF JUSTICE is their failure to recognize the difference between
private activities authorized or regulated by government, on the
one hand, and the actions of government itself, on the other.
A
In determining whether the actions of a political subdivision of
a State, as well as those of a state legislature, are immune from
the Sherman Act, we must interpret the provisions of the Act "in
the light of its legislative history and of the particular evils at
which the legislation was aimed."
Apex Hosiery Co. v.
Leader, 310 U. S. 469,
310 U. S. 489.
Those "particular evils" did not include acts of governmental
bodies. Rather, Congress was concerned with attacking
concentrations of private economic power unresponsive to public
needs, such as "these great trusts, these great corporations, these
large moneyed institutions." 21 Cong.Rec. 2562 (1890). [
Footnote 3/2]
Recognizing this congressional intent, the Court, in
Parker
v. Brown, held that the antitrust laws apply to private, and
not governmental, action. The program there at issue was, in
Page 435 U. S. 429
fact, established by California's legislature, and not by one of
its political subdivisions. But the Court nowhere held that the
actions of municipal governments should not equally be immune from
the antitrust laws. On the contrary, it expressly equated "the
state or its municipality." 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 351.
The
Parker opinion repeatedly and carefully [
Footnote 3/3] emphasized that California's
program was not the action of "private persons, individual or
corporate."
Id. at
317 U. S. 350.
[
Footnote 3/4] The distinction
established in
Parker v. Brown was not one between actions
of a state legislature and those of other governmental units.
Rather, the Court drew the line between private action and
governmental action.
There can be no doubt on which side of this line the
petitioners' actions fall. "Municipal corporations are
instrumentalities of the State for the convenient administration of
government within their limits."
Louisiana ex rel. Folsom v.
Mayor of New Orleans, 109 U. S. 285,
109 U. S. 287;
cf. Reynolds v. Sims, 377 U. S. 533,
377 U.S. 575. [
Footnote 3/5] They have only such powers as
are delegated them by the State of which they are a subdivision,
and, when they act, they exercise the State's sovereign power.
Avery v. Midland County, 390 U. S. 474,
390 U. S. 480;
Breard v.
Page 435 U. S. 430
Alexandria, 341 U. S. 622,
341 U. S. 640.
City governments are not unaccountable to the public, but are
subject to direct popular control through their own electorates and
through the state legislature. [
Footnote 3/6] They are thus a far cry from the private
accumulations of wealth that the Sherman Act was intended to
regulate.
B
The plurality today advances two reasons for holding nonetheless
that the
Parker doctrine is inapplicable to municipal
governments. First, the plurality notes that municipalities cannot
claim the State's sovereign immunity under the Eleventh Amendment.
Ante at
435 U. S. 412.
But this is hardly relevant to the question of whether they are
within the reach of the Sherman Act. That question must be answered
by reference to congressional intent, and not constitutional
principles that apply in entirely different situations. [
Footnote 3/7] And if constitutional
analogies are to be looked to, a decision much more directly
related to this case than those under the Eleventh Amendment is
National League of Cities v. Usery, 426 U.
S. 833. That case, like this one, involved an exercise
of Congress' power under the Commerce Clause, and held that States
and their political subdivisions must be given equal deference.
Id. at
426 U. S.
855-856, n. 20. The plurality does not advance any basis
for its disregard of
National League of Cities and its
Page 435 U. S. 431
reliance instead on the basically irrelevant body of law under
the Eleventh Amendment.
Secondly, the plurality relies on
Goldfarb v. Virginia State
Bar, 421 U. S. 773. The
Goldfarb case, however, did not overrule
Parker v.
Brown, but rather applied it.
Goldfarb concerned a
scheme regulating economic competition among private parties,
namely, lawyers. The Court held that this "private anticompetitive
activity," 421 U.S. at
421 U. S. 792,
could not be sheltered under the umbrella of the
Parker
doctrine unless it was compelled by the State. Since the bar
association and State Bar could show no more than that their
minimum fee schedule "complemented" actions of the State,
id. at
421 U. S. 791,
the scheme was not immune from the antitrust laws.
Cf.
Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp., 341 U.
