Respondents, the State of Illinois and 700 local governmental
entities, brought this antitrust treble damages action under §
4 of the Clayton Act alleging that petitioners, concrete block
manufacturers (which sell to masonry contractors, which in turn
sell to general contractors, from which respondents purchase the
block in the form of masonry structures) had engaged in a
price-fixing conspiracy in violation of § 1 of the Sherman
Act. Petitioners, relying on
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe
Machinery Corp., 392 U. S. 481,
moved for partial summary judgment against all plaintiffs that were
indirect purchasers of block from petitioners, contending that only
direct purchasers could sue for the alleged overcharge. The
District Court granted the motion, but the Court of Appeals
reversed, holding that indirect purchasers such as respondents
could recover treble damages for an illegal overcharge if they
could prove that the overcharge was passed on to them through the
intermediate distribution channels.
Hanover Shoe held that
generally the illegally overcharged direct purchaser suing for
treble damages, and not others in the chain of manufacture or
distribution, is the party "injured in his business or property"
within the meaning of § 4.
Held:
1. If a pass-on theory may not be used defensively by an
antitrust violator (defendant) against a direct purchaser
(plaintiff), that theory may not be used offensively by an indirect
purchaser (plaintiff) against an alleged violator (defendant).
Therefore, unless
Hanover Shoe is to be overruled or
limited, it bars respondents' pass-on theory. Pp.
431 U. S.
729-736.
(a) Allowing offensive but not defensive use of pass-on would
create a serious risk of multiple liability for defendants, since
even though an indirect purchaser had already recovered for all or
part of an overcharge passed on to him, the direct purchaser would
still automatically recover the full amount of the overcharge that
the indirect purchaser had shown to be passed on, and, similarly,
following an automatic recovery of the full overcharge by the
direct purchaser, the indirect purchaser could sue to recover the
same amount. Overlapping recoveries would certainly result from the
two lawsuits unless the indirect purchaser is unable to establish
any pass-on whatsoever. Pp.
431 U. S.
730-731.
Page 431 U. S. 721
(b) The Court's perception in
Hanover Shoe of the
uncertainties and difficulties in analyzing price and output
decisions "in the real economic world, rather than an economist's
hypothetical model," applies with equal force to the assertion of
pass-on theories by plaintiffs as it does to such assertion by
defendants. Pp.
431 U. S.
731-733.
(c) Because
Hanover Shoe would bar petitioners from
using respondents' pass-on theory as a defense to a treble damages
suit by the direct purchasers (the masonry contractors),
Hanover Shoe must be overruled (or narrowly limited), or
it must be applied to bar respondents' attempt to use this pass-on
theory offensively. Pp.
431 U. S.
735-736.
2.
Hanover Shoe was correctly decided, and its
construction of § 4 is adhered to. Pp.
431 U. S.
736-747.
(a) Considerations of
stare decisis weigh heavily in
the area of statutory construction, where Congress is free to
change this Court's interpretation of its legislation. Pp.
431 U. S.
736-737.
(b) Whole new dimensions of complexity would be added to treble
damages suits, undermining their effectiveness, if the use of
pass-on theories under § 4 were allowed. Even under the
optimistic assumption that joinder of potential plaintiffs would
deal satisfactorily with problems of multiple litigation and
liability, § 4 actions would be transformed into massive
multiparty litigations involving many distribution levels and
including large classes of ultimate consumers remote from the
defendant. The Court's concern in
Hanover Shoe with the
problems of "massive evidence and complicated theories" involved in
attempting to establish a pass-on defense against a direct
purchaser applies
a fortiori to the attempt to trace the
effect of the overcharge through each step in the distribution
chain from the direct purchasers to the ultimate consumer. Pp.
431 U. S.
737-744.
(c) Attempts to carve out exceptions to
Hanover Shoe
for particular types of markets would entail the very problems that
Hanover Shoe sought to avoid. Pp.
431 U. S.
744-745.
(d) The legislative purpose in creating a group of "private
attorneys general" to enforce the antitrust laws under § 4,
Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of California, 405 U.
S. 251,
405 U. S. 262,
is better served by holding direct purchasers to be injured to the
full extent of the overcharge paid by them than by attempting to
apportion the overcharge among all that may have absorbed a part of
it. Pp.
431 U. S.
745-747.
536 F.2d 1163, reversed and remanded.
WHITE, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which BURGER,
C.J., and STEWART, POWELL, REHNQUIST, and STEVENS, JJ., joined.
BRENNAN, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which MARSHALL and
BLACKMUN, JJ.,
Page 431 U. S. 722
joined,
post, p.
431 U. S. 748.
BLACKMUN, J., filed a dissenting opinion,
post, p.
431 U. S.
765.
Page 431 U. S. 723
MR JUSTICE WHITE delivered the opinion of the Court.
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Machinery Corp.,
392 U. S. 481
(1968), involved an antitrust treble damages action
Page 431 U. S. 724
brought under § 4 of the Clayton Act [
Footnote 1] against a manufacturer of shoe
machinery by one of its customers, a manufacturer of shoes. In
defense, the shoe machinery manufacturer sought to show that the
plaintiff had not been injured in its business as required by
§ 4 because it had passed on the claimed illegal overcharge to
those who bought shoes from it. Under the defendant's theory, the
illegal overcharge was absorbed by the plaintiff's customers --
indirect purchasers of the defendant's shoe machinery -- who were
the persons actually injured by the antitrust violation.
In
Hanover Shoe, this Court rejected as a matter of law
this defense that indirect, rather than direct, purchasers were the
parties injured by the antitrust violation. The Court held that,
except in certain limited circumstances, [
Footnote 2] a direct purchaser suing for treble damages
under § 4 of the Clayton Act is injured within the meaning of
§ 4 by the full amount of the overcharge paid by it, and that
the antitrust defendant is
Page 431 U. S. 725
not permitted to introduce evidence that indirect purchasers
were in fact injured by the illegal overcharge. 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 494.
The first reason for the Court's rejection of this offer of proof
was an unwillingness to complicate treble damages actions with
attempts to trace the effects of the overcharge on the purchaser's
prices, sales, costs, and profits, and of showing that these
variables would have behaved differently without the overcharge.
Id. at
392 U. S.
492-493. [
Footnote
3] A second reason for barring the pass-on defense was the
Court's concern that unless direct purchasers were allowed to sue
for the portion of the overcharge arguably passed on to indirect
purchasers, antitrust violators "would retain the fruits of their
illegality"
Page 431 U. S. 726
because indirect purchasers "would have only a tiny stake in the
lawsuit," and hence little incentive to sue.
Id. at
431 U. S. 494.
In this case, we once again confront the question whether the
overcharged direct purchaser should be deemed for purposes of
§ 4 to have suffered the full injury from the overcharge; but
the issue is presented in the context of a suit in which the
plaintiff, an indirect purchaser, seeks to show its injury by
establishing pass-on by the direct purchaser and in which the
antitrust defendants rely on
Hanover Shoe's rejection of
the pass-on theory. Having decided that, in general, a pass-on
theory may not be used defensively by an antitrust violator against
a direct purchaser plaintiff, we must now decide whether that
theory may be used offensively by an indirect purchaser plaintiff
against an alleged violator.
I
Petitioners manufacture and distribute concrete block in the
Greater Chicago area. They sell the block primarily to masonry
contractors, who submit bids to general contractors for the masonry
portions of construction projects. The general contractors, in
turn, submit bids for these projects to customers such as the
respondents in this case, the State of Illinois and 700 local
governmental entities in the Greater Chicago area, including
counties, municipalities, housing authorities, and school
districts.
See 67 F.R.D. 461, 463 (ND Ill.1975); App.
16-48. Respondents are thus indirect purchasers of concrete block,
which passes through two separate levels in the chain of
distribution before reaching respondents. The block is purchased
directly from petitioners by masonry contractors and used by them
to build masonry structures; those structures are incorporated into
entire buildings by general contractors and sold to
respondents'
Respondent State of Illinois, on behalf of itself and respondent
local governmental entities, brought this antitrust treble damages
action under § 4 of the Clayton Act, alleging that
Page 431 U. S. 727
petitioners had engaged in a combination and conspiracy to fix
the prices of concrete block in violation of § 1 of the
Sherman Act. [
Footnote 4] The
complaint alleged that the amounts paid by respondents for concrete
block were more than $3 million higher by reason of this
price-fixing conspiracy. The only way in which the antitrust
violation alleged could have injured respondents is if all or part
of the overcharge was passed on by the masonry and general
contractors to respondents, rather than being absorbed at the first
two levels of distribution.
See Illinois v. Ampress Brick
Co., 536 F.2d 1163, 1164 (CA7 1976). [
Footnote 5]
Petitioner manufacturers moved for partial summary judgment
against all plaintiffs that were indirect purchasers of concrete
block from petitioners, contending that, as a matter of law, only
direct purchasers could sue for the alleged overcharge. [
Footnote 6] The District Court granted
petitioners' motion, but the Court of Appeals reversed, holding
that indirect purchasers such as respondents in this case can
recover treble damages for an illegal overcharge if they can prove
that the overcharge
Page 431 U. S. 728
was passed on to them through intervening links in the
distribution chain. [
Footnote
7]
We granted certiorari, 429 U.S. 938 (1976), to resolve a
conflict among the Courts of Appeals [
Footnote 8] on the question whether the offensive use of
pass-on authorized by the decision below is consistent with
Hanover Shoe's restrictions on the defensive use of
pass-on. We hold that it is not, and we reverse. We reach this
result in two steps. First, we conclude that, whatever rule is to
be adopted regarding pass-on in antitrust damages actions, it must
apply equally to plaintiffs and defendants. Because
Hanover
Shoe would bar petitioners from using respondents' pass-on
theory as a defense to a treble damages suit
Page 431 U. S. 729
by the direct purchasers (the masonry contractors), [
Footnote 9] we are faced with the
choice of overruling (or narrowly limiting)
Hanover Shoe
or of applying it to bar respondents' attempt to use this pass-on
theory offensively. Second, we decline to abandon the construction
given § 4 in
Hanover Shoe -- that the overcharged
direct purchaser, and not others in the chain of manufacture or
distribution, is the party "injured in his business or property"
within the meaning of the section -- in the absence of a convincing
demonstration that the Court was wrong in
Hanover Shoe to
think that the effectiveness of the antitrust treble damages action
would be substantially reduced by adopting a rule that any party in
the chain may sue to recover the fraction of the overcharge
allegedly absorbed by it.
II
The parties in this case agree that however § 4 is
construed with respect to the pass-on issue, the rule should apply
equally to plaintiffs and defendants -- that an indirect purchaser
should not be allowed to use a pass-on theory to recover damages
from a defendant unless the defendant would be allowed to use a
pass-on defense in a suit by a direct purchaser. Respondents, in
arguing that they should be allowed to recover by showing pass-on
in this case, have conceded that petitioners should be allowed to
assert a pass-on defense against direct purchasers of concrete
block, Tr. of Oral Arg. 33, 48; they ask this Court to limit
Hanover Shoe's bar on pass-on defenses to its "particular
factual context" of overcharges for capital goods used to
manufacture new products.
Id. at 41;
see id. at
36, 47-48.
