Material Service Corp., a deep mining coal producer, and its
successor, appellee General Dynamics Corp., acquired, through stock
purchases, control of appellee United Electric Coal Companies, a
strip-mining coal producer. The Government brought suit alleging
that this acquisition violated § 7 of the Clayton Act. The
District Court found no violation on the ground,
inter
alia, that the Government's evidence -- consisting principally
of past production statistics showing that, within certain
geographic markets, the coal industry was concentrated among a
small number of large producers, that this concentration was
increasing, and that the acquisition here would materially enlarge
the acquiring company's market share and thereby contribute to the
concentration trend -- did not support the Government's contention
that the acquisition substantially lessened competition in the
production and sale of coal in either or both of two specified
geographic markets. This conclusion was primarily based on a
determination that United Electric's coal reserves were so low that
its potential to compete with other producers in the future was far
weaker than the aggregate production statistics relied on by the
Government might otherwise have indicated, virtually all of United
Electric's proved reserves being either depleted or already
committed by long-term contracts with large customers, so that its
power to affect the price of coal was severely limited and steadily
diminishing.
Held:
1. While the Government's statistical showing might have been
sufficient to support a finding of "undue concentration" in the
absence of other considerations, the District Court was justified
in finding that other pertinent factors affecting the coal industry
and appellees' business mandated a conclusion that no substantial
lessening of competition occurred or was threatened by the
acquisition. Ample evidence showed that United Electric does not
have sufficient reserves, which are a key factor in measuring
Page 415 U. S. 487
a coal producer's market strength, to make it a significant
competitive force. Thus, in terms of probable future ability to
compete, rather than in terms of past production on which the
Government relied, the court was warranted in concluding that the
merger did not violate § 7 of the Act. Pp.
415 U. S.
494-504.
2. The District Court was justified in considering
post-acquisition evidence relating to changes in the patterns and
structure of the coal industry and in United Electric's reserve
situation, since (unlike evidence showing only that no lessening of
competition has yet occurred) the demonstration of weak coal
resources necessarily implied that United Electric was not merely
disinclined, but unable, to compete effectively for future
contracts, such evidence going directly to the question whether
future lessening of competition was probable. Pp.
415 U. S.
504-506.
3. United Electric's weak reserves position, rather than
establishing a "failing company" defense by showing that the
company would have gone out of business but for the merger, went to
the heart of the Government's statistical
prima facie case
and substantiated the District Court's conclusion that United
Electric, even if it remained in the market, did not have
sufficient reserves to compete effectively for long-term contracts,
and therefore appellees' failure to meet the prerequisites of a
failing company defense did not detract from the validity of the
District Court's analysis. Pp.
415 U. S.
506-508.
4. Under the "clearly erroneous" standard of Fed.Rule Civ.Proc.
52(a), which governs as fully on direct appeal to this Court as on
review by a court of appeals, the District Court's findings and
conclusions are supported by the evidence, and are not clearly
erroneous. P.
415 U. S.
508.
5. The District Court found new strip reserves unavailable, and
the mere possibility that United Electric could some day acquire
expertise to mine deep reserves does not depreciate the validity of
the conclusion that United Electric, at the time of trial, did not
have the power to compete effectively for long-term contracts, nor
does it give the production statistics relied on by the Government
more significance than the District Court ascribed to them. Pp.
415 U. S.
508-510.
341 F.
Supp. 534, affirmed.
STEWART, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BURGER, C.J., and BLACKMUN, POWELL, and REHNQUIST, JJ., joined.
DOUGLAS,
Page 415 U. S. 488
J., filed a dissenting opinion in which BRENNAN, WHITE, and
MARSHALL, JJ., joined,
post, p.
415 U. S.
511.
MR. JUSTICE STEWART delivered the opinion of the Court.
On September 22, 1967, the Government commenced this suit in the
United States District Court for the Northern District of Illinois,
challenging as violative of § 7 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat.
731, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 18, the acquisition of the stock
of United Electric Coal Companies by Material Service Corp. and its
successor, General Dynamics Corp. After lengthy discovery
proceedings, a trial was held from March 30 to April 22, 1970, and,
on April 13, 1972, the District Court issued an opinion and
judgment finding no violation of the Clayton Act.
341 F.
Supp. 534. The Government appealed directly to this Court
pursuant to the Expediting Act, 15 U.S.C. § 29, and we noted
probable jurisdiction. 409 U.S. 1058.
I
At the time of the acquisition involved here, Material Service
Corp. was a large midwest producer and supplier of building
materials, concrete, limestone, and coal. All of its coal
production was from deep-shaft mines operated by it or its
affiliate, appellee Freeman Coal Mining Corp., and production from
these operations
Page 415 U. S. 489
amounted to 6.9 million tons of coal in 1959 and 8.4 million
tons in 1967. In 1954, Material Service began to acquire the stock
of United Electric Coal Companies. United Electric at all relevant
times operated only strip or open-pit mines in Illinois and
Kentucky; at the time of trial in 1970, a number of its mines had
closed, and its operations had been reduced to four mines in
Illinois and none in Kentucky. [
Footnote 1] In 1959, it produced 3.6 million tons of coal,
and by 1967, it had increased this output to 5.7 million tons.
Material Service's purchase of United Electric stock continued
until 1959. At this point, Material's holdings amounted to more
than 34% of United Electric's outstanding shares, and -- all
parties are now agreed on this point -- Material had effective
control of United Electric. The president of Freeman was elected
chairman of United Electric's executive committee, and other
changes in the corporate structure of United Electric were made at
the behest of Material Service.
Some months after this takeover, Material Service was itself
acquired by the appellee General Dynamics Corp. General Dynamics is
a large diversified corporation, much of its revenues coming from
sales of aircraft, communications, and marine products to
Government agencies. The trial court found that its purchase of
Material Service was part of a broad diversification program aimed
at expanding General Dynamics into commercial, nondefense business.
As a result of the purchase of Material Service, and through it, of
Freeman and United Electric, General Dynamics became the Nation's
fifth largest commercial coal producer. During the early 1960's
General Dynamics increased its equity in United
Page 415 U. S. 490
Electric by direct purchases of United Electric stock, and, by
1966, it held or controlled 66.15% of United Electric's outstanding
shares. In September, 1966, the board of directors of General
Dynamics authorized a tender offer to holders of the remaining
United Electric stock. This offer was successful, and United
Electric shortly thereafter became a wholly owned subsidiary of
General Dynamics.
The thrust of the Government's complaint was that the
acquisition of United Electric by Material Service in 1959 violated
§ 7 of the Clayton Act [
Footnote 2] because the takeover substantially lessened
competition in the production and sale of coal in either or both of
two geographic markets. It contended that a relevant "section of
the country" within the meaning of § 7 was, alternatively, the
State of Illinois or the Eastern Interior Coal Province Sales Area,
the latter being one of four major coal distribution areas
recognized by the coal industry and comprising Illinois and
Indiana, and parts of Kentucky, Tennessee, Iowa, Minnesota,
Wisconsin, and Missouri. [
Footnote
3]
Page 415 U. S. 491
At trial, controversy focused on three basic issues: the
propriety of coal as a "line of commerce," the definition of
Illinois or the Eastern Interior Coal Province Sales Area as a
relevant "section of the country," and the probability of a
lessening of competition within these or any other product and
geographic markets resulting from the acquisition. The District
Court decided against the Government on each of these issues.