S. 384.
Unlike
Goldfarb, this case does not involve any
anticompetitive activity by private persons. As noted in
Bates
v. State Bar of Arizona, 433 U. S. 350,
433 U. S. 361,
actions of governmental bodies themselves present "an entirely
different case" falling squarely within the rule of
Parker v.
Brown. Although the State Bar in
Goldfarb was "a
state agency for some limited purposes," 421 U.S. at
421 U. S. 791,
the price-fixing it fostered was for the private benefit of its
members, and its actions were essentially those of a private
professional group.
Cf. Asheville Tobacco Board of Trade, Inc.
v. FTC, 263 F.2d 502, 508-510 (CA4). Unlike a city, the
Virginia State Bar surely is not "a political subdivision of the
State." [
Footnote 3/8]
By requiring that a city show a legislative mandate for its
activity, the plurality today blurs, if indeed it does not erase,
this logical distinction between private and governmental action.
In
Goldfarb and in
Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co.,
428 U. S. 579, the
Court held that private action must be compelled by the state
legislature in order to escape the reach of the Sherman Act. State
compulsion is an appropriate requirement
Page 435 U. S. 432
when private persons claim that their anticompetitive actions
are not their own, but the State's, since a State cannot immunize
private anticompetitive conduct merely by permitting it. [
Footnote 3/9] But it is senseless to
require a showing of state compulsion when the State itself acts
through one of its governmental subdivisions.
See New Mexico v.
American Petrofina, Inc., 501 F.2d 363, 369-370 (CA9).
C
The separate opinion of THE CHIEF JUSTICE does not rely on any
distinctions between States and their political subdivisions. It
purports to find a simpler reason for subjecting the petitioners to
antitrust liability despite the fact that they are governmental
bodies, namely, that
Parker v. Brown does not protect "a
State's entrepreneurial personality."
Ante at
435 U. S. 422.
[
Footnote 3/10] But this
distinction is no more substantial a basis for disregarding the
governmental action immunity in this case than the reasons advanced
by the plurality.
A State may choose to regulate private persons providing certain
goods or services, or it may provide the goods and services itself.
The State's regulatory body in the former case, or a state-owned
utility in the latter, will necessarily make economic decisions.
These decisions may be responsive to similar concerns, and they may
have similar anticompetitive effects. [
Footnote 3/11] Yet, according to THE CHIEF JUSTICE, the
former
Page 435 U. S. 433
type of governmental decision is immune from antitrust
liability, while the latter is not.
There is no basis for this distinction either in the Sherman Act
itself or in our prior cases interpreting it. To the contrary,
Parker v. Brown established that governmental actions are
not regulated by the Sherman Act.
See supra at
435 U. S.
428-430. And, as this Court has previously said:
"'Government is not partly public or partly private, depending
upon the governmental pedigree of the type of a particular activity
or the manner in which the Government conducts it.'
Federal
Crop Insurance Corp. v. Merrill, 332 U. S.
380,
332 U. S. 383-384. On the
other hand, it is hard to think of any governmental activity on the
'operational level,' our present concern, which is 'uniquely
governmental' in the sense that its kind has not, at one time or
another, been, or could not conceivably be, privately
performed."
Indian Towing Co. v. United States, 350 U. S.
61,
350 U. S. 67-68.
Nonetheless, THE CHIEF JUSTICE would treat some governmental
actions as governmental for purposes of the antitrust laws, and
some as if they were not governmental at all.
Moreover, the scope of the immunity envisioned by THE CHIEF
JUSTICE is virtually impossible to determine. The distinction
between "proprietary" and "governmental" activities has aptly been
described as a "quagmire."
Id. at
350 U. S. 65.
The "distinctions [are] so finespun and capricious as to be almost
incapable of being held in the mind for adequate formulation."
Id. at
350 U. S. 65-68.
The separate opinion of THE CHIEF JUSTICE does nothing to make
these distinctions any more substantial or understandable.
[
Footnote 3/12] Indeed, even a
moment's
Page 435 U. S. 434
consideration of the range of services provided today by
governments shows how difficult it is to determine whether or not
they are "proprietary." For example, i a city or State decides to
provide water service to its citizens at cost on a monopoly basis,
is its action to be characterized as "proprietary"? Whether it is
"proprietary" or not, it is surely an act of government, as are the
petitioners' actions in this case.