Before turning to this request to limit
Hanover Shoe,
we consider the substantially contrary position, adopted by our
dissenting Brethren, by the United States as
amicus
curiae, and by lower courts that have allowed offensive use of
pass on, that the unavailability of a pass-on theory to a
defendant
Page 431 U. S. 730
should not necessarily preclude its use by plaintiffs seeking
treble damages against that defendant. [
Footnote 10] Under this view,
Hanover Shoe's
rejection of pass-on would continue to apply to defendants unless
direct and indirect purchasers were both suing the defendant in the
same action; but it would not bar indirect purchasers from
attempting to show that the overcharge had been passed on to them.
We reject this position for two reasons.
First, allowing offensive but not defensive use of pass-on would
create a serious risk of multiple liability for defendants. Even
though an indirect purchaser had already recovered for all or part
of an overcharge passed on to it, the direct purchaser would still
recover automatically the full amount of the overcharge that the
indirect purchaser had shown to be passed on; similarly, following
an automatic recovery of the full overcharge by the direct
purchaser, the indirect purchaser could sue to recover the same
amount. The risk of duplicative recoveries created by unequal
application of the
Hanover Shoe rule is much more
substantial than in the more usual situation where the defendant is
sued in two different lawsuits by plaintiffs asserting conflicting
claims to the same fund. A one-sided application of
Hanover
Shoe substantially increases the possibility of inconsistent
adjudications -- and therefore of unwarranted multiple liability
for the defendant -- by
presuming that one plaintiff (the
direct purchaser) is entitled to full recovery while preventing the
defendant from using that presumption against the other plaintiff;
overlapping recoveries are certain to result from the two
lawsuits
Page 431 U. S. 731
unless the indirect purchaser is unable to establish any pass-on
whatsoever. As in
Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of Cal.,
405 U. S. 251,
405 U. S. 264
(1972), we are unwilling to "open the door to duplicative
recoveries" under § 4. [
Footnote 11]
Second, the reasoning of
Hanover Shoe cannot justify
unequal treatment of plaintiffs and defendants with respect to the
permissibility of pass-on arguments. The principal basis for the
decision in
Hanover Shoe was the Court's perception of the
uncertainties and difficulties in analyzing price and output
Page 431 U. S. 732
decisions "in the real economic world, rather than an
economist's hypothetical model," 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493,
and of the costs to the judicial system and the efficient
enforcement of the antitrust laws of attempting to reconstruct
those decisions in the courtroom. [
Footnote 12] This perception that the attempt to trace
the complex economic adjustments to a change in the cost of a
particular factor of production would greatly complicate and reduce
the effectiveness of already protracted treble damages proceedings
applies with no less force to the assertion of pass-on theories by
plaintiffs than it does to the assertion by defendants. However
"long and complicated" the proceedings would be when defendants
sought to prove pass-on,
ibid., they would be equally so
when the same evidence was introduced by plaintiffs. Indeed, the
evidentiary complexities and uncertainties involved in the
defensive use of pass-on against a direct purchaser are multiplied
in the offensive use of pass-on by a plaintiff several steps
removed from the defendant in the chain of distribution. The
demonstration of how much of the overcharge was passed on by the
first purchaser must be repeated at each point at which
Page 431 U. S. 733
the price-fixed goods changed hands before they reached the
plaintiff. [
Footnote 13]
It is argued, however, that
Hanover Shoe rests on a
policy of ensuring that a treble damages plaintiff is available to
deprive antitrust violators of "the fruits of their illegality,"
id. at
392 U. S. 494,
a policy that would be furthered by allowing plaintiffs, but not
defendants, to use pass-on theories.
See, e.g., In re Western
Liquid Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d 191, 197 (CA9 1973),
cert.
denied sub nom. Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. Alaska, 415 U.S.
919 (1974); Brief for United States as
Amicus Curiae 6,
113, 17-19. [
Footnote 14] We
do not read the Court's
Page 431 U. S. 734
concern in
Hanover Shoe for the effectiveness of the
treble damages remedy as countenancing unequal application of the
Court's pass-on rule. Rather, we understand
Hanover
Shoe
Page 431 U. S. 735
as resting on the judgment that the antitrust laws will be more
effectively enforced by concentrating the full recovery for the
overcharge in the direct purchasers, rather than by allowing every
plaintiff potentially affected by the overcharge to sue only for
the amount it could show was absorbed by it.
We thus decline to construe § 4 to permit offensive use of
a pass-on theory against an alleged violator that could not use the
same theory as a defense in an action by direct purchasers. In this
case, respondents seek to demonstrate that masonry contractors, who
incorporated petitioners' block into walls and other masonry
structures, passed on the alleged overcharge on the block to
general contractors, who incorporated the masonry structures into
entire buildings, and that the general contractors, in turn, passed
on the overcharge to respondents in the bids submitted for those
buildings. We think it clear that, under a fair reading of
Hanover Shoe, petitioners would be barred from asserting
this theory in a suit by the masonry contractors.
In
Hanover Shoe, this Court did not endorse the broad
exception that had been recognized in that case by the courts below
-- permitting the pass-on defense against middlemen who did not
alter the goods they purchased before reselling them. [
Footnote 15] The masonry contractors
here could not be included under this exception in any event,
because they transform the concrete block purchased from defendants
into the masonry portions of buildings. But this Court, in
Hanover Shoe,
Page 431 U. S. 736
indicated the narrow scope it intended for any exception to its
rule barring pass-on defenses by citing, as the only example of a
situation where the defense might be permitted, a preexisting
cost-plus contract. In such a situation, the purchaser is insulated
from any decrease in its sales as a result of attempting to pass on
the overcharge, because its customer is committed to buying a fixed
quantity regardless of price. The effect of the overcharge is
essentially determined in advance, without reference to the
interaction of supply and demand that complicates the determination
in the general case. The competitive bidding process by which the
concrete block involved in this case was incorporated into masonry
structures and then into entire buildings can hardly be said to
circumvent complex market interactions as would a cost-plus
contract. [
Footnote 16]
We are left, then, with two alternatives: either we must
overrule
Hanover Shoe (or at least narrowly confine it to
its facts), or we must preclude respondents from seeking to recover
on their pass-on theory. We choose the latter course.
III
In considering whether to cut back or abandon the
Hanover
Shoe rule, we must bear in mind that considerations of
stare decisis weigh heavily in the area of statutory
construction, where Congress is free to change this Court's
interpretation of its legislation.
See Edelman v. Jordan,
415 U. S. 651,
415 U. S. 671
(1974);
Burnet v. Coronado Oil & Gas Co., 285 U.
S. 393,
285 U. S.
406-408 (1932) (Brandeis, J., dissenting). This
presumption of adherence to our prior decisions construing
legislative enactments would support our reaffirmance of the
Hanover Shoe
Page 431 U. S. 737
construction of § 4, joined by eight Justices without
dissent only a few years ago, [
Footnote 17] even if the Court were persuaded that the
use of pass-on theories by plaintiffs and defendants in treble
damages actions is more consistent with the policies underlying the
treble damages action than is the
Hanover Shoe rule. But
we are not so persuaded.
Permitting the use of pass-on theories under § 4
essentially would transform treble damages actions into massive
efforts to apportion the recovery among all potential plaintiffs
that could have absorbed part of the overcharge -- from direct
purchasers to middlemen to ultimate consumers. However appealing
this attempt to allocate the overcharge might seem in theory, it
would add whole new dimensions of complexity to treble damages
suits, and seriously undermine their effectiveness.
As we have indicated, potential plaintiffs at each level in the
distribution chain are in a position to assert conflicting claims
to a common fund -- the amount of the alleged overcharge -- by
contending that the entire overcharge was absorbed at that
particular level in the chain. [
Footnote 18] A treble damages action brought by one of
these potential plaintiffs (or one class of potential plaintiffs)
to recover the overcharge implicates all three of the interests
that have traditionally been thought to support compulsory joinder
of absent and potentially adverse claimants: the interest of the
defendant in
Page 431 U. S. 738
avoiding multiple liability for the fund; the interest of the
absent potential plaintiffs in protecting their right to recover
for the portion of the fund allocable to them; and the social
interest in the efficient administration of justice and the
avoidance of multiple litigation. Reed, Compulsory Joinder of
Parties in Civil Actions, 55 Mich.L.Rev. 327, 330 (1957).
See
Provident Tradesmens Bank & Trust Co. v. Patterson,
390 U. S. 102,
390 U. S.
110-111 (1968); 7 C. Wright & A. Miller, Federal
Practice and Procedure § 1602 (1972).
Opponents of the
Hanover Shoe rule have recognized this
need for compulsory joinder in suggesting that the defendant could
interplead potential claimants under 28 U.S.C. § 1335.
[
Footnote 19] But if the
defendant, for any of a variety of reasons, [
Footnote 20] does not choose to interplead the
absent potential claimants, there would be a strong argument for
joining them as "persons needed for just adjudication" under
Fed.Rule Civ.Proc.19(a). [
Footnote 21]
See Comment, Standing to Sue in
Antitrust Cases:
Page 431 U. S. 739
The Offensive Use of Passing-On, 123 U.Pa.L.Rev. 976, 998
(1975). These absent potential claimants would seem to fit the
classic definition of "necessary parties," for purposes of
compulsory joinder, given in
Shield v.
Barrow, 17 How. 130,
58 U. S. 139
(1855):
"Persons having an interest in the controversy, and who ought to
be made parties, in order that the court may act on that rule which
requires it to decide on, and finally determine the entire
controversy, and do complete justice, by adjusting all the rights
involved in it."
See Notes of Advisory Committee on 1966 Amendment to
Rule 19, 8 U.S.C.App. p. 7760; 7 C. Wright & A. Miller,
supra, §§ 1604, 1618; 3A J. Moore, Federal
Practice 19.08 (1974). The plaintiff bringing the treble damages
action would be required, under Fed.Rule Civ.Proc.19(c), to "state
the names, if known," of these absent potential claimants; they
should also be notified by some means that the action was pending.
[
Footnote 22] Where, as
would often be the case, the potential claimants at a particular
level of distribution are so numerous that joinder of all is
impracticable, a representative presumably would have to be found
to bring them into the action as a class.
See Fed.Rule
Civ.Proc.19(d); 3A J. Moore,
supra, � 19.21.
It is unlikely, of course, that all potential plaintiffs could
or would be joined. Some may not wish to assert claims to the
Page 431 U. S. 740
overcharge; others may be unmanageable as a class; and still
others may be beyond the personal jurisdiction of the court. We can
assume that ordinarily the action would still proceed, the absent
parties not being deemed "indispensable" under Fed.Rule
Civ.Proc.19(b).
See Provident Tradesmens Bank & Trust Co.
v. Patterson, supra. But allowing indirect purchasers to
recover using pass-on theories, even under the optimistic
assumption that joinder of potential plaintiffs will deal
satisfactorily with problems of multiple litigation and liability,
would transform treble damages actions into massive multiparty
litigations involving many levels of distribution and including
large classes of ultimate consumers remote from the defendant. In
treble damages actions by ultimate consumers, the overcharge would
have to be apportioned among the relevant wholesalers, retailers,
and other middlemen, whose representatives presumably should be
joined. [
Footnote 23] And in
suits
Page 431 U. S. 741
by direct purchasers or middlemen, the interests of ultimate
consumers are similarly implicated. [
Footnote 24]
There is thus a strong possibility that indirect purchasers
remote from the defendant would be parties to virtually every
treble damages action (apart from those brought against defendants
at the retail level). The Court's concern in
Hanover Shoe
to avoid weighing down treble damages actions with the "massive
evidence and complicated theories," 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493,
involved in attempting to establish a pass-on defense against a
direct purchaser applies
a fortiori to the attempt to
trace the effect of the overcharge through each step in the
distribution chain from the direct purchaser to the ultimate
consumer. We are no more inclined than we were in
Hanover
Shoe to ignore the burdens that such an attempt would impose
on the effective enforcement of the antitrust laws.