As to the relevant product market, the court found that coal
faced strong and direct competition from other sources of energy
such as oil, natural gas, nuclear energy, and geothermal power,
which created a cross-elasticity of demand among those various
fuels. As a result, it concluded that coal, by itself, was not a
permissible product market, and that the "energy market" was the
sole "line of commerce" in which anticompetitive effects could
properly be canvassed.
Similarly, the District Court rejected the Government's proposed
geographic markets on the ground that they were "based essentially
on past and present production statistics, and do not relate to
actual coal consumption patterns." 341 F. Supp. at 556. The court
found that a realistic geographic market should be defined in terms
of transportation arteries and freight charges that determined the
cost of delivered coal to purchasers, and thus the competitive
position of various coal producers. In particular, it found that
freight rate districts, designated by the Interstate Commerce
Commission for determining rail transportation rates, of which
there were four in the area served by the appellee companies, were
the prime determinants for the
Page 415 U. S. 492
geographic competitive patterns among coal producers. In
addition, the court concluded that two large and specialized coal
consumption units were sufficiently differentiable in their coal
use patterns to be included as relevant geographic areas. [
Footnote 4] In lieu of the State of
Illinois or the Eastern Interior Coal Province Sales Area, the
court accordingly found the relevant geographic market to be 10
smaller areas, comprising the two unique consumers together with
four utility sales areas and four non-utility sales areas based on
the ICC freight rate districts.
Finally, and, for purposes of this appeal, most significantly,
the District Court found that the evidence did not support the
Government's contention that the 1959 acquisition of United
Electric substantially lessened competition in any product or
geographic market. This conclusion was based on four determinations
made in the court's opinion,
id. at 558-559. First, the
court noted that, while the number of coal producers in the Eastern
Interior Coal Province declined from 144 to 39 during the period of
1957-1967, this reduction
"occurred not because small producers have been acquired by
others, but as the inevitable result of the change in
Page 415 U. S. 493
the nature of demand for coal."
Consequently, the court found,
"this litigation presents a very different situation from that,
in such cases as
United States v. Philadelphia National
Bank, 374 U. S. 321 (1963), and
United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U. S.
270 (1966), where the Supreme Court was concerned with
'preventing even slight increases in concentration.' 374 U.S. at
374 U. S. 365, n. 2."
341 F. Supp. at 558. Second, the court noted that United
Electric and Freeman were "predominantly complementary in nature,"
since
"United Electric is a strip mining company with no experience in
deep mining nor likelihood of acquiring it, [and] Freeman is a deep
mining company with no experience or expertise in strip
mining."
Ibid. Third, the court found that, if Commonwealth
Edison, a large investor-owned public utility, were excluded,
"none of the sales by United Electric in the period 1965 to
1967, the years chosen by the Government for analysis, would have
or could have been competitive with Freeman, had the two companies
been independent,"
because of relative distances from potential consumers and the
resultant impact on relative competitive position.
Ibid.
Finally, the court found that United Electric's coal reserves were
so low that its potential to compete with other coal producers in
the future was far weaker than the aggregate production statistics
relied on by the Government might otherwise have indicated. In
particular, the court found that virtually all of United Electric's
proved coal reserves were either depleted or already committed by
long-term contracts with large customers, and that United
Electric's power to affect the price of coal was thus severely
limited and steadily diminishing. On the basis of these
considerations, the court concluded:
"Under these circumstances, continuation of the affiliation
between United Electric and Freeman is not adverse
Page 415 U. S. 494
to competition, nor would divestiture benefit competition even
were this court to accept the Government's unrealistic product and
geographic market definitions."
Id. at 560.
II
The Government sought to prove a violation of § 7 of the
Clayton Act principally through statistics showing that, within
certain geographic markets the coal industry was concentrated among
a small number of large producers; that this concentration was
increasing; and that the acquisition of United Electric would
materially enlarge the market share of the acquiring company, and
thereby contribute to the trend toward concentration.
The concentration of the coal market in Illinois and,
alternatively, in the Eastern Interior Coal Province was
demonstrated by a table of the shares of the largest two, four, and
10 coal producing firms in each of these areas for both 1957 and
1967 that revealed the following: [
Footnote 5]
------------------------------------------------
Eastern Interior
Coal Province Illinois
----------------- -----------
1957 1967 1957 1967
------------------------------------------------
Top 2 firms. . . . 29.6 48.6 37.8 52.9
Top 4 firms. . . . 43.0 62.9 54.5 75.2
Top 10 firms. . . . 65.5 91.4 84.0 98.0
------------------------------------------------
These statistics, the Government argued, showed not only that
the coal industry was concentrated among a small number of leading
producers, but that the trend had been toward increasing
concentration. [
Footnote 6]
Furthermore, the undisputed
Page 415 U. S. 495
fact that the number of coal-producing firms in Illinois
decreased almost 73% during the period of 1957 to 1967 from 144 to
39 was claimed to be indicative of the same trend. The acquisition
of United Electric by Material Service resulted in increased
concentration of coal sales among the leading producers in the
areas chosen by the Government, as shown by the following table:
[
Footnote 7]
---------------------------------------------------------------------
1959 1967
------------------------- ---------------------------
Share of Share of Share of Share of
top 2 top 2 top 2 top 2
but for given Percent but for given Percent
merger merger increase merger merger increase
---------------------------------------------------------------------
Province . . . . 33.1 37.9 14.5 45.0 48.6 8.0
Illinois . . . . 36.6 44.3 22.4 44.0 52.9 20.2
---------------------------------------------------------------------
Finally, the Government's statistics indicated that the
acquisition increased the share of the merged company
Page 415 U. S. 496
in the Illinois and Eastern Interior Coal Province coal markets
by significant degrees: [
Footnote
8]
--------------------------------------------------
Province Illinois
-------------- --------------
Share Share
Rank (percent) Rank (percent)
--------------------------------------------------
1959
Freeman . . . . . . 2 7.6 2 15.1
United Electric. . 6 4.8 5 8.1
Combined. . . . . . 2 12.4 1 23.2
1967
Freeman . . . . . . 5 6.5 2 12.9
United Electric . . 9 4.4 6 8.9
Combined. . . . . . 2 10.9 2 21.8
--------------------------------------------------
In prior decisions involving horizontal mergers between
competitors, this Court has found
prima facie violations
of § 7 of the Clayton Act from aggregate statistics of the
sort relied on by the United States in this case. In
Brown Shoe
Co. v. United States, 370 U. S. 294, the
Court reviewed the legislative history of the most recent
amendments to the Act, and found that
"[t]he dominant theme pervading congressional consideration of
the 1950 amendments was a fear of what was considered to be a
rising tide of economic concentration in the American economy."