Cf. Lowenstein v.
Evans, 69 F. 908 (CC S.C.). [
Footnote 3/13] But THE CHIEF JUSTICE, like the
plurality, ignores what seems to me the controlling distinction in
this case, that between private and governmental action.
II
The Court's decision in this case marks an extraordinary
intrusion into the operation of state and local government in this
country. Its impact can hardly be overstated.
A
Under our federal system, a State is generally free to allocate
its governmental power to its political subdivisions as it wishes.
[
Footnote 3/14] A State may
decide to permit its municipalities to exercise its police power
without having to obtain approval of each law from the legislature.
[
Footnote 3/15] Such local
self-government
Page 435 U. S. 435
serves important state interests. It allows a state legislature
to devote more time to statewide problems without being burdened
with purely local matters, and allows municipalities to deal
quickly and flexibly with local problems. But today's decision, by
demanding extensive legislative control over municipal action, will
necessarily diminish the extent to which a State can share its
power with autonomous local governmental bodies.
This will follow from the plurality's emphasis on state
legislative action, and the vagueness of the criteria it announces.
[
Footnote 3/16] First, it is not
clear from the plurality opinion whether a municipal government's
actions will be immune from the Sherman Act if they are merely
"authorized" by a state legislature, or whether they must be
legislatively "directed" in order to enjoy immunity. While the
plurality uses these terms interchangeably, they can have very
different meanings.
See Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428
U.S. at
428 U. S.
592-593. A municipality that is merely "authorized" by a
state statute to provide a monopoly service thus cannot be certain
it will not be subject to antitrust liability if it does so.
Second, the plurality gives no indication of how specifically
the legislature's "direction" must relate to the "action complained
of." Reference to the facts of this case will show how elusive the
plurality's test is. Stripped to its essentials, the counterclaim
alleged that the petitioners engaged in sham litigation, maintained
their monopolies by debenture covenants, foreclosed competition by
long-term supply contracts,
Page 435 U. S. 436
and tied the sale of gas and water to the sale of electricity.
Broadly speaking, these actions could be characterized as bringing
lawsuits, issuing bonds, and providing electric and gas service,
all of which are activities authorized by state statutes. [
Footnote 3/17] But, in affirming the
judgment of the Court of Appeals, the Court makes evident that it
does not consider these statutes alone a sufficient "mandate" to
the cities.
On the other hand, the plurality states that a city need not
"point to a specific, detailed legislative authorization before it
properly may assert a
Parker defense to an antitrust
suit."
Ante at
435 U. S. 415.
Thus, it seems that the petitioners need not identify a statute
compelling each lawsuit, each contract, and each debenture
covenant. [
Footnote 3/18] But
what intermediate showing
Page 435 U. S. 437
of legislative authorization, approval, or command will meet the
plurality's test I am unable to fathom. [
Footnote 3/19]
Finally, state statutes often are enacted with little recorded
legislative history, [
Footnote
3/20] and the bare words of a statute will often be
unilluminating in interpreting legislative intent. For example, do
the Louisiana statutes permitting the petitioners to operate public
utilities [
Footnote 3/21]
"contemplate" that the petitioners might tie the sale of gas to the
sale of electricity? Do those statutes, indeed, "contemplate" that
electric service will be provided to city residents on a monopoly
basis? Without legislative history or relevant statutory language,
any answer to these questions would be purely a creation of
judicial imagination. [
Footnote
3/22]
Page 435 U. S. 438
As a practical result of the uncertainties in today's opinions
[
Footnote 3/23] and of the
plurality's emphasis on state legislative action, a prudent
municipality will probably believe itself compelled to seek passage
of a state statute requiring it to engage in any activity which
might be considered anticompetitive. Each time a city grants an
exclusive franchise, or chooses to provide a service itself on a
monopoly basis, or refuses to grant a zoning variance to a
business, [
Footnote 3/24] or even
-- as alleged in this case -- brings litigation on behalf of its
citizens, state legislative action will be necessary to ensure that
a federal court will not subsequently decide that the activity was
not "contemplated" by the legislature. Thus, the effect of today's
decision is greatly to impair the ability of a State to delegate
governmental power broadly to its municipalities. [
Footnote 3/25] Such extensive interference with
the fundamentals of state government is not a proper function of
the federal judiciary. [
Footnote
3/26]
B
Today's decision will cause excessive judicial interference not
only with the procedures by which a State makes its governmental
decisions, but with their substance, as well.