Under an array of simplifying assumptions, economic theory
provides a precise formula for calculating how the overcharge is
distributed between the overcharged party (passer) and its
customers (passees).
If the market for the passer's
product is perfectly competitive;
if the overcharge is
imposed equally on all of the passer's competitors; and
if
the passer maximizes its profits, then the ratio of the shares of
the overcharge borne by passee and passer will equal the ratio of
the elasticities of supply and demand in the market for the
passer's product. [
Footnote
25]
Page 431 U. S. 742
Even if these assumptions are accepted, there remains a serious
problem of measuring the relevant elasticities -- the percentage
change in the quantities of the passer's product demanded and
supplied in response to a one percent change in price. In view of
the difficulties that have been encountered, even in informal
adversary proceedings, with the statistical techniques used to
estimate these concepts,
see Finkelstein, Regression
Models in Administrative Proceedings, 86 Harv.L.Rev. 1442, 1444
(1973), it is unrealistic to think that elasticity studies
introduced by expert witnesses will resolve the pass-on issue. We
need look no further than our own difficulties with sophisticated
statistical methodology that were evident last Term in
Gregg v.
Georgia, 428 U. S. 153
(1976), and its companion cases.
See id. at
428 U. S.
184-185 (joint opinion of STEWART, POWELL, and STEVENS,
JJ.);
428 U. S.
233-236 (MARSHALL, J., dissenting);
Roberts v.
Louisiana, 428 U. S. 325,
428 U. S.
354-355 (1976) (WHITE, J., dissenting).
More important, as the
Hanover Shoe Court observed, 392
U.S. at
392 U. S. 493,
"in the real economic world, rather than an economist's
hypothetical model," the latter's drastic simplifications generally
must be abandoned. Overcharged direct purchasers often sell in
imperfectly competitive markets. They often compete with other
sellers that have not been subject to the overcharge; and their
pricing policies often cannot be explained solely by the convenient
assumption of profit maximization. [
Footnote 26] As we concluded in
Hanover Shoe,
392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
492,
Page 431 U. S. 743
attention to "sound laws of economics" can only heighten the
awareness of the difficulties and uncertainties involved in
determining how the relevant market variables would have behaved
had there been no overcharge. [
Footnote 27]
It is quite true that these difficulties and uncertainties will
be less substantial in some contexts than in others. There have
been many proposals to allow pass-on theories in some of these
contexts while preserving the
Hanover Shoe rule in others.
Respondents here argue, not without support from some lower courts,
[
Footnote 28] that pass-on
theories should be permitted for middlemen that resell goods
without altering them and for contractors that add a fixed
percentage markup to the cost of their materials in submitting
bids. Brief for Respondents 9-30; Tr. of Oral Arg. 36 48.
Exceptions to the
Hanover Shoe rule have also been urged
for other situations in which most of the overcharge is purportedly
passed on -- for example, where a price-fixed good is a small but
vital input into a
Page 431 U. S. 744
much larger product, making the demand for the price-fixed good
highly inelastic.
Compare Philadelphia Housing Auth. v.
American Radiator & Standard Sanitary Corp., 50 F.R.D. 13
(ED Pa.1970),
aff'd sub nom. Mangano v. American Radiator &
Standard Sanitary Corp., 438 F.2d 1187 (CA3 1971),
with In
re Master Key Antitrust Litigation, 1972 Trade Cas. �
74,680 (Conn.).
See Schaefer, supra, n 25, at 918-925.
We reject these attempts to carve out exceptions to the
Hanover Shoe rule for particular types of markets.
[
Footnote 29] An exception
allowing evidence of pass-on by middlemen that resell the goods
they purchase of course would be of no avail to respondents,
because the contractors that allegedly passed on the overcharge on
the block incorporated it into buildings.
See supra at
431 U. S. 735.
An exception for the contractors here on the ground that they
purport to charge a fixed percentage above their costs would
substantially erode the
Hanover Shoe rule without
justification. Firms in many sectors of the economy rely to an
extent on cost-based rules of thumb in setting prices.
See
F. Scherer, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance
176-179 (1970). These rules are not adhered to rigidly, however;
the extent of the markup (or the allocation of costs) is varied to
reflect demand conditions.
Id. at 176-177. The intricacies
of tracing the effect of an overcharge on the purchaser's prices,
costs, sales, and profits thus are not spared the litigants.
More generally, the process of classifying various market
situations according to the amount of pass-on likely to be
Page 431 U. S. 745
involved and its susceptibility of proof in a judicial forum
would entail the very problems that the
Hanover Shoe rule
was meant to avoid. The litigation over where the line should be
drawn in a particular class of cases would inject the same "massive
evidence and complicated theories" into treble damages proceedings,
albeit at a somewhat higher level of generality. As we have noted,
supra at
431 U. S.
735-736,
Hanover Shoe itself implicitly
discouraged the creation of exceptions to its rule barring pass-on
defenses, and we adhere to the narrow scope of exemption indicated
by our decision there.
The concern in
Hanover Shoe for the complexity that
would be introduced into treble damages suits if pass-on theories
were permitted was closely related to the Court's concern for the
reduction in the effectiveness of those suits if brought by
indirect purchasers with a smaller stake in the outcome than that
of direct purchasers suing for the full amount of the overcharge.
The apportionment of the recovery throughout the distribution chain
would increase the overall costs of recovery by injecting extremely
complex issues into the case; at the same time, such an
apportionment would reduce the benefits to each plaintiff by
dividing the potential recovery among a much larger group. Added to
the uncertainty of how much of an overcharge could be established
at trial would be the uncertainty of how that overcharge would be
apportioned among the various plaintiffs. This additional
uncertainty would further reduce the incentive to sue. The
combination of increasing the costs and diffusing the benefits of
bringing a treble damages action could seriously impair this
important weapon of antitrust enforcement.
We think the longstanding policy of encouraging vigorous private
enforcement of the antitrust laws,
see, e.g, Perma Life
Mufflers, Inc. v. International Parts Corp., 392 U.
S. 134,
392 U. S. 139
(1968), supports our adherence to the
Hanover Shoe rule,
under which direct purchasers are not only spared the burden
Page 431 U. S. 746
of litigating the intricacies of pass-on, but also are permitted
to recover the full amount of the overcharge. We recognize that
direct purchasers sometimes may refrain from bringing a treble
damages suit for fear of disrupting relations with their suppliers.
[
Footnote 30] But on
balance, and until there are clear directions from Congress to the
contrary, we conclude that the legislative purpose in creating a
group of "
private attorneys general'" to enforce the antitrust
laws under § 4, Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of Cal.,
405 U.S. at 405 U. S. 262,
is better served by holding direct purchasers to be injured to the
full extent of the overcharge paid by them than by attempting to
apportion the overcharge among all that may have absorbed a part of
it.
It is true that, in elevating direct purchasers to a preferred
position as private attorneys general, the
Hanover Shoe
rule denies recovery to those indirect purchasers who may have been
actually injured by antitrust violations. Of course, as MR. JUSTICE
BRENNAN points out in dissent, "from the deterrence standpoint, it
is irrelevant to whom damages are paid, so long as some one
redresses the violation."
Post at
431 U. S. 760.
But § 4 has another purpose in addition to deterring violators
and depriving them of "the fruits of their illegality,"
Hanover
Shoe, 392 U. at
392 U. S. 494;
it is also designed to compensate victims of antitrust violations
for their injuries.
E.g., Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat,
Inc., 429 U. S. 477,
429 U. S.
485-486 (1977).
Hanover Shoe does further the
goal of compensation to the extent that the direct purchaser
absorbs at least some, and often most, of the overcharge. In view
of the considerations supporting the
Hanover Shoe rule, we
are unwilling to carry the compensation principle to its logical
extreme by attempting to allocate damages among all "those within
the defendant's chain of distribution,"
post at
431 U. S. 761,
especially
Page 431 U. S. 747
because we question the extent to which such an attempt would
make individual victims whole for actual injuries suffered, rather
than simply depleting the overall recovery in litigation over
pass-on issues. Many of the indirect purchasers barred from
asserting pass-on claims under the
Hanover Shoe rule have
such a small stake in the lawsuit that even if they were to recover
as part of a class, only a small fraction would be likely to come
forward to collect their damages. [
Footnote 31] And given the difficulty of ascertaining the
amount absorbed by any particular indirect purchaser, there is
little basis for believing that the amount of the recovery would
reflect the actual injury suffered.
Page 431 U. S. 748
For the reasons stated, the judgment is reversed, and the case
is remanded for further proceedings consistent with this
opinion.
So ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 731, 15 U.S.C. § 15,
provides:
"Any person who shall be injured in his business or property by
reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue therefor
in any district court of the United States in the district in which
the defendant resides or is found or has an agent, without respect
to the amount in controversy, and shall recover threefold the
damages by him sustained, and the cost of suit, including a
reasonable attorney's fee."
[
Footnote 2]
The Court cited, as an example of when a pass-on defense might
be permitted, the situation where "an overcharged buyer has a
preexisting "cost-plus" contract, thus making it easy to prove that
he has not been damaged. . . ." 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 494.
See infra at
431 U. S.
735-736.
[
Footnote 3]
The Court explained the economic uncertainties and complexities
involved in proving pass-on as follows:
"A wide range of factors influence a company's pricing policies.
Normally the impact of a single change in the relevant conditions
cannot be measured after the fact; indeed a businessman may be
unable to state whether, had one fact ben different (a single
supply less expensive, general economic conditions more buoyant, or
the labor market tighter, for example), he would have chosen a
different price. Equally difficult to determine, in the real
economic world rather than an economist's hypothetical model, is
what effect a change in a company's price will have on its total
sales. Finally, costs per unit for a different volume of total
sales are hard to estimate. Even if it could be shown that the
buyer raised his price in response to, and in the amount of, the
overcharge and that his margin of profit and total sales had not
thereafter declined, there would remain the nearly insuperable
difficulty of demonstrating that the particular plaintiff could not
or would not have raised his prices absent the overcharge or
maintained the higher price had the overcharge been discontinued.
Since establishing the applicability of the passing-on defense
would require a convincing showing of each of these virtually
unascertainable figures, the task would normally prove
insurmountable. On the other hand, it is not unlikely that, if the
existence of the defense is generally confirmed, antitrust
defendants will frequently seek to establish its applicability.
Treble damage actions would often require additional long and
complicated proceedings involving massive evidence and complicated
theories."
392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
492-493. (Footnote omitted.)
[
Footnote 4]
Section 1 of the Sherman Act, c. 647, 26 Stat. 209, as amended,
15 U.S.C. § 1, provides in relevant part:
"Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise,
or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
States, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to be illegal.
. . ."
[
Footnote 5]
Private treble damages actions brought by masonry contractors,
general contractors, and private builders were settled, without
prejudice to this suit. 536 F.2d at 1164.
[
Footnote 6]
The responses to petitioners' interrogatories indicated that
only four of the plaintiffs represented by the State purchased
concrete block directly from one of the petitioners. 67 F.R.D. 461,
463 (ND Ill.1975). Only 7% of the 700 public entities named as
plaintiffs were apparently able to state the cost of the concrete
block used in their building projects. Brief for Petitioners 5 n.