Id. at
370 U. S. 315.
A year later, in
United States v. Philadelphia National
Bank, 374 U. S. 321, the
Court clarified the relevance of a statistical demonstration of
concentration in a particular industry and of the effects
Page 415 U. S. 497
thereupon of a merger or acquisition with the following
language:
"This intense congressional concern with the trend toward
concentration warrants dispensing, in certain cases, with elaborate
proof of market structure, market behavior, or probable
anticompetitive effects. Specifically, we think that a merger which
produces a firm controlling an undue percentage share of the
relevant market, and results in a significant increase in the
concentration of firms in that market, is so inherently likely to
lessen competition substantially that it must be enjoined in the
absence of evidence clearly showing that the merger is not likely
to have such anticompetitive effects."
Id. at
374 U. S. 363.
See also United States v. Continental Can Co.,
378 U. S. 441,
378 U. S. 458;
United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.S. at
384 U. S. 277;
United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.
S. 546,
384 U. S.
550-552.
The effect of adopting this approach to a determination of a
"substantial" lessening of competition is to allow the Government
to rest its case on a showing of even small increases of market
share or market concentration in those industries or markets where
concentration is already great or has been recently increasing,
since,
"if concentration is already great, the importance of preventing
even slight increases in concentration and so preserving the
possibility of eventual deconcentration is correspondingly
great."
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.
S. 271,
377 U. S. 279,
citing
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, supra,
at
374 U. S. 365
n. 42.
While the statistical showing proffered by the Government in
this case, the accuracy of which was not discredited by the
District Court or contested by the appellees, would under this
approach have sufficed to
Page 415 U. S. 498
support a finding of "undue concentration" in the absence of
other considerations, the question before us is whether the
District Court was justified in finding that other pertinent
factors affecting the coal industry and the business of the
appellees mandated a conclusion that no substantial lessening of
competition occurred or was threatened by the acquisition of United
Electric. We are satisfied that the court's ultimate finding was
not in error.
In
Brown Shoe v. United States, supra, we cautioned
that statistics concerning market share and concentration, while of
great significance, were not conclusive indicators of
anticompetitive effects:
"Congress indicated plainly that a merger had to be functionally
viewed, in the context of its particular industry."
370 U.S. at
370 U. S.
321-322.
"Statistics reflecting the shares of the market controlled by
the industry leaders and the parties to the merger are, of course,
the primary index of market power; but only a further examination
of the particular market -- its structure, history and probable
future -- can provide the appropriate setting for judging the
probable anticompetitive effect of the merger."
Id. at
370 U. S. 322
n. 38.
See also United States v. Continental Can Co.,
supra, at
378 U. S. 458.
In this case, the District Court assessed the evidence of the
"structure, history and probable future" of the coal industry, and,
on the basis of this assessment, found no substantial probability
of anticompetitive effects from the merger.
Much of the District Court's opinion was devoted to a
description of the changes that have affected the coal industry
since World War II. On the basis of more than three weeks of
testimony and a voluminous record, the court discerned a number of
clear and significant developments
Page 415 U. S. 499
in the industry. First, it found that coal had become
increasingly less able to compete with other sources of energy in
many segments of the energy market. Following the War, the industry
entirely lost its largest single purchaser of coal -- the railroads
-- and faced increasingly stiffer competition from oil and natural
gas as sources of energy for industrial and residential uses.
Because of these changes in consumption patterns, coal's share of
the energy resources consumed in this country fell from 78.4% in
1920 to 21.4% in 1968. The court reviewed evidence attributing this
decline not only to the changing relative economies of alternative
fuels and to new distribution and consumption patterns, but also to
more recent concern with the effect of coal use on the environment
and consequent regulation of the extent and means of such coal
consumption.
Second, the court found that, to a growing extent since 1954,
the electric utility industry has become the mainstay of coal
consumption. While electric utilities consumed only 15.76% of the
coal produced nationally in 1947, their share of total consumption
increased every year thereafter, and, in 1968, amounted to more
than 59% of all the coal consumed throughout the Nation. [
Footnote 9]
Third, and most significantly, the court found that, to an
increasing degree, nearly all coal sold to utilities is transferred
under long-term requirements contracts, under which coal producers
promise to meet utilities' coal consumption requirements for a
fixed period of time, and at predetermined prices. The court
described the mutual benefits accruing to both producers and
consumers of
Page 415 U. S. 500
coal from such long-term contracts in the following terms:
"This major investment [in electric utility equipment] can be
jeopardized by a disruption in the supply of coal. Utilities are,
therefore, concerned with assuring the supply of coal to such a
plant over its life. In addition, utilities desire to establish in
advance, as closely as possible, what fuel costs will be for the
life of the plant. For these reasons, utilities typically arrange
long-term contracts for all or at least a major portion of the
total fuel requirements for the life of the plant. . . ."
"The long-term contractual commitments are not only required
from the consumer's standpoint, but are also necessary from the
viewpoint of the coal supplier. Such commitments may require the
development of new mining capacity. . . . Coal producers have been
reluctant to invest in new mining capacity in the absence of
long-term contractual commitments for the major portion of the
mine's capacity. Furthermore, such long-term contractual
commitments are often required before financing for the development
of new capacity can be obtained by the producer."
341 F. Supp. at 543 (footnote omitted). These developments in
the patterns of coal distribution and consumption, the District
Court found, have limited the amounts of coal immediately available
for "spot" purchases on the open market, since
"[t]he growing practice by coal producers of expanding mine
capacity only to meet long-term contractual commitments and the
gradual disappearance of the small truck mines has tended to limit
the production capacity available for spot sales."
Ibid.
Page 415 U. S. 501
Because of these fundamental changes in the structure of the
market for coal, the District Court was justified in viewing the
statistics relied on by the Government as insufficient to sustain
its case. Evidence of past production does not, as a matter of
logic, necessarily give a proper picture of a company's future
ability to compete. In most situations, of course, the unstated
assumption is that a company that has maintained a certain share of
a market in the recent past will be in a position to do so in the
immediate future. Thus, companies that have controlled sufficiently
large shares of a concentrated market are barred from merger by
§ 7 not because of their past acts, but because their past
performances imply an ability to continue to dominate with at least
equal vigor. In markets involving groceries or beer, as in
Von's Grocery, supra, and
Pabst, supra,
statistics involving annual sales naturally indicate the power of
each company to compete in the future. Evidence of the amount of
annual sales is relevant as a prediction of future competitive
strength, since, in most markets, distribution systems and brand
recognition are such significant factors that one may reasonably
suppose that a company which has attracted a given number of sales
will retain that competitive strength.