Page 435 U. S. 439
States should be "accorded wide latitude in the regulation of
their local economies,"
New Orleans v. Dukes, 427 U.
S. 297,
427 U. S. 303,
and in "the manner in which they will structure delivery of those
governmental services which their citizens require."
National
League of Cities v. Usery, 426 U.S. at
426 U. S. 847.
The antitrust liability the Court today imposes on municipal
governments will sharply limit that latitude.
First, the very vagueness and uncertainty of the new test for
antitrust immunity is bound to discourage state agencies and
subdivisions in their experimentation with innovative social and
economic programs. [
Footnote
3/27] In the exercise of their powers, local governmental
entities often take actions that might violate the antitrust laws
if taken by private persons, such as granting exclusive franchises,
enacting restrictive zoning ordinances, and providing public
services on a monopoly basis. But a city contemplating such action
in the interest of its citizens will be able to do so after today
only at the risk of discovering too late that a federal court
believes that insufficient statutory "direction" existed, or that
the activity is "proprietary" in nature.
Second, the imposition of antitrust liability on the activities
of municipal governments will allow the sort of wide-ranging
inquiry into the reasonableness of state regulations that this
Court has forsworn. [
Footnote
3/28] For example, in
New Orleans v. Dukes, supra, a
city ordinance which, to preserve the character of a historic area,
prohibited the sale of food from pushcarts unless the vendor had
been in business for at least eight years was challenged under the
Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. The Court
upheld the constitutional validity of the ordinance. But it now
appears that, if Dukes had proceeded under the antitrust laws and
claimed that the ordinance was an unreasonably anticompetitive
limit
Page 435 U. S. 440
on the number of pushcart vendors, he might well have prevailed
unless New Orleans could establish that the Louisiana Legislature
"contemplated" the exclusion of all but a few pushcart vendors from
the historic area. The "wide latitude" of the States "in the
regulation of their local economies," exercised in
Dukes
by the city to which this power to regulate had been delegated,
could thus be wholly stifled by the application of the antitrust
laws.
C
Finally, today's decision will impose staggering costs on the
thousands of municipal governments in our country. In this case, a
not atypical antitrust action, the respondent claimed that it had
suffered damages of $180 million as a result of only one of the
antitrust violations it alleged. Trebled, this amounts to $540
million on this claim alone, to be recovered from cities with a
combined population (in 1970) of about 75,000. [
Footnote 3/29] A judgment of this magnitude would
assure bankruptcy for almost any municipality against which it
might be rendered. [
Footnote
3/30] Even if the petitioners ultimately prevail, their
citizens will have to bear the rapidly mounting
Page 435 U. S. 441
costs of antitrust litigation through increased taxes or
decreased services. [
Footnote
3/31] The prospect of a city closing its schools, discharging
its policemen, and curtailing its fire department in order to
defend an antitrust suit would surely dismay the Congress that
enacted the Sherman Act. [
Footnote
3/32]
For all of the reasons discussed in this opinion, I respectfully
dissent.
* MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN joins all but Part II-B of this
opinion.
[
Footnote 3/1]
As the plurality acknowledges,
ante at
435 U. S. 393
n. 8,
Parker v. Brown did not create any exemption from
the antitrust laws, but simply recognized that it was the intent of
Congress that the Sherman Act should not apply to governmental
action. It is thus hard to understand why the plurality invokes the
doctrine that exemptions from the antitrust laws will not be
lightly implied by subsequent enactment of a regulatory statute.
This rule, which effects the accommodation of two federal statutes
and rests on the principle that implied repeals are not favored,
has no relevance to the
Parker doctrine, which is based on
an interpretation of the Sherman Act itself.