**. In the only example cited to us by the parties, the cost of the
concrete block was reported as less than one-half of one percent of
the total cost of the project.
Id. at 21 n. *.
[
Footnote 7]
The District Court based its grant of summary judgment against
the indirect purchaser plaintiffs not on the ground that this
Court's construction of § 4 in
Hanover Shoe barred
their attempt to show that the masonry and general contractors
passed on the overcharge to them, but rather on the ground that
these indirect purchasers lacked standing to sue for an overcharge
on one product -- concrete block -- that was incorporated by the
masonry and general contractors into an entirely new and different
product -- a building. 67 F.R.D. at 467-468. Although the Court of
Appeals held that these indirect purchasers did have standing to
sue for damages under § 4, it agreed with the District Court's
reading of
Hanover Shoe. 536 F.2d at 1164-1167. Because we
find
Hanover Shoe dispositive here, we do not address the
standing issue, except to note, as did the Court of Appeals below,
536 F.2d at 1166, that the question of which persons have been
injured by an illegal overcharge for purposes of § 4 is
analytically distinct from the question of which persons have
sustained injuries too remote to give them standing to sue for
damages under § 4.
See Handler & Blechman,
Antitrust and the Consumer Interest: The Fallacy of
Parens
Patriae and A Suggested New Approach, 85 Yale L.J. 626,
644-645 (1976).
[
Footnote 8]
Compare Mangano v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary
Corp., 438 F.2d 1187 (CA3 1971),
aff'g Philadelphia
Housing Auth. v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary
Corp., 50 F.R.D. 13 (ED Pa.1970),
with In re Western
Liquid Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d 191 (CA9 1973),
cert.
denied sub nom. Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. Alaska, 415 U.S.
919 (1974);
West Virginia v. Chas. Pfizer & Co., 440
F.2d 1079 (CA2),
cert. denied sub nom. Cotler Drugs, Inc. v.
Chas. Pfizer & Co., 404 U.S. 871 (1971),
and the
decision below,
Illinois v. Ampress Brick Co., 536 F.2d
1163.
[
Footnote 9]
See infra at
431 U. S.
734-735
[
Footnote 10]
Post at
431 U. S. 753
(BRENNAN, J., dissenting);
post at
431 U. S.
765-766 (BLACKMUN, J., dissenting); Brief for United
States as
Amicus Curiae 4-6, 15-21; Tr. of Oral Arg.
50-54, 57-60;
West Virginia v. Chas. Pfizer & Co., 440
F.2d at 1086-1088;
Boshes v. General Motors Corp., 59
F.R.D. 589, 592-598 (ND Ill.1973);
In re Master Key Antitrust
Litigation, 1973-2 Trade Cas. � 74,680, p. 94,978
(Conn.);
Carnivale Bag Co. v. Slide-Rite Mfg.
Corp., 395 F.
Supp. 287, 290-291 (SDNY 1975).
See also Brief for
State of California as
Amicus Curiae 6-12.
[
Footnote 11]
In recognition of the need to avoid duplicative recoveries,
courts adopting the view that pass-on theories should not be
equally available to plaintiffs and defendants have agreed that
defendants should be allowed to assert a pass-on defense against a
direct purchaser if an indirect purchaser is also attempting to
recover on a pass-on theory
in the same lawsuit. E.g.,
In re Western Liquid Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d at 200-201;
West Virginia v. Chas. Pfizer & Co., 440 F.2d at 1088.
See also Comment, Standing to Sue in Antitrust Cases: The
Offensive Use of Passing-On, 123 U.Pa.L.Rev. 976, 995-998 (1975);
Comment,
Mangano and Ultimate-Consumer Standing: The
Misuse of the
Hanover Doctrine, 72 Colum.L.Rev. 394, 410
(1972); Brief for United States as
Amicus Curiae 25.
Various procedural devices, such as the Multidistrict Litigation
Act, 28 U.S.C. § 1407, and statutory interpleader, 28 U.S.C.
§ 1335, are relied upon to bring indirect and direct
purchasers together in one action in order to apportion damages
among them and thereby reduce the risk of duplicative recovery.
These procedural devices cannot protect against multiple liability
where the direct purchasers have already recovered by obtaining a
judgment or by settling, as is more likely (and as occurred here,
see n 5,
supra); acknowledging that the risk of multiple recoveries
is inevitably increased by allowing offensive but not defensive use
of pass-on,
e.g., Comment, 123 U.Pa.L.Rev.
supra
at 994, proponents of this approach ultimately fall back on the
argument that it is better for the defendant to pay six-fold or
more damages than for an injured party to go uncompensated.
E.g., Comment, 72 Colum.L.Rev.
supra at 411; Tr.
of Oral Arg. 58 ("a little slopover on the shoulders of the
wrongdoers . . . is acceptable"). We do not find this risk
acceptable.
Moreover, even if ways could be found to bring all potential
plaintiffs together in one huge action, the complexity thereby
introduced into treble damages proceedings argues strongly for
retaining the
Hanover Shoe rule.
See 431 U.
S. infra.
[
Footnote 12]
That this rationale was more important in the decision to bar
the pass-on defense than the second reason -- the concern that, if
pass-on defenses were permitted, indirect purchasers would lack the
incentive to sue and antitrust violators would retain their
ill-gotten gains,
see supra at
431 U. S.
725-726, is shown by the fact that the Court recognized
an exception for preexisting cost-plus contracts, which "mak[e] it
easy to prove that [the direct purchaser] has not been
damaged." 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 494.
(Emphasis added.) The amount of the stake that the customers of the
direct purchaser have in a lawsuit against the overcharger is not
likely to depend on whether they buy under a cost-plus contract or
in a competitive market, but the Court allowed a pass-on defense in
the former situation because the preexisting cost-plus contract
makes easy the normally complicated task of demonstrating that the
overcharge has not been absorbed by the direct purchaser.
See Note, The Effect of
Hanover Shoe on the
Offensive Use of the Passing-on Doctrine, 46 So.Cal.L.Rev. 98, 108
(1972).
[
Footnote 13]
Offensive use of pass-on by the last purchaser in the
distribution chain is simpler in one respect than defensive use of
pass-on against a direct purchaser that sells a product to other
customers. In the latter case, even if the defendant shows that, as
a result of the overcharge, the direct purchaser increased its
price by the full amount of the overcharge, the direct purchaser
may still claim injury from a reduction in the volume of its sales
caused by its higher prices. This additional element of injury from
reduced volume is not present in the suit by the final purchaser of
the overcharged goods, where the issue regarding injury will be
whether the defendant's overcharge caused the plaintiff to pay a
higher price for whatever it purchased. But the final purchaser
still will have to trace the overcharge through each step in the
distribution chain. In our view, the difficulty of reconstructing
the pricing decisions of intermediate purchasers at each step in
the chain beyond the direct purchaser generally will outweigh any
gain in simplicity from not having to litigate the effects of the
passed-on overcharge on the direct purchaser's volume.
[
Footnote 14]
We are urged to defer to evidence in the legislative history of
the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of 1976, 90 Stat.
1394-1396, 15 U.S.C. § 15c
et seq. (1976 ed.), that
Congress understood
Hanover Shoe as applying only to
defendants.
Post at
431 U. S.
756-758 (BRENNAN, J., dissenting); Brief for 47 States
as
Amici Curiae 14-15, n. 6; Brief for United States as
Amicus Curiae 14-15, and n. 12. The House Report
(apparently viewing the issue as one of standing,
cf.
n 7,
supra) endorsed
the Ninth Circuit's view of "the pro-enforcement thrust of
Hanover Shoe" in
In re Western Liquid Asphalt Cases,
supra, and criticized lower court decisions barring pass-on
arguments by plaintiffs. H.R.Rep. No. 94-499, p. 6 n. 4 (1975). In
addition, one of the sponsors of this legislation, Representative
Rodino, clearly assumed that the issue of offensive use of pass-on
under § 4 would be resolved favorably to plaintiffs by this
Court.
See 122 Cong.Rec. H10295 (daily ed., Sept. 16,
1976).
Congress made clear, however, that this legislation did not
alter the definition of which overcharged persons were injured
within the meaning of § 4. It simply created a new procedural
device --
parens patriae actions by States on behalf of
their citizens -- to enforce existing rights of recovery under
§ 4. The House Report quoted above stated that the
parens
patriae provision "creates no new substantive liability"; the
relevant language of the newly enacted § 4C(a) of the Clayton
Act tracks that of existing § 4, showing that it was intended
only as "an alternative means . . . for the vindication of existing
substantive claims." H.R.Rep. No. 94-499,
supra at 9. "The
establishment of an alternative remedy does not increase any
defendant's liability."
Ibid. Representative Rodino
himself acknowledged in the remarks cited above that this
legislation did not create a right of recovery for consumers where
one did not already exist.
We thus cannot agree with the dissenters that the legislative
history of the 1976 Antitrust Improvements Act is dispositive as to
the interpretation of § 4 of the Clayton Act, enacted in 1914,
or the predecessor section of the Sherman Act, enacted in 1890.
Post at
431 U. S.
756-758. The cases cited by MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN,
post at
431 U. S. 765
n. 24, to support his reliance on this legislation all involved
specific statutory language that was thought to clarify the meaning
of an earlier statute.
E.g., Red Lion Broadcasting Co. v.
FCC, 395 U. S. 367,
395 U. S.
380-381 (1969) (language in 1959 amendment to § 315
of the Communications Act approved fairness doctrine adopted by FCC
under the "public interest" standard of the original Act). Here, by
contrast, Congress borrowed the language of § 4 in adding the
parens patriae section. The views expressed by particular
legislators as to the meaning of that language in § 4 "cannot
serve to change the legislative intent of Congress . . .
since
the statements were [made] after passage of the [Clayton] Act.'"
Regional Rail Reorganization Act Cases, 419 U.
S. 102, 419 U. S. 132
(1974), quoting National Woodwork Mfrs. Assn. v. NLRB,
386 U. S. 612,
386 U. S. 639
n. 34 (1967).
While we do not lightly disagree with the reading of
Hanover
Shoe urged by these legislators, we think the construction of
§ 4 adopted in that decision cannot be applied for the
exclusive benefit of plaintiffs. Should Congress disagree with this
result, it may, of course, amend the section to change it. But it
has not done so in the recent
parens patriae
legislation.
[
Footnote 15]
In a separate trial pursuant to Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 42(b), the
District Court held that the defendant shoe machinery manufacturer
was not permitted to assert a pass-on defense against its customer.
185 F.
Supp. 826 (MD Pa.),
aff'd, 281 F.2d 481 (CA3),
cert. denied, 364 U.S. 901 (1960). The District Court
indicated that pass-on defenses were barred against "consumers" who
use the defendant's product to make their own but not against
"middlemen" who simply resell the defendant's product. 185 F. Supp.
at 830-831. Both on interlocutory appeal and after trial on the
merits, the Court of Appeals affirmed on the basis of the District
Court's reasoning.
See 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 488
n. 6.
[
Footnote 16]
Another situation in which market forces have been superseded
and the pass-on defense might be permitted is where the direct
purchaser is owned or controlled by its customer.
Cf. Perkins
v. Standard Oil Co., 395 U. S. 642,
395 U. S. 648
(1969);
In re Western Liquid Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d at
197, 199.
[
Footnote 17]
The sole dissenting Justice in
Hanover Shoe did not
reach the pass on question. 392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
513.