In the coal market, as analyzed by the District Court, however,
statistical evidence of coal production was of considerably less
significance. The bulk of the coal produced is delivered under
long-term requirements contracts, and such sales thus do not
represent the exercise of competitive power, but rather the
obligation to fulfill previously negotiated contracts at a
previously fixed price. The focus of competition in a given
timeframe is not on the disposition of coal already produced, but
on the procurement of new long-term supply contracts. In this
situation, a company's
Page 415 U. S. 502
past ability. to produce is of limited significance, since it is
in a position to offer for sale neither its past production nor the
bulk of the coal it is presently capable of producing, which is
typically already committed under a long-term supply contract. A
more significant indicator of a company's power effectively to
compete with other companies lies in the state of a company's
uncommitted reserves of recoverable coal. A company with relatively
large supplies of coal which are not already under contract to a
consumer will have a more important influence upon competition in
the contemporaneous negotiation of supply contracts than a firm
with small reserves, even though the latter may presently produce a
greater tonnage of coal. In a market where the availability and
price of coal are set by long-term contracts, rather than immediate
or short-term purchases and sales, reserves, rather than past
production are the best measure of a company's ability to
compete.
The testimony and exhibits in the District Court revealed that
United Electric's coal reserve prospects were "unpromising." 341 F.
Supp. at 559. United's relative position of strength in reserves
was considerably weaker than its past and current ability to
produce. While United ranked fifth among Illinois coal producers in
terms of annual production, it was 10th in reserve holdings, and
controlled less than 1% of the reserves held by coal producers in
Illinois, Indiana, and western Kentucky.
Id. at 538. Many
of the reserves held by United had already been depleted at the
time of trial, forcing the closing of some of United's midwest
mines. [
Footnote 10]
Page 415 U. S. 503
Even more significantly, the District Court found that, of the
52,033,304 tons of currently mineable reserves in Illinois,
Indiana, and Kentucky controlled by United, only four million tons
had not already been committed under long-term contracts. United
was found to be facing the future with relatively depleted
resources at its disposal, and with the vast majority of those
resources already committed under contracts allowing no further
adjustment in price. In addition, the District Court found that
"United Electric has neither the possibility of acquiring more
[reserves] nor the ability to develop deep coal reserves," and thus
was not in a position to increase its reserves to replace those
already depleted or committed.
Id. at 560.
Viewed in terms of present and future reserve prospects -- and
thus in terms of probable future ability to compete -- rather than
in terms of past production, the District Court held that United
Electric was a far less significant factor in the coal market than
the Government contended or the production statistics seemed to
indicate. While the company had been and remained a "highly
profitable" and efficient producer of relatively large amounts of
coal, its current and future power to compete for subsequent
long-term contracts was severely limited by its scarce uncommitted
resources. [
Footnote 11]
Irrespective of the company's size when viewed as a producer, its
weakness as a competitor was properly
Page 415 U. S. 504
analyzed by the District Court and fully substantiated that
court's conclusion that its acquisition by Material Service would
not "substantially . . . lessen competition. . . ." The validity of
this conclusion is not undermined, we think, by the three-faceted
attack made upon it by the Government in this Court -- to which we
now turn.
III
First, the Government urges that the court committed legal error
by giving undue consideration to facts occurring after the
effective acquisition in 1959. [
Footnote 12] In
FTC v. Consolidated Foods Corp.,
380 U. S. 592,
380 U. S. 598,
this Court stated that post-acquisition evidence tending to
diminish the probability or impact of anticompetitive effects might
be considered in a § 7 case.
See also United States v. E.
I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.
S. 586,
353 U. S. 597
et seq., 353 U. S. 602
et seq. But in
Consolidated Foods, supra, and in
United States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.S. at
378 U. S. 463,
the probative value of such evidence was found to be extremely
limited, and judgments against the Government were in each instance
reversed in part because "too much weight" had been given to
post-acquisition events. The need for such a limitation is obvious.
If a demonstration that no anticompetitive effects had occurred at
the time of trial or of judgment constituted a permissible defense
to a § 7 divestiture suit, violators could stave off such
actions
Page 415 U. S. 505
merely by refraining from aggressive or anticompetitive behavior
when such a suit was threatened or pending. [
Footnote 13]
Furthermore, the fact that no concrete anticompetitive symptoms
have occurred does not itself imply that competition has not
already been affected,
"for once the two companies are united, no one knows what the
fate of the acquired company and its competitors would have been
but for the merger."
FTC v. Consolidated Foods, supra, at
380 U. S. 598.
And, most significantly, § 7 deals in "probabilities, not
certainties,"
Brown Shoe v. United States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 323,
and the mere nonoccurrence of a substantial lessening of
competition in the interval between acquisition and trial does not
mean that no substantial lessening will develop thereafter; the
essential question remains whether the probability of such future
impact exists at the time of trial.
Page 415 U. S. 506
In this case, the District Court relied on evidence relating to
changes in the patterns and structure of the coal industry and in
United Electric's coal reserve situation after the time of
acquisition in 1959. Such evidence could not reflect a positive
decision on the part of the merged companies to deliberately but
temporarily refrain from anticompetitive actions, nor could it
reasonably be thought to reflect less active competition than that
which might have occurred had there not been an acquisition in
1959. As the District Court convincingly found, the trend toward
increased dependence on utilities as consumers of coal and toward
the near-exclusive use of long-term contracts was the product of
inevitable pressures on the coal industry in all parts of the
country. And, unlike evidence showing only that no lessening of
competition has yet occurred, the demonstration of weak coal
resources necessarily and logically implied that United Electric
was not merely disinclined, but unable, to compete effectively for
future contracts. Such evidence went directly to the question of
whether future lessening of competition was probable, and the
District Court was fully justified in using it.
Second, the Government contends that reliance on depleted and
committed resources is essentially a "failing company" defense,
which must meet the strict limits placed on that defense by this
Court's decisions in
United States v. Third National Bank in
Nashville, 390 U. S. 171;
Citizen Publishing Co. v. United States, 394 U.
S. 131; and
United States v. Greater Buffalo
Press, 402 U. S. 549. The
failing company doctrine, recognized as a valid defense to a §
7 suit in
Brown Shoe, supra, at
370 U. S. 346,
was first announced by this Court in
International Shoe Co. v.
FTC, 280 U. S. 291, and
was preserved by explicit references in the legislative history of
the modern amendments to § 7. H.R.Rep. No. 1191, 81st Cong.,
1st Sess., 6 (1949); S.Rep. No. 1775, 81st Cong., 2d Sess.,
Page 415 U. S. 507
7 (1950). A company invoking the defense has the burden
[
Footnote 14] of showing
that its "resources [were] so depleted and the prospect of
rehabilitation so remote that it faced the grave probability of a
business failure . . . ,"
International Shoe, supra, at
280 U. S. 302,
and further that it tried and failed to merge with a company other
than the acquiring one,
Citizen Publishing Co., supra, at
394 U. S. 138;
Greater Buffalo Press, supra, at
402 U. S.
555.