[
Footnote 3/2]
See also, e.g., 20 Cong.Rec. 1458 (1889) ("the
practice, now becoming too common, of large corporations, and of
single persons, too, of large wealth, so arranging that they
dictate to the people of this country what they shall pay when they
purchase, and what they shall receive when they sell"); 21
Cong.Rec. 2728 (1890) ("transaction[s] the only purpose of which is
to extort from the community, monopolize, segregate, and apply to
individual use, for the purposes of individual greed, wealth which
ought properly and lawfully and for the public interest to be
generally diffused over the whole community");
id. at 3147
(remarks of Sen. George).
That the Sherman Act was enacted to deal with combinations of
individuals and corporations for private business advantage has
long been recognized by this Court.
Eastern Railroad Presidents
Conf. v. Noerr Motor Freight, Inc., 365 U.
S. 127,
365 U. S.
135-136;
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.S.
at
310 U. S.
492-493, and n. 15;
Standard Oil Co. v. United
States, 221 U. S. 1,
221 U. S. 50,
221 U. S. 58.
[
Footnote 3/3]
See Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.
S. 579,
428 U. S. 51, and
n. 24.
[
Footnote 3/4]
The Court assumed that California's program would violate the
Sherman Act "if it were organized and made effective solely by
virtue of a contract, combination or conspiracy of private persons,
individual or corporate," but noted that the program "was never
intended to operate by force of individual agreement or
combination." 317 U.S. at
317 U. S. 350.
The Court found nothing in the Sherman Act or its legislative
history to suggest that "it was intended to restrain state action
or official action directed by a state"; rather, the Act was
intended "to suppress combinations to restrain competition and
attempts to monopolize by individuals and corporations."
Id. at
317 U. S. 351.
It was "a prohibition of individual, and not state, action."
Id. at
317 U. S.
352.
[
Footnote 3/5]
See also, e.g., Trenton v. New Jersey, 262 U.
S. 182,
262 U. S.
185-186;
Hunter v. Pittsburgh, 207 U.
S. 161,
207 U. S. 178;
The Mayor v.
Ray, 19 Wall. 468,
86 U. S. 475;
Bradford v. Shreveport, 305 So.
2d 487 (La.).
[
Footnote 3/6]
Cf. Barnes v. District of Columbia, 91 U. S.
540,
91 U. S.
544-545;
The Mayor v. Ray, supra at
86 U. S. 475;
East Hartford v. Hartford
Bridge Co., 10 How. 511. Under Louisiana law, the
petitioners' powers are subject to complete legislative control.
See Bradford v. Shreveport, supra.
[
Footnote 3/7]
That the particular factual and legal context is all important
is shown by the fact that, under other provisions of the
Constitution, a municipality is equated with a State.
E.g.,
Waller v. Florida, 397 U. S. 387
(Double Jeopardy Clause);
Avery v. Midland County,
390 U. S. 474,
390 U. S. 480
(Fourteenth Amendment);
Trenton v. New Jersey, supra,
(Impairment of Contract Clause).
See also Doran v. Salem Inn,
Inc., 422 U. S. 922,
422 U. S. 927
n. 2 (28 U.S.C.§ 1254(2)).
[
Footnote 3/8]
Worcester v. Street R. Co., 196 U.
S. 539,
196 U. S.
548.
[
Footnote 3/9]
See Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp.,
341 U. S. 384;
Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.
S. 197,
193 U. S.
346.
[
Footnote 3/10]
However, the District Court's "conclusion,"
ante at
435 U. S. 418,
that the petitioners' electric utility service was a business
activity engaged in for profit was not supported by any evidence
(since the case was decided on a motion to dismiss), and is indeed
challenged here by the petitioners in their reply brief.
[
Footnote 3/11]
Of course, the fact -- heavily relied upon both by the plurality
and THE CHIEF JUSTICE -- that the actions of cities may have
anticompetitive effects misses the point. The whole issue before
the Court today is whether conduct that would concededly subject a
private individual to liability because of its anticompetitive
nature is proscribed by the antitrust laws when undertaken by a
city.
[
Footnote 3/12]
In various places, the separate opinion of THE CHIEF JUSTICE
refers to "
business activit[ies] . . . in which a profit is
realized,'" to "proprietary enterprises," to activities which have
"the inherent capacity for economically disruptive anticompetitive
effects," to those which are not "integral operation[s] in the area
of traditional government functions," and to those not "the
prerogative of the State."