[
Footnote 18]
In this Part, we assume that use of pass-on will be permitted
symmetrically; if at all. This assumption, of course, reduces the
substantial risk of multiple liability for defendants that is posed
by allowing indirect purchasers to recover for the overcharge
passed on to them while at the same time allowing direct purchasers
automatically to collect the entire overcharge.
See supra
at
431 U. S.
730-731. But the possibility of inconsistent judgments
obtained by conflicting claimants remains nonetheless. Even this
residual possibility justifies bringing potential and actual
claimants together in one action if possible.
[
Footnote 19]
See n 11,
supra. Interpleader under Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 22(1) often
would be unavailable, because service of process for rule
interpleader, as contrasted with statutory interpleader, does not
run nationwide.
See 3A J. Moore, Federal Practice �
22.04[2] (1974).
[
Footnote 20]
For example, a condition precedent for invoking statutory
interpleader is the posting of a bond for the amount in dispute, 28
U.S.C. § 1336(a)(2),
see 3A J. Moore,
supra,
� 22.10, and a defendant may be unwilling to put up a bond
for the huge amounts normally claimed in multiple-party treble
damage suits. For a discussion of other circumsnces in which
statutory interpleader may be "impractical,"
see McGuire,
The Passing-On Defense and the Right of Remote Purchasers to
Recover Treble Damages under
Hanover Shoe, 33
U.Pltt.L.Rev. 177, 197-198 (1971).
[
Footnote 21]
Rule 19(a) provides in part:
"A person who is subject to service of process and whose joinder
will not deprive the court of jurisdiction over the subject matter
of the action shall be joined as a party in the action if (1) in
his absence, complete relief cannot be accorded among those already
parties, or (2) he claims an interest relating to the subject of
the action, and is so situated that the disposition of the action
in his absence may (i) as a practical matter impair or impede his
ability to protect that interest or (ii) leave any of the persons
already parties subject to a substantial risk of incurring double,
multiple, or otherwise inconsistent obligations by reason of his
claimed interest."
[
Footnote 22]
See the comment of the Advisory Committee on the 1966
Amendment to Rule 19:
"In some situations, it may be desirable to advise a person who
has not been joined of the fact that the action is pending, and, in
particular cases, the court, in its discretion, may itself convey
this information by directing a letter or other informal notice to
the absentee."
28 U.S.C. App. p. 7760.
[
Footnote 23]
E.g., Philadelphia Housing Auth. v. American Radiator &
Standard Sanitary Corp., 50 F.R.D. 13 (ED Pa.1970),
aff'd
sub nom. Mangano v. American Radiator & Standard Sanitary
Corp., 438 F.2d 1187 (CA3 1971) (suit against manufacturers of
plumbing fixtures on behalf of all homeowners in the United
States). There often will be more levels of distribution or
manufacture between the defendant and the ultimate consumers than
the two levels (masonry and general contractors) in this case. For
example, in
Philadelphia Housing Auth., supra, the
plaintiffs included homeowners who had bought used, rather than
new, homes, and who therefore had to show that, each time their
houses changed hands, the sellers passed on part of the plumbing
manufacturers' original overcharge. 50 F.R.D. at 19-20, 25-26.
,Treble damages suits by ultimate consumers against any of the
manufacturers of industrial raw materials or equipment that have
been charged in recent Government price-fixing suits would involve
not only several levels within a distribution chain, but also
several separate chains of distribution; for example, chromite sand
is used to make ingots, ingots are used to make steel, and steel is
used to make consumer products. Handler & Blechman,
supra, n 7, at 640 n.
77, and
see id. at 636-637 (citing Justice Department
price-fixing suits against defendants far removed from
consumers).
[
Footnote 24]
E.g., Donson Stores, Inc. v. American Bakeries Co., 58
F.R.D. 481 (SDNY 1973) (motion to intervene by a putative class of
20 million consumers of bread in treble damages action against
bread manufacturers).
Cf. Handler & Blechman,
supra, n 7, at 653
(arguing that the effect of legislation authorizing States to bring
treble damages actions on behalf of their citizens,
see
n 14,
supra, will
be to intereject claims on behalf of large classes of consumers
into treble damages suits brought by middlemen). Thus, in this
case, the plaintiff housing authorities, App. 20, presumably have
passed on part of the alleged overcharge to their tenants and
subtenants, who would have to be brought into the suit before
damages could be fairly apportioned.
[
Footnote 25]
An overcharge imposed by an antitrust violator or group of
violators on their customers is analytically equivalent to an
excise tax imposed on the violator's product in the amount of the
overcharge. The effect of such an overcharge can be calculated
using the economic theorems for the incidence of an excise tax.
See Schaefer, Passing-On Theory in Antitrust Treble Damage
Actions: An Economic and Legal Analysis, 16 Wm. & Mary L.Rev.
883, 887, 893 (1975), and sources cited in
id. at 887 n.
21.
[
Footnote 26]
Thus, in the instant case respondents have offered to prove that
general and masonry contractors calculate their bids by adding a
percentage markup to the cost of their materials, Brief for
Respondents 223, rather than by attempting to equate marginal cost
and marginal revenue as required by an explicit profit-maximizing
strategy.
[
Footnote 27]
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN, in dissent, argues that estimating a
passee's damages requires nothing more than estimating what the
passer's price would have been absent the violation, and suggests
that apportioning the overcharge throughout the distribution chain
is "no different from and no more complicated" than the initial
task of estimating the amount of the overcharge itself.
Post at
431 U. S.
758-759, and n. 14. But as the dissent recognizes,
post at
431 U. S. 749
n. 3, unless the indirect purchaser is at the end of the
distribution chain, it can claim damages not only from the portion
of the overcharge it absorbs but also from the portion it passes
on, which causes a reduction in sales volume under less than
perfectly inelastic demand conditions.
See n 13,
supra. The difficulties of
the task urged upon us by the dissenters cannot be so easily
brushed aside.
In any event, as we understand the dissenters' argument, it
reduces to the proposition that, because antitrust cases are
already complicated, there is little harm in making them more so.
We disagree.
[
Footnote 28]
See, e.g., West Virginia v. Chas. Pfizer &
Co., 314 F.
Supp. 710, 745-746 (SDNY 1970),
aff'd, 440 F.2d 1079
(CA2 1971);
Boshes v. General Motors Corp., 59 F.R.D. at
597.
[
Footnote 29]
We note that supporters of the offensive use of pass-on, other
than litigants in particular cases, generally have not contended
for a halfway rejection of
Hanover Shoe that would permit
offensive use of pass-on in some types of market situations, but
not in others.
See, e.g., Tr. of Oral Arg. 57 (United
States as
amicus curiae); Note, The Defense of "Passing
On" in Treble Damage Suits Under the Antitrust Laws, 70 Yale L.J.
469, 476, 478 (1961); commentators cited in
n 11,
supra.
[
Footnote 30]
See, e.g., In re Western Liquid Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d
at 198; Wheeler, Antitrust Treble-Damage Action: Do They Work?, 61
Calif.L.Rev. 1319, 1325 (1973).
[
Footnote 31]
Commentators have noted that recoveries in treble damages
actions aggregating large numbers of small claims often have failed
to compensate the individuals on behalf of whom the suits have been
brought.
E.g., Handler, The Shift from Substantive to
Procedural Innovations in Antitrust Suits -- the Twenty-Third
Annual Antitrust Review, 71 Colum.L.Rev. 1, 9-10 (1971); Wheeler,
supra, n 30, at
1339; Kirkham, Complex Civil Litigation -- Have Good Intentions
Gone Awry?, 70 F.R.D. 199, 206-207 (1976).
The dissenting opinion of MR JUSTICE BRENNAN appears to suggest
that the 1976
parens patriae legislation,
see
n 14,
supra,
provides an answer to this problem of compensating indirect
purchasers for small injuries.
Post at
431 U. S. 764
n. 23. Quite to the contrary, the Act "recognizes that rarely, if
ever, will all potential claimants actually come forward to secure
their share of the recovery," and that "the undistributed portion
of the fund . . . will often be substantial." H.R.Rep. No. 94-499,
p. 16 (1975). The portion of the fund recovered in a
parens
patriae action that is not used to compensate the actual
injuries of antitrust victims is to be used as "a civil penalty . .
. deposited with the State as general revenues," Clayton Act §
4E(2), 15 U.S.C. § 15e(2) (1976 ed.), enacted by the 1976 Act,
or "for some public purposes benefiting, as closely as possible,
the class of injured persons," such as reducing the price of the
overcharged goods in future sales. H.R.Rep. No. 94-499,
supra at 16. That Congress chose to provide such
innovative methods of distributing damages awarded in a
parens
patriae action under newly enacted § 4C of the Clayton
Act, 15 U.S.C. § 15c (1976 ed.), does not eliminate the
obstacles to compensating indirect purchasers bringing traditional
suits under § 4.
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN, with whom MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL and MR.
JUSTICE BLACKMUN join, dissenting.
Respondent State of Illinois brought this treble damages civil
antitrust action under § 4 of the Clayton Act on behalf of
itself and various local governmental entities in the Greater
Chicago area alleging that an overcharge in the price of concrete
block used in the construction of public buildings was made by the
petitioners, manufacturers and sellers of concrete block, pursuant
to a price-fixing conspiracy in violation of § 1 of the
Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1. [
Footnote 2/1] Section 4 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat.
731, 15 U.S.C. § 15, broadly provides:
"[A]ny person who shall be injured in his business or property
by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws may sue
therefor . . . and shall recover threefold the damages by him
sustained. . . ."
Decisions of the Court defining the reach of § 4 have been
consistent with its broad objectives: to compensate victims of
antitrust violations and to deter future violations. The Court has
stated that § 4
"does not confine its protection to consumers, or to purchasers,
or to competitors, or to sellers . . . , [but] is comprehensive in
its terms and coverage, protecting all who are made victims of the
forbidden practices by whomever they may be perpetrated."
Mandevlle Island Farms, Inc. v. American Crystal Sugar
Co., 334 U. S. 219,
334 U. S. 236
(1948). [
Footnote 2/2]
Page 431 U. S. 749
Today's decision that § 4 affords a remedy only to persons
who purchase directly from an antitrust offender is a regrettable
retreat from that line of cases. Section 4 was cearly intended to
operate to protect individual consumers who purchase through
middlemen. Indeed, Congress acted on the premise that § 4 gave
a cause of action to indirect as well as direct purchasers when it
recently enacted the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act
of 1976, 90 Stat. 1394-1396, 15 U.S.C. § 15c
et seq.
(1976 ed.), and authorized state attorneys general to sue as
parens patriae to recover damages on behalf of citizens of
their various States.
Today's decision outs Congress' purpose and severely undermines
the effectiveness of the private treble damages action as an
instrument of antitrust enforcement. For in many instances, the
brunt of antitrust injuries is borne by indirect purchasers, often
ultimate consumers of a product, as increased costs are passed
along the chain of distribution. [
Footnote 2/3] In these instances, the Court's decision
frustrates both the compensation and deterrence objectives of the
treble damages action. Injured consumers are precluded from
recovering damages from manufacturers, and direct purchasers who
act as middlemen have little incentive to sue suppliers so long as
they may pass on the bulk of the illegal overcharges to the
ultimate consumers. This frustration of the congressional scheme is
in no way mandated by
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe
Machinery Corp., 392 U. S. 481
(1968). To the contrary, the same considerations that
Hanover
Shoe held
Page 431 U. S. 750
required rejection of the defendant's argument there, that,
because plaintiff had passed on cost increases to consumers in the
form of higher prices defendant should be relieved of liability
especially the consideration that it is essential to the public
interest to preserve the effectiveness of the private treble
damages action -- require affirmance of the decision below
construing § 4 to authorize respondents' suit.