The Government asserts that United Electric was a healthy and
thriving company at the time of the acquisition, and could not be
considered on the brink of failure, and also that the appellees
have not shown that Material Service was the only available
acquiring company. These considerations would be significant if the
District Court had found no violation of § 7 by reason of
United Electric's being a failing company, but the District Court's
conclusion was not, as the Government suggests, identical with or
even analogous to such a finding. The failing company defense
presupposes that the effect on competition and the "loss to [the
company's] stockholders and in, jury to the communities where its
plants were operated,"
International Shoe, supra, at
280 U. S. 302,
will be less if a company continues to exist even as a party to a
merger than if it disappears entirely from the market. It is, in a
sense, a "lesser of two evils" approach, in which the possible
threat to competition resulting from an acquisition is deemed
preferable to the adverse impact on competition and other losses if
the company goes out of business. [
Footnote 15]
Page 415 U. S. 508
The appellees' demonstration of United's weak reserves position,
however, proved an entirely different point. Rather than showing
that United would have gone out of business but for the merger with
Material Service, the finding of inadequate reserves went to the
heart of the Government's statistical
prima facie case
based on production figures, and substantiated the District Court's
conclusion that United Electric, even if it remained in the market,
did not have sufficient reserves to compete effectively for
long-term contracts. The failing company defense is simply
inapposite to this finding, and the failure of the appellees to
meet the prerequisites of that doctrine did not detract from the
validity of the court's analysis.
Finally, the Government contends that the factual underpinning
of the District Court's opinion was not supported by the evidence
contained in the record, and should be reevaluated by this Court.
The findings and conclusions of the District Court are, of course,
governed by the "clearly erroneous" standard of Fed.Rule Civ.Proc.
52(a) just as fully on direct appeal to this Court as when a civil
case is being reviewed by a court of appeals. The record in this
case contains thousands of pages of transcript and hundreds of
exhibits. Little purpose would be served by discussing in detail
each of the Government's specific factual contentions. Suffice it
to say that we find the controlling findings and conclusions
contained in the District Court's careful and lengthy opinion to be
supported by the evidence in the record, and not clearly
erroneous.
One factual claim by the Government, however, goes to the heart
of the reasoning of the District Court, and thus is worthy of
explicit note here. The Government
Page 415 U. S. 509
asserts that the paucity of United Electric's coal reserves
could not have the significance perceived by the District Court,
since all companies engaged in extracting minerals at some point
deplete their reserves and then acquire new reserves or the new
technology required to extract more minerals from their existing
holdings. United Electric, the Government suggests, could at any
point either purchase new strip reserves or acquire the expertise
to recover currently held deep reserves.
But the District Court specifically found new strip reserves not
to be available:
"Evidence was presented at trial by experts, by state officials,
by industry witnesses, and by the Government itself indicating that
economically mineable strip reserves that would permit United
Electric to continue operations beyond the life of its present
mines are not available. The Government failed to come forward with
any evidence that such reserves are presently available."
341 F. Supp. at 559. In addition, there was considerable
testimony at trial, apparently credited by the District Court,
indicating that United Electric and others had tried to find
additional strip reserves not already held for coal production, and
had been largely unable to do so.
Moreover, the hypothetical possibility that United Electric
might in the future acquire the expertise to mine deep reserves
proves nothing -- or too much. As the Government pointed out in its
brief and at oral argument, in recent years, a number of companies
with no prior experience in extracting coal have purchased coal
reserves and entered the coal production business in order to
diversify and complement their current operations. The mere
possibility that United Electric, in common with all other
companies with the inclination and the corporate treasury to do so,
could some day expand into an essentially new line of business does
not depreciate the validity of
Page 415 U. S. 510
the conclusion that United Electric, at the time, of the trial
did not have the power to compete on a significant scale for the
procurement of future long-term contracts, nor does it vest in the
production statistics relied on by the Government more significance
than ascribed to them by the District Court.
IV
In addition to contending that the District Court erred in
finding that the acquisition of United Electric would not
substantially lessen competition, the Government urges us to review
the court's determinations of the proper product and geographic
markets. The Government suggests that, while the "energy market"
might have been an appropriate "line of commerce," coal also had
sufficient "practical indicia" as a separate "line of commerce" to
qualify as an independent and consistent submarket.
Cf. United
States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.S. at
378 U. S.
456-457. It also suggests that, irrespective of the
validity of the criteria adopted by the District Court in selecting
its 10 geographic markets, competition between United Electric and
Material Service within the larger alternative geographic markets
claimed by the Government established those areas as a permissible
"section of the country" within the meaning of § 7.
While, under normal circumstances, a delineation of proper
geographic and product markets is a necessary precondition to
assessment of the probabilities of a substantial effect on
competition within them, in this case we nevertheless affirm the
District Court's judgment without reaching these questions. By
determining that the amount and availability of usable reserves,
and not the past annual production figures relied on by the
Government, were the proper indicators of future ability to
compete, the District Court wholly rejected the Government's
Page 415 U. S. 511
prima facie case. Irrespective of the markets within
which the acquiring and the acquired company might be viewed as
competitors for purposes of this § 7 suit, the Government's
statistical presentation simply did not establish that a
substantial lessening of competition was likely to occur in any
market. By concluding that
"divestiture [would not] benefit competition even were this
court to accept the Government's unrealistic product and geographic
market definitions,"
341 F.
Supp. at 560, the District Court rendered superfluous its
further determinations that the Government also erred in its choice
of relevant markets. Since we agree with the District Court that
the Government's reliance on production statistics in the context
of this case was insufficient, it follows that the judgment before
us may be affirmed without reaching the issues of geographic and
product markets.
The judgment of the District Court is affirmed.
It is so ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
United Electric also had coal mining operations in Utah and
other Western States. The Government has not contended, however,
that these holdings are of any relevance in this case.
[
Footnote 2]
Section 7 of the Clayton Act reads in pertinent part as
follows:
"No corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the
Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the
assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in
any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of
such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to
tend to create a monopoly."
[
Footnote 3]
Testimony at trial indicated that the Eastern Interior Coal
Province -- the area of coal production upon which the Eastern Coal
Province Sales Area was based -- was originally named by United
States Geological Survey maps of the coalfields in the United
States and described one portion of a sequence of coal-bearing rock
formations known geologically as the Pennsylvania System. The Sales
Area of the Eastern Interior Coal Province was derived from the
assumption, acknowledged in the trial court's opinion, that the
high costs of transporting coal -- which may amount to 40% of the
price of delivered coal -- will inevitably give producers of coal a
clear competitive advantage in sales in the immediate areas of the
mines.
[
Footnote 4]
The trial court found that Commonwealth Edison, a large private
electric utility with generation facilities in many parts of
Illinois, and the Metropolitan Chicago Interstate Air Quality
Control Region constituted separate and unique geographic regions.
Commonwealth Edison was found to have unique attributes because of
the great size of its coal consumption requirements, its
distinctive distribution patterns, and its extensive commitment to
air pollution programs and the development of nuclear energy. The
Chicago Control Region, a congressionally designated area
consisting of six counties in Illinois and two in Indiana, was
distinguished from other geographic markets because of the impact
of existing and anticipated air pollution regulations which would
create special problems in the competition for coal sales
contracts.
341 F.
Supp. 534, 557.
[
Footnote 5]
The figures for 1967 reflect the impact on market concentration
of the acquisition involved here.