[
Footnote 3/13]
This case, involving a state liquor monopoly, was cited with
approval in
Parker v. Brown, 317 U.S. at
317 U. S.
352.
[
Footnote 3/14]
See, e.g., Lockport v. Citizens for Community Action,
430 U. S. 259,
430 U. S. 269;
Avery v. Midland County, 390 U.S. at
390 U. S.
481-482.
[
Footnote 3/15]
Local self-government is broadest in "home rule" municipalities,
which can be almost entirely free from legislative control in local
matters.
See Vanlandingham, Municipal Home Rule in the
United States, 10 Wm. & Mary L.Rev. 269 (1968). Although the
petitioners are not home rule cities, Louisiana's Constitution has
a home rule provision, La.Const. of 1974, Art. 6, §§ 5,
6; La.Const. of 1921, Art. XIV, §§ 22, 40(c), as do the
constitutions or statutes of at least 33 other States. Note,
Antitrust Law and Municipal Corporations, 65 Geo.L.J. 1547, 1559 n.
77 (1977).
[
Footnote 3/16]
While THE CHIEF JUSTICE has not joined those portions of the
plurality opinion that discuss what is necessary to show that a
challenged activity was required by the State, he would apparently
require a still stronger, and hence less justifiable, showing of
state legislative compulsion.
Ante at
435 U. S.
425-426, n. 6.
[
Footnote 3/17]
La.Rev.Stat.Ann. § 33:621 (West 1951):
"The inhabitants of the city shall continue a body politic and
corporate by its present name and, as such, . . . may sue and be
sued; . . . may acquire by condemnation or otherwise, construct,
own, lease, and operate and regulate public utilities within or
without the corporate limits of the city subject only to
restrictions imposed by general law for the protection of other
communities; . . . [and] may borrow money on the faith and credit
of the city by issue or sale of bonds, notes, or other evidences of
debt. . . ."
See also La.Rev.Stat.Ann. §§ 33:1326 (West
1951), 33:4162, 33:4163 (West 1966).
[
Footnote 3/18]
The plurality's suggestion that the Louisiana Legislature has
expressed a state policy that the activities of cities should be
subject to the antitrust laws,
ante at
435 U. S.
414-415, n. 44, and 416, is both erroneous and
irrelevant. Louisiana Rev.Stat.Ann. § 33:1334(G) (West Supp.
1977) applies not to municipalities, but only to utility
commissions created jointly by several cities or counties; there is
no comparable statute applicable to the petitioners. Moreover, the
applicability of the federal antitrust laws is a matter of federal,
not state, law; conversely, a State's restrictions on municipal
action are a matter of state, not federal, law. A State can no more
bring a person's conduct within the coverage of federal law when
Congress has not done so than it can exempt a person's conduct from
the operation of federal law if Congress has provided otherwise.
Cf. Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp.,
341 U. S. 384.
[
Footnote 3/19]
The Court imposes yet another unwarranted limitation upon
governmental immunity from the antitrust laws. Apparently, a
municipality can claim immunity only if the state legislature has
mandated its action "pursuant to state policy to displace
competition with regulation or monopoly public service."
Ante at
435 U. S. 413
(plurality opinion);
see ante at
435 U. S. 425
(opinion of BURGER, C.J.). Even had the Louisiana State Legislature
passed a law specifically compelling the petitioners to litigate in
an effort to prevent respondent from constructing its nuclear
generating facility, compelling them to insert restrictive
covenants in their debentures, and compelling the tying
arrangements complained of, could such a law fairly be described as
"displac[ing] competition with regulation or monopoly public
service"? Would the Court thus deny the cities immunity for their
actions even if they were compelled by the State which controlled
them?
[
Footnote 3/20]
See M. Price & I. Bitner, Effective Legal Research
73, 103 (3d ed.1969).
[
Footnote 3/21]
See n 17,
supra.