I
In
Hanover Shoe, supra, the Court held that a defendant
in a treble damages action could not escape liability, except in
very limited circumstances, [
Footnote
2/4] by proof that the plaintiff had passed on illegal
overcharges to others farther along in the chain of distribution.
[
Footnote 2/5] The defendant in
Hanover Shoe, United Shoe, argued that Hanover was not
entitled to recover damages because the increased price it had paid
for United's equipment [
Footnote
2/6] had, in turn, been reflected in the increased price at
which Hanover had sold its shoes to the consuming public. The Court
held that several reasons supported its conclusion that this
defense was not available to United despite "the argument that
sound laws of economics require" its recognition, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 492.
First, the Court followed earlier cases holding that the "victim of
an overcharge is [immediately]
Page 431 U. S. 751
damaged within the meaning of § 4 to the extent of that
overcharge."
Id. at
392 U. S. 491.
The particularly apt precedent supporting this proposition was
Southern Pacific Co. v. Darnel-Taenzer Lumber Co.,
245 U. S. 531
(1918), [
Footnote 2/7] where a
pass-on defense had been rejected because of "[t]he general
tendency of the law, in regard to damages at least, . . . not to go
beyond the first step," and the Court's belief that
"[t]he carrier ought not to be allowed to retain his illegal
profit, and the only one who can take it from him is the one that
alone was in relation with him, and from whom the carrier took the
sum. . . ."
Id. at
245 U. S.
533-534. In other words, the requirement of privity
between plaintiff and defendant was a reason to deny defendant the
pass-on defense, since otherwise the defendant would be able to
profit by his own wrong.
Hanover Shoe cannot be read,
however, as limiting actions to parties in privity with one
another. That was made clear in
Perkins v. Standard Oil
Co., 395 U. S. 642,
395 U. S. 648
(1969), decided the next Term, a price discrimination case in which
the Court traced an illegal overcharge through several levels in
the chain of distribution, ultimately holding that a plaintiff
seeking to recover damages need show only a
"causal connection between the price discrimination in violation
of the [antitrust laws] and the injury suffered. . . . If there is
sufficient evidence in the record to support an inference of
causation, the ultimate conclusion as to what that evidence proves
is for the jury."
Darnell-Taenzer does, however, support
Hanover
Shoe's denial of the pass-on defense for the other reasons
relied upon in
Hanover Shoe: the difficulty of proving and
quantifying a pass-on, and the role of the treble damages action as
the most effective means of antitrust enforcement. 392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
492-494. The Court correctly discerned that the
difficulty of reconstructing
Page 431 U. S. 752
hypothetical pricing decisions, [
Footnote 2/8] would aggravate the already complex nature
of antitrust litigation, since pass-on defenses would become
commonplace whenever the chain of distribution extended beyond the
plaintiff. This would lessen the effectiveness of the treble
damages action, since ultimate consumers individually often suffer
only minor damages, and therefore have little incentive to bring
suit. Limiting defendants' liability to the loss of profits
suffered by direct purchasers would thus allow the antitrust
offender to avoid having to pay the full social cost of his illegal
conduct in many cases in which indirect purchasers failed to bring
suit. Consequently,
"those who violate the antitrust laws by price-fixing or
monopolizing would retain the fruits of their illegality because no
one was available who would bring suit against them. Treble damage
actions, the importance of which the Court has many times
emphasized, would be substantially reduced in effectiveness."
Id. at
392 U. S. 494.
Hanover Shoe thus confronted the Court with the choice, as
had been true in
Darnell-Taenzer, of interpreting § 4
in a way that might overcompensate the plaintiff, who had certainly
suffered some injury, or of defining it in a way that under-deters
the violator by allowing him to retain a portion of his ill-gotten
overcharges. The Court chose to interpret § 4 so as to allow
the plaintiff to recover for the entire overcharge. This choice was
consistent with recognition of the importance
Page 431 U. S. 753
of the treble damages action in deterring antitrust violations.
[
Footnote 2/9] But
Hanover
Shoe certainly did not imply that an indirect purchaser would
not also have a cause of action under § 4 when the illegal
overcharges were passed on to him.
Despite the superficial appeal of the argument that
Hanover
Shoe should be applied "consistently," thus precluding
plaintiffs and defendants alike from proving that increased costs
were passed along the chain of distribution, there are sound
reasons for treating offensive and defensive passing-on cases
differently. The interests at stake in "offensive" passing-on
cases, where the indirect purchasers sue for damages for their
injuries, are simply not the same as the interests at stake in the
Hanover Shoe, or "defensive" passing-on situation. There
is no danger in this case, for example, as there was in
Hanover
Shoe, that the defendant will escape liability and frustrate
the objectives of the treble damages action. Rather, the same
policies of insuring the continued effectiveness of the treble
damages action and preventing wrongdoers from retaining the spoils
of their misdeeds favor allowing indirect purchasers to prove that
overcharges were passed on to them.
Hanover Shoe thus can
and should be limited to cases of defensive assertion of the
passing-on defense to antitrust liability, where direct and
indirect purchasers are not parties in the same action. [
Footnote 2/10] I fully agree with the
observation:
"The attempt to transform a rejection of a defense
Page 431 U. S. 754
because it unduly hampers antitrust enforcement into a reason
for a complete refusal to entertain the claims of a certain class
of plaintiffs seems an ingenious attempt to turn the decision [in
Hanover Shoe] and its underlying rationale on its
head."
In re Master Key Antitrust Litigation, 1973-2 Trade
Cas. � 74,680, pp. 94,9794,979 (Conn.).
II
A
Today's decision goes far to frustrate Congress' objectives in
creating the treble damages action. Treble damages actions were
first authorized under § 7 of the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 210.
The legislative history of this section shows that it was conceived
primarily as a remedy for "[t]he people of the United States as
individuals," especially for consumers.
See, e.g., 21
Cong.Rec. 1767-1768 (1890) (remarks of Sen. George);
see also
id. at 2612 (Sens. Teller and Reagan), 2615 (Sen. Coke), 2640
(Sen. Spooner). [
Footnote 2/11]
In the Clayton Act of
Page 431 U. S. 755
1914, Congress extended the § 7 remedy to persons injured
by "any violation of the antitrust laws."
See Brunswick Corp v.
Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc., 429 U. S. 477,
429 U. S. 486
n. 10 (1977), citing H. R. Rep. No. 627, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 14
(1914). These actions were conceived primarily as
"'open[ing] the door of justice to every man, whenever he may be
injured by those who violate the antitrust laws, and giv[ing] the
injured party ample damages for the wrong suffered.' [
Footnote 2/12]"
Brunswick, supra, at
429 U. S. 486
n. 10, quoting 51 Cong. Rec. 9073 (1914) (remarks of Rep. Webb);
see, e.g., id. at 9079 (Rep. Volstead), 9270 (Rep.
Carlin), 9414-9417, 9466-9467, 9487-9495.
See also the
House debates following the conference committee report.
Id. at 16274-16275 (Rep. Webb), 16317-16319 (Rep.
Floyd).
The Court has interpreted § 4 broadly, this in recognition
of the plainly stated congressional objective,
Northern Pacific
R. Co. v. United States, 356 U. S. 1,
356 U. S. 4
(1958), that the private treble damages action play a paramount
role in the enforcement of the fundamental economic policy of the
Nation,
Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc.,
395 U. S. 100,
395 U. S.
130-131 (1969);
Minnesota Mining & Mfg. Co. v.
New Jersey Wood Finishing Co., 381 U.
S. 311,
381 U. S. 318
(1965), and has concluded that
"the purposes of the antitrust laws are best served by insuring
that the private action will be an ever-present threat to deter
anyone contemplating business behavior in violation of the
antitrust laws."
Perma Life Mufflers, Inc. v. International Parts Corp.,
392 U. S. 134,
392 U. S. 139
(1968). The federal courts have accordingly been cautioned "not
[to]
Page 431 U. S. 756
add requirements to burden the private litigant beyond what is
specifically set forth by Congress in [the antitrust] laws,"
Radovich v. National Football League, 352 U.
S. 445,
352 U. S. 454
(1957), and express approval has been given the
"'tendency of the courts . . . to find some way in which damages
can be awarded where a wrong has been done. Difficulty of
ascertainment is no longer confused with right of recovery' for a
proven invasion of the plaintiff's rights."
Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, 327 U.
S. 251,
327 U. S.
265-266 (1946).
See also Zenith Radio Corp. v.
Hazeltine Research, Inc., supra at
395 U. S.
130-131;
Perma Life Mufflers, Inc. v. International
Parts Corp., supra; Hanover Shoe, Inc. v. United Shoe Machinery
Corp., 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 494.
And
Radiant Burners, Inc. v. Peoples Gas Light & Coke
Co., 364 U. S. 656,
364 U. S. 660
(1961), emphasized that, to plead a cause of action under § 4,
"allegations adequate to show a violation and . . . that plaintiff
was damaged thereby are all the law requires."
B
The recently enacted Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements
Act of 1976 was expressly adopted to create
"an effective mechanism to permit consumers to recover damages
for conduct which is prohibited by the Sherman Act by giving State
attorneys general a cause of action [to sue as
parens
patriae on behalf of the States' citizens] against antitrust
violators."
S.Rep. No. 94-803, p. 6 (1976). Title III of the new Act
responded to the holding of
Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of
Cal., 405 U. S. 251
(1972), that the Clayton Act does not authorize a State to sue for
damages for an injury to its general economy allegedly attributable
to a violation of the antitrust laws. The Senate Report
accompanying the new Act expressly found that "[t]he economic
burden of most antitrust violations is borne by the consumer in the
form of higher prices for goods and services," S.Rep. No. 94-803,
supra at 39, and it is clear that the new Act is intended
to provide a remedy
Page 431 U. S. 757
for injured consumers whether or not they purchased directly
from the violator. The Senate Report states,
id. at
42:
"A direct cause of action is granted the States to avoid the
inequities and inconsistencies of restrictive judicial
interpretations. . . . Section 4C is intended to assure that
consumers are not precluded from the opportunity of proving the
amount of their damage and to avoid problems with respect to
manageability [of class actions],
standing, privity, target
area, remoteness, and the like. [
Footnote 2/13]"
(Emphasis supplied.)
Representative Rodino, a sponsor, stated during the House
debates:
"[A]ssuming the State attorney general proves a violation, and
proves that an overcharge was 'passed on' to the consumers,
injuring them 'in their property' -- that is, their pocketbooks --
recoveries are authorized by the compromise bill whether or not the
consumes purchased directly, from the price-fixer, or indirectly,
from intermediaries, retailers, or middlemen. The technical and
procedural argument that consumers have no 'standing' whenever they
are not 'in privity' with the price-fixer, and have not purchased
directly from him, is rejected by the compromise bill. Opinions
relying on this procedural
Page 431 U. S. 758
technicality . . . are squarely rejected by the compromise
bill."
122 Cong.Rec. H10295 (daily ed. Sept. 16, 1976).
It is difficult to see how Congress could have expressed itself
more clearly. Even if the question whether indirect purchasers
could recover for damages passed on to them was open before passage
of the 1976 Act, and I do not believe that it was, Congress'
interpretation of § 4 in enacting the
parens patriae
provision should resolve it in favor of their authority to sue.