[
Footnote 6]
The figures demonstrating the degree of concentration in the two
coal markets chosen by the Government were roughly comparable to
those in
United States v. Von's Grocery Co., 384 U.
S. 270, where the top four firms in the market
controlled 24.4% of the sales, the top eight 40.9%, and the top 12
48.8%.
See id. at
384 U. S. 281 (WHITE, J., concurring).
See also
United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.
S. 546,
384 U. S. 551,
where the top four producers of beer in Wisconsin were found to
control 47.74% of the market, and the top 10 in the Nation and the
local three-state area to control 45.06% and 58.93%, respectively.
The statistics in the present case appear to represent a less
advanced state of concentration than those involved in
United
States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.
S. 271,
377 U. S. 279,
where the two largest firms held 50% of the market, and the top
five and the top nine controlled, respectively, 76% and 95.7%; and
in
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 365,
where the two largest banks controlled 44% of the pre-merger
market.
[
Footnote 7]
The percentage increase in concentration asserted here was thus
analogous to that found in
Von's Grocery, supra, where the
concentration among the top four, eight, and 12 firms was
increased, respectively, by 18.0%, 7.6%, and 2.5% as a result of
the merger invalidated there. In
Philadelphia Bank, supra,
the 34% increase in concentration in the two largest firms from 44%
to 59% was found to be clearly significant. 374 U.S. at
374 U. S.
365.
[
Footnote 8]
The 1959 Illinois figure of 23.2% was asserted by the Government
to be comparable to the 23.94% share of the Wisconsin beer market
found to be significant in
Pabst, supra, and the 25% share
controlled by the merged company in
United States v.
Continental Can Co., 378 U. S. 441,
378 U. S. 461.
The Province figure of 12.4% was compared with the shares held by
the merged companies in
Von's Grocery (7.5%), and in the
Pabst national (4.49%) and three-state (11.32%)
markets.
[
Footnote 9]
In 1968, electric utilities accounted for 59.09% of United
States coal consumption, coke plants 18.20%, cement mills 1.88%,
other manufacturing (including steel and rolling mills) 17.70%, and
retail and miscellaneous consumers 3.14%.
[
Footnote 10]
The District Court found that, while United Electric held six
mines operating in the midwest in 1948, it had opened only three
new ones since then, and four had closed because of exhaustion of
reserves. The court found that the evidence showed that reserves in
two other mines would soon be depleted, and the appellees inform us
in their briefs that these events have already occurred.
[
Footnote 11]
As an example of the impact of depleted or committed reserves on
a company's ability to compete for long-term contracts, the
District Court noted that a number of requirements contracts signed
by United Electric to supply coal to electric utilities were backed
up by reserves belonging to Freeman, and "
could not have been
obtained without that guarantee" because of the utilities'
fear that the contract obligation could not otherwise be fulfilled.
341 F. Supp. at 559 (emphasis in original).
[
Footnote 12]
The court's reliance on such facts and the absence of specific
findings of fact concerning the competitive situation in 1959, at
which point both sides now agree the acquisition took place, may
have been engendered by the Government's apparent inconsistency in
its position concerning the critical date. Certain of the
appellees' proposed findings of fact concerning United Electric's
resources in 1959 and its attempts to increase its depleted
holdings were termed "irrelevant" by the Government at the
trial.
[
Footnote 13]
The mere nonoccurrence of anticompetitive effects from a merger
would, of course, merely postpone, rather than preclude, a
divestiture suit. This Court indicated in
United States v. E.
I. du Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U.
S. 586,
353 U. S. 597,
that a merger may be attacked
ab initio long after its
culmination if effect on competition not apparent immediately after
the merger subsequently appears, since § 7 was designed to
arrest the creation of monopolies "
in their incipiency'" and
"`incipiency' . . . denotes not the time the stock was acquired,
but any time when the acquisition threatens to ripen into a
prohibited effect. . . ." See also FTC v. Consolidated Foods
Corp., 380 U. S. 592,
380 U. S. 598.
The scope this "time of suit" concept gives to the Government in
attacking mergers under § 7 is discussed in Orrick, The
Clayton Act: Then and Now, 24 ABA Antitrust Section 44 (1964);
Subcommittee on Section 7, The Backward Sweep Theory and the
Oligopoly Problem, 32 ABA Antitrust L.J. 306 (1966). In the context
of the present case, the "time of suit" rule, coupled with the
limited weight given to post-merger evidence of no anticompetitive
impact, tends to give the Government a "heads-I-win,
tails-you-1ose" advantage over a § 7 defendant: post-merger
evidence showing a lessening of competition may constitute an
"incipiency" on which to base a divestiture suit, but evidence
showing that such lessening has not, in fact, occurred cannot be
accorded "too much weight."
[
Footnote 14]
In
Citizen Publishing Co. v. United States,
394 U. S. 131,
394 U. S.
138-139, "[t]he burden of proving that the conditions of
the failing company doctrine have been satisfied" was found to be
"on those who seek refuge under it." (Footnote omitted.)
[
Footnote 15]
Alternative rationales for the failing company defense are
discussed in Bok, Section 7 of the Clayton Act and the Merging of
Law and Economics, 74 Harv.L.Rev. 226, 339-347 (1960); Comment,
"Substantially to Lessen Competition . . .": Current Problems of
Horizontal Mergers, 68 Yale L.J. 1627, 1662-1668 (1959).
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, with whom MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN, MR. JUSTICE
WHITE, and MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL concur, dissenting.
In this case, the United States appeals from a District Court
decision [
Footnote 2/1] upholding
the acquisition of stock in United Electric Coal Companies by
Material Service Corp. and its successor, General Dynamics Corp.,
against a challenge that the acquisition violated § 7 of the
Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18. [
Footnote 2/2] The United States instituted
Page 415 U. S. 512
this civil antitrust action on the claim that the acquisition
may substantially lessen competition in the Illinois and Eastern
Interior Coal Province (EICP) sales area coal markets. After trial
on the merits, the District Court rejected the Government's
proposed product and geographic markets and dismissed the action,
concluding that the Government had failed to show a substantial
lessening of competition in the markets the court deemed
relevant.
I
The combination here challenged is the union of two major
Illinois coal producers -- Freeman Coal Mining Corp. and United
Electric Coal Companies -- under the ultimate corporate control of
General Dynamics Corp. Material Service Corp. acquired all the
stock of Freeman Coal in 1942, and began to acquire United Electric
stock in 1954. By 1959, holdings in United reached 34%, and
Material Service requested and received representation on United's
board of directors. As a result, Freeman's president was elected
chairman of United's executive committee. "With the affiliation of
Freeman and United Electric thus formalized in 1959, common control
of the two coal companies was achieved."
341 F.
Supp. 534, 537 (1972).
General Dynamics acquired Material Service Corp. in 1959, and
moved to solidify the union of Freeman and United by engaging in
continued purchases of United's stock throughout the early 1960's.
By 1966, it held nearly two-thirds of United's outstanding shares,
and a successful tender offer increased the holdings to over 90%.