[
Footnote 3/22]
This problem of statutory interpretation is exacerbated by the
fact that today's decision will have "retroactive" application in
two senses. First, antitrust liability can be premised on actions
that have occurred in the past. Second, many of the statutes
governing contemporary and future municipal activities were enacted
years ago. Thus, municipalities will be faced with the difficult
problem of establishing their antitrust immunity based on statutes
that were enacted without any foreknowledge of the criteria
announced by the Court today.
[
Footnote 3/23]
The vagueness of the test proposed in the separate opinion of
THE CHIEF JUSTICE,
see supra at
435 U. S.
433-434, will only add to the confusion of a city trying
to protect itself from antitrust liability.
[
Footnote 3/24]
See Whitworth v. Perkins, 559 F.2d 378 (CA5).
[
Footnote 3/25]
By imposing antitrust liability on "proprietary" governmental
activities, the test adopted in the opinion of THE CHIEF JUSTICE
would further deter States from choosing to provide services
themselves, rather than regulating others.
[
Footnote 3/26]
See Sailors v. Board of Education, 387 U.
S. 105;
Williams v. Eggleston, 170 U.
S. 304,
170 U. S. 310;
see also Baker v. Carr, 369 U. S. 186,
369 U.S. 289-290, and n.
23, and cases cited (Frankfurter, J., dissenting).
The plurality's emphasis on legislative action also leaves in
doubt the status of state delegations of power to administrative
agencies, unless they, too, can show that the legislature
"directed" their actions. This, of course, defeats the whole
purpose of establishing such agencies.
[
Footnote 3/27]
See New State Ice Co. v. Liebmann, 285 U.
S. 262,
285 U. S. 311
(Brandeis, J., dissenting).
[
Footnote 3/28]
Ferguson v. Skrupa, 372 U. S. 726.
[
Footnote 3/29]
U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1970 Census
of Population, Number of Inhabitants, United States Summary, Table
31 (1971).
[
Footnote 3/30]
The Court indicates that the remedy of treble damages might not
be "appropriate" in antitrust actions against a municipality.
Ante at
435 U.S.
401-402, and n. 22. But the language of § 4 of the
Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15 (1976 ed.), is mandatory on its
face: it requires that
"[a]ny person who shall be injured in his business or property
by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws . . .
shall recover threefold the damages by him sustained."
(Emphasis supplied.)
Cf., e.g., 35 U.S.C. § 284.
And the legislative history cited by MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN,
post at
435 U. S. 443
n. 2, demonstrates that Congress has understood the treble damages
provision to be mandatory, and has refused to change it. The Court
does not say on what basis a district court could possibly
disregard this clear statutory command.
Cf. Perma Life
Mufflers, Inc. v. International Parts Corp., 392 U.
S. 134.
[
Footnote 3/31]
Legal fees to defend one current antitrust suit have been
estimated as at least one-half million dollars a month. N.Y. Times,
June 27, 1977, p. 41, col. 6;
id. Sept. 4, 1977, section
3, p. 5, col. 1.
[
Footnote 3/32]
Treble damages liability can, of course, be ruinous to a private
corporation as well. But a private corporation, organized for the
purpose of seeking private profit, is surely very different from a
city providing essential governmental functions, and shareholders
do not stand in the same relation to their corporation as do
residents or taxpayers to the city in which they live. An
investment in a corporation is essentially a business decision; a
shareholder takes the risks of corporate losses in the hope of
corporate profits. A citizen's relationship to his city government
is obviously far different.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN, dissenting.
I join MR. JUSTICE STEWART's dissent with the exception of
435 U. S. but
wish to note that I do not take his opinion as reaching the
question whether petitioners should be immune under the Sherman Act
even if found to have been acting in concert with private parties.
To grant immunity to municipalities in such a circumstance would go
beyond the protections previously accorded officials of the States
themselves.
See Parker v. Brown, 317 U.
S. 341,
317 U. S.
351-352 (193) ("[W]e have no question of the state or
its municipality becoming a participant in a private agreement or
combination by others for restraint of trade,
cf. Union Pacific
R. Co. v. United States, 313 U. S. 450").
The Court of Appeals did not have the opportunity to rule on how a
"conspiracy with private parties" exception to municipalities'
general immunity should be limited, if indeed such an exception is
appropriate at all. If the view that municipalities are not subject
to the full reach
Page 435 U. S. 442
of Sherman Act liability had commanded a majority, a remand for
consideration of this more limited exception would be in order.