Indeed, the House Report accompanying the bill actually referred to
the opinion of the District Court in this case as an example of the
correct answer. N. 13,
supra. The Court's tortuous efforts
to impose a "consistency" upon this area of the law that Congress
has so clearly rejected is a return to the "legal somersaults and
twistings and turnings" of the Court's earlier opinions that
ultimately led to the passage of the Clayton Act in 1914 to salvage
the ailing Sherman Act.
See 51 Cong.Rec. 9086 (1914)
(remarks of Rep. Kelly).
III
Hanover Shoe correctly observed that the necessity of
tracing a cost increase through several levels of a chain of
distribution "would often require additional long and complicated
proceedings involving massive evidence and complicated theories."
392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 493.
But this may be said of almost all antitrust cases.
Hanover
Shoe itself highlights this unavoidable complication, in that
it requires the plaintiff to prove a probable course of events
which
would have occurred but for the violation. [
Footnote 2/14] In essence, estimating the
amount of
Page 431 U. S. 759
damages passed on to an indirect purchaser is no different from
and no more complicated than estimating what the middleman's
selling price would have been, absent the violation.
See
ante at
431 U. S. 733
n. 13.
Nor should the fact that the price-fixed product in this case
(the concrete block) was combined with another product (the
buildings) before resale operate as an absolute bar to recovery. It
may well be true, as the State claims, that the cost of the block
was included separately in the project bids, and therefore can be
factored out from the price of the building with relative
certainty. In any case, this is a factual matter to be determined
based on the strength of the plaintiff's evidence. [
Footnote 2/15]
See, e.g., In re
Western Liquid Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d 191 (CA9 1973),
cert. denied sub nom. Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. Alaska,
415 U.S. 919 (1974). Admittedly, there will be many cases in which
the plaintiff will be unable to prove that the overcharge was
passed on. In others, the portion of the overcharge passed on may
be only approximately determinable. But again, this problem hardly
distinguishes this case from other antitrust cases. Reasoned
estimation is required in all antitrust cases, but,
"while the damages [in such cases] may not be determined by mere
speculation or guess, it will be enough if the evidence show the
extent of the damages as a matter of just and reasonable inference,
although the result be only approximate."
Story Parchment Co. v. Paterson Co., 282 U.
S. 555,
282 U. S. 563
(1931).
See also Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, 327 U.S.
at
327 U. S. 266;
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Southern Photo Materials Co.,
273 U. S. 359,
273 U. S. 379
(1927). Lack of precision in apportioning damages between direct
and indirect purchasers is thus plainly not a convincing reason for
denying
Page 431 U. S. 760
indirect purchasers an opportunity to prove their injuries and
damages. Moreover, from the deterrence standpoint, it is irrelevant
to whom damages are paid, so long as someone redresses the
violation. Antitrust violators are equally deterred whether the
judgments against them are in favor of direct or indirect
purchasers.
Hanover Shoe said as much. The Court's
decision recognized that some plaintiffs would recover more than
their due, but concluded that the necessity of assuring that
someone recover, and thus deter future violations and
prevent the antitrust offender from profiting by his illegal
overcharge, outweighed any resulting injustice. [
Footnote 2/16]
I concede that, despite the broad wording of § 4, there is
a point beyond which the wrongdoer should not be held liable.
See, e.g., Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat, Inc.,
429 U. S. 477
(1977);
Hawaii v. Standard Oil Co. of Cal., 405 U.
S. 251 (1972). Courts have therefore developed various
tests of antitrust "standing," not unlike the concept of proximate
cause in tort law, to define that point. The definition has been
variously articulated, usually in terms of two tests. The more
restrictive test focuses on the directness of the injury; [
Footnote 2/17] the more liberal, and more
widely accepted, on whether the plaintiff is within the "target
area" of the defendant's violation. [
Footnote 2/18]
Page 431 U. S. 761
But if the broad language of § 4 means anything, surely it
must render the defendant liable to those within the defendant's
chain of distribution. It would indeed be "paradoxical to deny
recover to the ultimate consumer while permitting the middlemen a
windfall recovery." P. Areeda, Antitrust Analysis: Problems, Text,
Cases 75 (2d ed.1974).
IV
I acknowledge some abstract merit in the argument that to allow
indirect purchasers to sue while at the same time precluding
defendants from asserting pass-on defenses in suits by direct
purchasers subjects antitrust defendants to the risk of multiple
liability. But, as a practical matter, existing procedural
mechanisms can eliminate this danger in most instances. Even
though, as the Court says, no procedure currently exists which can
eliminate the possibility entirely,
ante at
431 U. S. 731
n. 11, the hypothetical possibility that a few defendants might be
subjected to the danger of multiple liability does not, in my view,
justify erecting a bar against all recoveries by indirect
purchasers without regard to whether the particular case presents a
significant danger of double recovery. The "double recovery"
specter was argued in the Congress that passed the
Hart-Scott-Rodino Act, and was rejected. The Senate Report recorded
the Act's purpose to codify the holding of the Court of Appeals for
the Ninth Circuit in
In re Western Liquid Asphalt Cases,
supra:
"'We therefore see no problem of double recovery, and we believe
that, if this difficulty should arise in some other connection, the
district court will be able to fashion relief accordingly. In
addition to the court's control over its decree, numerous devices
exist. We note that the consolidation of cases, which has already
occurred, is one means of averting duplicitous awards. The short,
four-year statute of limitations is another; later suits, after
Page 431 U. S. 762
final judgment herein, are unlikely. 15 U.S.C. § 15b. In
other cases, it may be that statutory interpleader, 28 U.S.C.
§ 1335, could be used by antitrust defendants to avoid double
liability. If necessary, special masters may be appointed to handle
complex cases. Finally, there are the doctrines of
res
judicata and collateral estoppel and procedures for compulsory
joinder. The day is long past when courts, particularly federal
courts, will deny relief to a deserving plaintiff merely because of
procedural difficulties or problems of apportioning damages.'"
"We would prefer to place the burden of proving apportionment
upon appellees, rather than deny all recovery to appellants. Such a
burden would be the consequence of appellees' illegal acts, not
appellants' suits. Where the choice is between a windfall to
intermediaries or letting guilty defendants go free, liability is
imposed.
Hanover Shoe, supra, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
494. So, too, between ultimate purchasers and
defendants."
S.Rep. No. 94-803, p. 44 (1976), quoting 487 F.2d at 201
(citation omitted).
Moreover, the possibility of multiple recovery arises in only
two situations: (1) where suits by direct and indirect purchasers
are pending at the same time but in different courts; and (2) where
additional suits are filed after an award of damages based on the
same violation in a prior suit. [
Footnote 2/19] In the first situation, the United
States, Brief as
Amicus Curiae 25, cogently points out
that district courts may make use of the alternatives suggested by
the Manual for Complex Litigation, 1 (pt. 2) J. Moore, Federal
Practice (1976): district courts may use the intra-district
transfer power created by 28 U.S.C. § 1404(b), coordinate
pretrial proceedings of cases pending in
Page 431 U. S. 763
different districts, or transfer oases to a single district
pursuant to § 1404(a). In addition, the Judicial Panel on
Multidistrict Litigation is empowered by 28 U.S.C. § 1407 to
transfer cases involving common questions of fact to any district
for coordinated pretrial proceedings upon its determination that
the transfer "will be for the convenience of parties and witnesses,
and will promote the just and efficient conduct of such actions."
After pretrial transfers under this section, cases can be
consolidated and transferred to the same district for trial
pursuant to the transfer power under § 1404(a). [
Footnote 2/20] A further device mentioned
in
Western Liquid Asphalt is statutory interpleader under
28 U.S.C. § 1335, by which the defendant can bring all
potential plaintiffs into the same court and require them to
litigate
inter se to determine their appropriate shares of
the total recovery. [
Footnote
2/21]
True, there is a greater hypothetical danger of multiple
recovery where suits are independently instituted after an earlier
suit based on the same violation has proceeded to judgment.
[
Footnote 2/22] But, even here,
the likelihood that defendants
Page 431 U. S. 764
will be subjected to multiple liability is, as a practical
matter, remote. The extended nature of antitrust actions, often
involving years of discovery, combines with the short four-year
statute of limitations to make it impractical for potential
plaintiffs to sit on their rights until after entry of judgment in
the earlier suit.
The Court today regrettably weakens the effectiveness of the
private treble damages action as a deterrent to antitrust
violations by, in most cases, precluding consumers from recovering
for antitrust injuries. For, in many instances, consumers, although
indirect purchasers, bear the brunt of antitrust violations. To
deny them an opportunity for recovery is particularly indefensible
when direct purchasers, acting as middlemen and ordinarily
reluctant to sue their suppliers, [
Footnote 2/23] pass on the bulk of their increased
costs to consumers farther along the chain of distribution.
Congress has given us a clear signal that § 4 is not to be
read to have the restrictive
Page 431 U. S. 765
scope ascribed to it by the Court today. I would follow the
congressional understanding, and therefore would affirm. [
Footnote 2/24]
[
Footnote 2/1]
The block was sold to various general and special contractors
who had successfully bid to construct public buildings. The State
was thus an indirect purchaser of the block.
[
Footnote 2/2]
There is, of course, a point beyond which antitrust defendants
should not be held responsible for the remote consequences of their
actions.
See the discussion in Part III,
infra at
431 U. S.
760-761.
[
Footnote 2/3]
The portion of an illegal overcharge that a direct purchaser can
pass on depends upon the elasticity of demand in the relevant
product market. If the market is relatively inelastic, he may pass
on a relatively large portion. If demand is relatively elastic, he
may not be able to raise his price, and will have to absorb the
increase, making it up by decreasing other costs or increasing
sales volume. It is extremely unlikely that a middleman could pass
on the entire cost increase. But rarely would he have to absorb the
entire increase. R. Posner, Antitrust Cases, Economic Notes, and
Other Materials 147-149 (1974).
[
Footnote 2/4]
The opinion recognizes that
"there might be situations -- for instance, when an overcharged
buyer has a preexisting 'cost-plus' contract, thus making it easy
to prove that he has not been damaged -- where the considerations
requiring that the passing-on defense not be permitted in this case
would not be present."
392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
494.
[
Footnote 2/5]
Hanover Shoe did not involve the consumers of the
plaintiff's shoes, to whom the overcharge allegedly was passed.
United's passing-on argument is referred to as "defensive" passing
on. The State's position, seeking recovery of illegal overcharges
allegedly passed on to it and its citizens, is referred to as
"offensive" passing on.
[
Footnote 2/6]
Hanover alleged that United monopolized the shoe machinery
industry in violation of § 2 of the Sherman Act by its
practice of leasing but refusing to sell its shoemaking
machinery.
[
Footnote 2/7]
In
Darnell-Taenzer, shippers brought suit for
reparations against a railroad claiming that the railroad had
charged unreasonable rates. The railroad argued that the shippers
had, in turn, passed on to their customers any excess over the
reasonable rate.
[
Footnote 2/8]
"[T]he impact of a single change in the relevant conditions
cannot be measured after the fact; indeed, a businessman may be
unable to state whether, had one fact been different. . . . The
would have chosen a different price. . . ."
392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
492-493. The Court further observed that it is equally
difficult to ascertain "what effect a change in a company's price
will have on its total sales"; and it is all but impossible to
demonstrate that the particular plaintiff "could not or would not
have raised his prices absent the overcharge or maintained the
higher price had the overcharge been discontinued."