In early 1967, United became a wholly owned subsidiary of
Page 415 U. S. 513
General Dynamics. With the 1959 union of Freeman and United
Electric thus completed, the Government filed this action
challenging the legality of the combination which produced in
General Dynamics the Nation's fifth largest coal producer with
total annual production of over 14 million tons.
II
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, the standard against which this
combination must be tested, proscribes such combinations "where in
any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of
such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition. . . ."
[
Footnote 2/3] "Determination of
the relevant market is a necessary predicate to a finding of a
violation of the Clayton Act. . . ."
United States v. E. I. du
Pont de Nemours & Co., 353 U. S. 586,
353 U. S. 593
(1957). The court below concluded that "the energy market is the
appropriate line of commerce for testing the competitive effect of
the United Electric-Freeman combination." 341 F. Supp. at 555. The
court rejected the Government's hypothesis of coal as a submarket
for antitrust purposes as "untenable," finding that
United
States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.
S. 441 (1964),
"compel[s] this court to conclude that, since coal competes with
gas, oil, uranium and other forms of energy, the relevant line of
commerce must encompass inter-fuel competition."
341 F. Supp. at 556.
I read
Continental Can to import no such compulsion.
That case involved the acquisition of the Nation's third largest
producer of glass containers, Hazel-Atlas Glass Co., by Continental
Can, the country's second largest producer of metal containers. The
District Court found inter-industry competition an insufficient
predicate for finding a § 7 line of commerce embracing both
cans and
Page 415 U. S. 514
bottles. We reversed, finding that inter-industry competition
mandated "treating as
a relevant product market the
combined glass and metal container industries and all end uses for
which they compete" 378 U.S. at
378 U. S. 457
(emphasis added). But that inter-industry market was only one of
several lines of commerce in that case. Both parties conceded that
"the can industry and the glass container industry were relevant
lines of commerce."
Id. at
378 U. S. 447.
Since § 7 proscribes acquisitions which may involve a
substantial lessening of competition in any line of commerce, the
absence of anticompetitive effects in either the bottle or can
markets could not sustain the acquisition, since there existed
a market -- the glass/metal container market given
recognition in this Court -- in which the prohibited effect was
present.
The District Court here found an energy market in which the
combination did not work the prohibited effect. Whatever the
correctness of that finding,
Continental Can teaches us
that it is of no help to appellees if there exist other lines of
commerce in which the effect is present. Any combination may
involve myriad lines of commerce; the existence of an energy market
is not inconsistent with, and does not negate, the existence of a
narrower coal market for "within this broad market, well defined
submarkets may exist which, in themselves, constitute product
markets for antitrust purposes."
Brown Shoe Co. v. United
States, 370 U. S. 294,
370 U. S. 325
(1962).
This principle found recognition in
Continental Can,
where we recognized glass and metal containers "to be two separate
lines of commerce," despite finding that competition between the
lines "necessarily implied one or more
other lines of
commerce embracing both industries." 378 U.S. at
378 U. S.
456-457 (emphasis added). It was also recognized in
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.
S. 271 (1964), which involved the combination
Page 415 U. S. 515
of an aluminum conductor manufacturer and a producer of both
aluminum and copper conductor. The District Court there refused to
treat aluminum conductor as a separate § 7 line of commerce
because of the competition between aluminum and copper conductor.
Though we found that competition sufficient to justify finding a
single aluminum/copper conductor market, we reversed the District
Court, holding that the inter-industry competition did not preclude
"division [of that market] for purposes of § 7 into separate
submarkets."
Id. at
377 U. S. 275.
[
Footnote 2/4] Coal has both price
advantages and operational disadvantages which combine to delineate
within the energy market "economically significant submarket[s]."
[
Footnote 2/5] The consumers for
whom price is determinative mark out a submarket in which coal is
the overwhelming choice; the boundaries of this submarket are
strengthened by coal's virtual inability to compete in other
significant sectors of the energy market. Energy-use technology in
highway and air transportation necessitates the use of liquid
fuels. The relative operational ease of dieselized power plants has
worked to virtually foreclose coal from the rail transportation
market. [
Footnote 2/6] Despite
their higher cost, gas and oil enjoy a competitive edge in the
space-heating market because of simple consumer preference for
these sources of energy over coal. [
Footnote 2/7]
The market for coal is therefore effectively limited to large
industrial energy consumers such as electric utilities and certain
manufacturers with the ability and economic
Page 415 U. S. 516
incentive to consider coal as an energy source. [
Footnote 2/8] The court below noted that the
"utility market has become the mainstay of coal production," 341 F.
Supp. at 539. Within this sector, coal's economic advantage yields
it an overwhelming share of the market. In each year from 1960 to
1967 (the period during which the Freeman-United Electric union
solidified), coal accounted for over 90% of the Btu's consumed by
steam electric utility plants in the EICP sales area; it also
provided 74% of the Btu's consumed by cement plants in the same
area, and 94% of the Btu's consumed by such plants in Illinois,
[
Footnote 2/9]
The coal market is therefore viewed by energy consumers as a
separate economic entity confined to those users with the
technological capability to allow the use of coal and the incentive
for economy to mandate it. Within that market, coal experiences
little competition from other fuels, since coal's delivered price
per Btu, in the areas served by Freeman and United Electric, is
significantly lower than that for any other combustible fuel except
interruptible natural gas, which is available only on a seasonal
basis. [
Footnote 2/10] Central
Illinois Light Co., for example, purchases coal at 27 cents per
million Btu's,
Page 415 U. S. 517
firm natural gas at 45 cents, and oil (for ignition purposes) at
70 cents. [
Footnote 2/11] Since
coal consumption facilities are unique and not readily adaptable to
alternative energy sources, there is little inter-fuel price
sensitivity. As the court in
Kennecott Copper Corp. v.
FTC, 467 F.2d 67, 79 (CA10 1972), stated in finding that
"[t]he coal industry is a distinct submarket which has
characteristics which are not shared by the other fuel industries,"
coal prices "are now, and promise to be in the future, subject to
the peculiarities of the coal business, [since] other fuels appear
to have a limited effect."
The competitive position of coal is thus not unlike that of
aluminum conductor in
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America,
supra. Like coal, aluminum conductor had "little consumer
acceptance" for many purposes, but its substantial price advantage
over other conductors gave it "decisive advantages" in those areas
of the market where price was "the single, most important,
practical factor." 377 U.S. at
377 U. S.
275-276. Despite the existence of some competition from
other forms of conductor, those factors were sufficient to set
aluminum conductor apart as an economically significant § 7
submarket. That precedent seems to be indistinguishable; and, thus,
whatever the existence of a § 7 energy market, coal
constitutes an economically significant submarket for § 7
purposes. [
Footnote 2/12]
III
In rejecting the Government's proposed geographic markets the
court below adopted much narrower markets
Page 415 U. S. 518
which, for the most part, followed ICC freight rate districts
(FRD's). [
Footnote 2/13] The
justification was that, since ordinary rail rates are the same for
all mines in any particular FRD, and since transportation costs are
the principal competitive factor in coal marketing, mines in one
FRD cannot effectively compete for the same customers with mines in
other FRD's. Since United Electric's mines are located in the
Belleville and Fulton-Peoria FRD's and Freeman's mines are located
in the Springfield and Southern Illinois FRD's, the combination of
the two companies was found to present no risk of anticompetitive
effects. The error of the District Court in drawing the § 7
sections of the country "so narrowly as to place appellees in
different markets" [
Footnote
2/14] is amply demonstrated by the overlapping distribution
patterns of Freeman and United Electric. Though located in
different FRD's and thus supposedly not competitive, they sold
one-half their output to the same customers at the same facilities.