In light of the fact that the plurality and THE CHIEF JUSTICE
have concluded that municipalities should be subject to broad
Sherman Act liability, I must question the nonchalance with which
the Court puts aside the question of remedy.
Ante at
435 U. S. 402,
and n. 22. It is a grave act to make governmental units potentially
liable for massive treble damages when, however "proprietary" some
of their activities may seem, they have fundamental
responsibilities to their citizens for the provision of
life-sustaining services such as police and fire protection. The
several occasions in the past when the Court has found that
Congress intended to subject municipalities and States to liability
as "persons" or "corporations" do not provide the support for
today's holding that the plurality opinion would pretend.
Ante at
435 U. S.
400-402, and nn.19-21. The Court cites previous
constructions of the Elkins Act; the federal tax on sellers of
alcoholic beverages; and the Shipping Act, 1916. But the financial
penalties available under those Acts do not even approach the
magnitude of the treble damages remedy provided by the antitrust
laws. [
Footnote 4/1] Nor has
Page 435 U. S. 443
the Court come to grips with the plainly mandatory language of
§ 4 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15 (1976 ed.):
"Any person who shall be injured in his business or property by
reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws . . .
shall recover threefold the damages by him sustained"
(emphasis supplied), and the repeated occasions on which
Congress has rejected proposals to make the treble damages remedy
discretionary. [
Footnote 4/2] It is
one thing to leave open the question of remedy if there is a
conceivable defense to damages whose theory is consistent with the
mandatory language of the Clayton Act (
e.g., in the case
of private utilities subject to state tariffs, that their conduct
was required by state law, and hence was involuntary).
See
Cantor v. Detroit Edison Co., 428 U.
S. 579,
428 U. S.
614-615, n. 6 (1976) (opinion concurring in judgment).
It is quite another to delay the question of remedy in the absence
of any suggested basis for a defense, especially where the prospect
of insolvency for petitioner cities would so threaten the welfare
of their inhabitants. The sensible course, it seems to me, is to
consider the range of liability in light of the range of defendants
for whom Sherman Act penalties would be appropriate.
[
Footnote 4/1]
Respondent seeks treble damages in excess of $540 million in
this case. If divided among Plaquemine and Lafayette residents,
that penalty would exceed $28,000 for each family of four.
Under the federal tax on sellers of alcoholic beverages, 26
U.S.C. §§ 11 and 205 (1926 ed.), construed in
Ohio v.
Helvering, 292 U. S. 360,
292 U. S.
370-371 (1934), the potential liability of the State of
Ohio was $25 for each retail, and $100 for each wholesale, outlet.
Under §§ 16 and 17 of the Shipping Act, 1916, 46 U.S.C.
§§ 815, 816 (1940 ed.), construed in
California v.
United States, 320 U. S. 577,
320 U. S.
585-586 (1944), a violation was a misdemeanor punishable
by a $5,000 fine. The Court's only arguable support lies in §
1 of the Elkins Act, 49 U.S.C. § 41, construed in
Union
Pacific R. Co. v. United States, 313 U.
S. 450 (1941). Even there, the potential liability of a
municipality not acting as a common carrier is a $20,000 fine, and,
were illegal transportation rebates to be received by the
municipality, three times the amount of the rebate. Even if a
municipality were held to be operating a common carrier under that
Act, potential financial liability is limited to the fine and the
actual damages caused by the prohibited conduct. 49 U.S.C. §
8.
[
Footnote 4/2]
E.g., H.R. 4597, 83d Cong., 1st Sess. (1953); H.R.
6875, 84th Cong., 1st Sess. (1955); H.R. 978, 85th Cong., 1st Sess.
(1957); H.R. 1184, 86th Cong., 1st Sess. (1959); H.R.190, 87th
Cong., 1st Sess. (1961).
See also Hearings on H.R. 4597
before Subcommittee No. 3 of the House Committee on the Judiciary,
83d Cong., 1st Sess. (1953); Hearings before the Antitrust
Subcommittee of the House Committee on the Judiciary, 84th Cong.,
1st Sess., 189, 509-522, 2246-2249 (1955).