Id. at
392 U. S. 493.
See generally Posner,
supra, 431
U.S. 720fn2/3|>n. 3 at 147-149.
[
Footnote 2/9]
The pass-on defense in
Hanover Shoe was asserted by a
defendant against whom a
prima facie case of liability had
already been made out. The Clayton Act provides:
"A final judgment . . . rendered in any civil or criminal
proceeding brought by or on behalf of the United States under the
antitrust laws . . . shall be
prima facie evidence against
such defendant. . . ."
15 U.S.C. § 16(a). The Government had secured a judgment
against United in
United States v. United Shoe Machinery
Corp., 110 F.
Supp. 295 (Mass.1953),
summarily aff'd, 347 U.
S. 521 (1954).
[
Footnote 2/10]
Commentators almost unanimously conclude that, despite
Hanover Shoe, § 4 should be construed to authorize
indirect purchasers to recover upon proof that increases were
passed on to them.
See, e.g., Comment, Standing to Sue in
Antitrust Cases: The Offensive Use of Passing-on, 123 U.Pa.L.Rev.
976 (1975); Comment, Mangano and Ultimate-Consumer Standing: The
Misuse of the
Hanover Doctrine, 72 Colum.L.Rev. 394
(1972); Note, The Effect of
Hanover Shoe on the Offensive
Use of the Passing-on Doctrine, 46 So.Cal.L.Rev. 98 (1972).
But
see Handler & Blechman, Antitrust and the Consumer
Interest: The Fallacy of
Parens Patriae and A Suggested
New Approach, 85 Yale L.J. 626, 638-655 (1976). In addition, most
courts have read
Hanover Shoe as not preventing indirect
purchasers from attempting to prove that they have been injured.
See, e.g., Yoder Bros., Inc. v. California-Florida Plant
Corp., 537 F.2d 1347 (CA5 1976);
In re Western Liquid
Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d 191 (CA9 1973),
cert. denied sub
nom. Standard Oil Co. of Cal. v. Alaska, 415 U.S. 919 (1974);
Illinois v. Bristol-Myers Co., 152 U.S.App.D.C. 367, 470
F.2d 1276 (1972);
West Virginia v. Chas. Pfizer & Co.,
440 F.2d 1079 (CA2),
cert. denied sub nom. Cotler Drugs, Inc.
v. Chas. Pfizer & Co., 404 U.S. 871 (1971);
In re
Master Key Antitrust Litigation, 1973-2 Trade Cas. �
74,680 (Conn.).
[
Footnote 2/11]
A further indication of Congress' desire to create a remedy for
all persons, including consumers, even though their individual
injuries might be comparatively slight, was the elimination of the
jurisdictional amount requirement for antitrust actions.
See 21 Cong. Rec. 2612, 3148-3149 (1890) (remarks of Sens.
Sherman and Edmunds).
[
Footnote 2/12]
The fact that damages are trebled both aids deterrence and
provides the incentive of compensation, since it encourages suits
for relatively minor injuries.
[
Footnote 2/13]
Congress rejected earlier Court of Appeals and District Court
decisions erecting standing barriers to suits by indirect
purchasers, and chose instead to pattern the Act
"after such innovative decisions as
In re Western Liquid
Asphalt Cases, 487 F.2d 191 (9th Cir.1973);
In re Master
Key Litigation, 1973 Trade Cases � 74,680 and 1975
Trade Cases � 60,377 (DC Conn.);
State of Illinois v.
Ampress Brick Co., 1975 Trade Cases � 60,295 (DC Ill.)
[this case below];
Carnivale Bag Co. v. Slide Rite Mfg.,
1975 Trade Cases � 60,370 (S.D.N.Y.);
In re Antibiotics
Antitrust Actions, 333 F.
Supp. 278 (S.D.N.Y.1971); and
West Virginia v. Charles
Pfizer & Co., 440 F.2d 1079 (2d Cir.1971)."
Congress accepted these decisions as correctly stating the law.
S.Rep. No. 94-803, pp. 443 (1976).
[
Footnote 2/14]
In
Hanover Shoe, the measure of damages was the
difference between the amount Hanover paid for the lease and the
amount it would have pad had United agreed to sell the machinery.
It has been suggested that the burden of demonstrating a pass-on
may be no more difficult or speculative than the plaintiff's
initial task of proving an overcharge in the first instance.
See Pollock, Automatic Treble Damages and the Passing-on
Defense: The
Hanover Shoe Decision, 13 Antitrust Bull.
1183, 1210 (1968).
[
Footnote 2/15]
One commentator has suggested that, in deciding whether to
permit recovery by indirect purchasers in a particular case, courts
should consider the number of intervening hands the product has
passed through and the extent of its change in the process. P.
Areeda, Antitrust Analysis: Problems, Text, Cases 75 (2d ed.
1974).
[
Footnote 2/16]
This holding is consistent with the Court's continuing concern
for the effectiveness of the treble damages action, which has been
sustained even when the plaintiff was "no less morally
reprehensible than the defendant" with whom he had conspired.
Perma Life Mufflers, Inc. v. International Parts Corp.,
392 U. S. 134,
392 U. S. 139
(1968).
[
Footnote 2/17]
See, e.g., Loeb v. Eastman Kodak Co., 183 F. 704 (CA3
1910).
[
Footnote 2/18]
Earlier this Term,
Brunswick Corp. v. Pueblo Bowl-O-Mat,
Inc., disallowed a treble damages recovery, stating that, in
order to recover, antitrust plaintiffs must prove
"antitrust injury, which is to say injury of the type the
antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that
which makes [the] defendants' acts unlawful."
429 U.S. at
429 U. S. 489.
At least one Court of Appeals has rephrased the target-area test in
terms of whether the injury to the plaintiff is a reasonably
foreseeable consequence of the defendant's illegal conduct.
Mulvey v. Samuel Goldwyn Productions, 433 F.2d 1073 (CA9
1970),
cert. denied, 402 U.S. 923 (1971).
[
Footnote 2/19]
If direct and indirect purchasers bring suit in the same court,
the cases may be consolidated and damages allocated in accordance
with Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 42(a).
See Vest Virginia v. Chas.
Pfizer & Co., 440 F.2d 1079 (CA2 1971).
[
Footnote 2/20]
For a discussion of this process,
see Note, The
Judicial Panel and the Conduct of Multidistrict Litigation, 87
Harv.L.Rev. 1001 (1974); Comment, The Experience of Transferee
Courts Under the Multidistrict Litigation Act, 39 U.Chi.L.Rev. 588
(1972).
[
Footnote 2/21]
Petitioners suggest that interpleader may be an impractical
alternative for some defendants, since it requires a defendant to
complicate the suit by bringing in ultimate consumers, and to post
bond for the amount in controversy.
See 28 U.S.C. §
1335(a)(2). Although § 1335 clearly places a burden upon
defendants who elect to use it in order to avoid potential multiple
liability, that burden is not unique to antitrust cases, and
Congress has clearly indicated that it considers the burden
justified.
See S.Rep. No. 94 803, p. 44 (1976).
[
Footnote 2/22]
The problem of potential multiple recoveries is not present in
this case. All suits against petitioners were filed in the Northern
District of Illinois. Petitioners never sought consolidation under
Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 42(a) and stipulated in settlements with direct
purchasers that the settlement would not affect the rights of
indirect purchasers.
[
Footnote 2/23]
The opinion for the Court "recognize[s] that direct purchasers
sometimes may refrain from bringing a treble damages suit for fear
of disrupting relations with their suppliers," but concludes
that,
"on balance, and until there are clear directions from Congress
to the contrary, we conclude that the legislative purpose in
creating a group of 'private attorneys general' to enforce the
antitrust laws . . . is better served by holding direct purchasers
to be injured to the full extent of the overcharge paid by them
than by attempting to apportion the overcharge among all that may
have absorbed a part of it."
Ante at
431 U. S. 746.
But the intent of Congress in enacting the
parens patriae
provision of the 1976 Act was clearly to provide a mechanism to
permit recovery by consumers, and this purpose is not furthered by
a rule that will keep most consumers out of court.
The Court's opinion further observes that
"[m]any of the indirect purchasers barred from asserting pass-on
claims . . . have such a small stake in the lawsuit that even if
they were to recover as part of a class, only a small fraction
would be likely to come forward to collect their damages."
Ante at
431 U. S. 747.
Yet it was precisely because of judicially perceived weaknesses in
the class action as a device for consumer recovery for antitrust
violations that Congress enacted the
parens patriae
provision of the 1976 Act.
[
Footnote 2/24]
Abundant authority sanctions deference to congressional
indications in subsequent legislation regarding the congressional
meaning in earlier Acts worded consistently with that meaning.
NLRB v. Bell Aerospace Co., 416 U.
S. 267,
416 U. S. 275
(1974);
Red Lion Broadcasting Co. v. FCC, 395 U.
S. 367,
395 U. S. 380
(1969);
FHA v. The Darlington, Inc., 358 U. S.
84,
358 U. S. 90
(1958);
United States v. Stafoff, 260 U.
S. 477,
260 U. S. 480
(1923);
New York & Norfolk R. Co. v. Peninsula
Exchange, 240 U. S. 34,
240 U. S. 39
(1916). Although it is true, as the Court's opinion states,
ante at
431 U. S. 734
n. 14, that the post-enactment statements of "particular
legislators" who participated in the enactment of a statute cannot
change its meaning,
see Regional Rail Reorganization Act
Cases, 419 U. S. 102,
419 U. S. 132
(1974), quoting
National Woodwork Manufacturers Assn. v.
NLRB, 386 U. S. 612,
386 U. S. 639
n. 34 (1967), in this case, the House and Senate Reports
accompanying the amendments to § 4 of the Clayton Act clearly
reveal the 94th Congress' interpretation of that section as
permitting the kind of consumer action which the Court now
prohibits. Moreover, it is no answer to this to say that the new
parens patriae provision will not in all cases directly
compensate indirect purchasers,
ante at
431 U. S. 747
n. 31, for it is clear that, despite the difficulty of distributing
benefits to such injured persons, the new Act authorizes recovery
by the State on their behalf.
MR. JUSTICE BLACKMUN, dissenting.
I regard MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN's dissenting opinion as persuasive
and convincing, and I join it without hesitation.
I add these few sentences only to say that I think the
plaintiffs-respondents in this case, which they now have lost, are
the victims of an unhappy chronology. If
Hanover Shoe, Inc. v.
United Shoe Machinery Corp., 392 U. S. 481
(1968), had not preceded this case, and were it not "on the books,"
I am positive that the Court today would be affirming, perhaps
unanimously, the judgment of the Court of Appeals. The policy
behind the Antitrust Acts and all the signs point in that
direction, and a conclusion in favor of indirect purchasers who
could demonstrate injury would almost be compelled.
But
Hanover Shoe is on the books, and the Court feels
that it must be "consistent" in its application of pass-on.
That,
Page 431 U. S. 766
for me, is a wooden approach, and it is entirely inadequate when
considered in the light of the objectives of the Sherman and
Clayton Acts. The Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act of
1976 tells us all that is needed as to Congress' present
understanding of the Acts. Nevertheless, we must now await still
another statute which, as the Court acknowledges,
ante at
431 U. S. 734
n. 14, the Congress may adopt. One regrets that it takes so long
and so much repetitious effort to achieve, and have this Court
recognize, the obvious congressional aim.