Lack of competition between FRD's is further refuted by the
existence of reciprocal selling patterns. For example,
Page 415 U. S. 519
while United's Belleville FRD mine was selling 25% of its output
to customers in the Southern Illinois FRD sales area, Freeman was
selling 20% of its Southern Illinois FRD coal to Belleville sales
area customers.
The inability of the lower court's narrow markets to
"
correspond to the commercial realities'" [Footnote 2/15] of the distribution patterns
displayed in the record is explained by the undue weight given
ordinary rail rates. While transportation costs are significant,
ordinary rail rates are not the single controlling element of
transportation costs. First, not all rail shipments are governed by
FRD rates; many of the most significant shipments are transported
via "unit trains" carrying only coal from a particular producer to
a particular customer pursuant to a negotiated rate. Thus, Freeman
ships Southern Illinois FRD coal by unit train to a Belleville FRD
sales area customer at a cost lower than any Belleville FRD rate to
that location. Second, not all coal transportation proceeds by
rail. United transports most of its coal by barge, and, in 1967,
only one-half of all the coal sold in the five States which receive
coal from Illinois was transported by all-rail shipments.
Normal rail rates are thus not so limiting as to eliminate
substantial competition between FRD sales areas. Coal producers may
constitute strong competitive factors in areas up to 500 miles from
the mine. Thus, in 1967, Freeman's Southern Illinois FRD Orient
Mine shipped over 1.5 million tons of coal to customers 300 to 500
miles away. At the same time, United's Fidelity Mine, only 40 miles
from the Orient, shipped more than one million tons, over half its
total production, to equally distant locations. Both Freeman and
United Electric have mines which are capable of supplying any point
in the EICP sales area.
Page 415 U. S. 520
Further, even assuming the existence of FRD markets, I think the
court below erred in rejecting the Government's proposed markets.
As with product markets, § 7 does not necessitate an
anticompetitive effect in any particular geographic market; its
proscription reaches combinations which may substantially lessen
competition in any section of the country. Thus, whatever the
correctness of the District Court in finding FRD markets, the lack
of anticompetitive effect in those markets is of no help to General
Dynamics if competition may be lessened substantially in other
geographic markets. And, as with product markets, the existence of
FRD markets is not inconsistent with the existence of a myriad of
other sometimes overlapping markets. Thus, in
United States v.
Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U. S. 546
(1966), we found Wisconsin, the Wisconsin-Michigan-Illinois
tri-state area, and the entire United States all to be relevant
§ 7 sections of the country in which to assess anticompetitive
impact.
While existing sales patterns show that transportation costs are
not as restrictive as the District Court found, long-range
transportation costs and the national distribution of coal deposits
serve to divide the country into regionally significant coal
markets. Both Freeman and United Electric are located in the EICP,
consisting of Central and Southern Illinois, Southwestern Indiana,
and Western Kentucky, and parts of other nearby areas. The region
overlies a geologically united coal-bearing rock sequence which is
estimated to contain 36% of the Nation's total coal resources.
Because of the separation of the region from other major producing
regions, [
Footnote 2/16]
Page 415 U. S. 521
EICP producers enjoy a substantial competitive edge with respect
to sales in an area composed of Illinois, Indiana, Western
Kentucky, parts of Tennessee Eastern Iowa, Southeastern Minnesota,
Southern Wisconsin, and extreme Eastern Missouri. In 1967, 825 of
EICP coal was sold in this area. Freeman sold over 93% of its coal,
and United Electric sold over 97% of its coal in this area.
Within the EICP sales area, Illinois stands as an economically
significant submarket. In 1967, 82% of the coal consumed in
Illinois came from Illinois mines, and 58,% of the coal mined in
the State was used there. Freeman sold 42% of its coal and United
Electric sold 62% of its coal to Illinois consumers, more than
either company sold in any other State. Since Illinois sales are
dominated by Illinois producers, and since all relevant Freeman and
United Electric Mines are located in Illinois, [
Footnote 2/17] the State constitutes a relevant
and significant market for § 7 purposes. Although economic
lines do not fall precisely along political boundaries, the
Government is not required to delineate § 7 markets by "metes
and bounds."
United States v. Pabst Brewing, supra at
384 U. S. 549.
In holding a four-county group a relevant geographic market in
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.
S. 321 (1963), we noted the artificiality of such
political boundaries, but held that "such fuzziness would seem
inherent in any attempt to delineate the relevant geographic
market."
Id. at
374 U. S. 360
n. 37. The State of Wisconsin was held a relevant market in
Pabst Brewing, supra, and, in
United States v. El Paso
Gas Co., 376 U. S. 651,
376 U. S. 657
(1964), we held that there could be "no
Page 415 U. S. 522
doubt that California is a
section of the country' as that
phrase is used in § 7."
IV
While finding no violation of § 7 in the Freeman-United
Electric combination, the District Court did not make clear the
standard used in reaching that ultimate conclusion. The court did
not mention what it thought to be the relevant market shares, nor
did it discuss the effect of the combination on industry
concentration. The court merely found that Freeman and United
Electric do not compete, because they are located in different FRD
geographic markets and because they sell different types of coal.
As already discussed, nearly all the mines of both companies are
located in Southern Illinois, and, as demonstrated by past
distribution patterns, with an ability to compete effectively at
distances up to 500 miles, their presence in different minute FRD's
within Southern Illinois has simply not rendered them
noncompetitive. The differences in the types of coal sold,
moreover, are irrelevant. It is true, as the court below notes,
that United Electric sells strip-mined coal, while Freeman extracts
deep reserves, but the fact that the companies sold half their
output to common customers demonstrates that at least a significant
portion of the consuming public is understandably unconcerned with
the details of extraction. While it is also true that only Freeman
sells metallurgical coal and a byproduct known as dust, this says
nothing more than that the companies do not compete in
metallurgical coal or dust; it does not relieve the court of the
responsibility for evaluating the anticompetitive effects in
nonmetallurgical coal production -- production which accounts for
100% of United's and 92% of Freeman's business. [
Footnote 2/18]
Page 415 U. S. 523
The court further found that United Electric, standing alone,
would not contribute meaningfully to further competition, since
virtually all its economically mineable strip reserves were
committed under long-term contracts, and it possessed neither the
capability to obtain more strip reserves nor the expertise to
develop its deep reserves. Although the doctrine was not invoked by
name, this appears to be an application of the "failing company"
defense.
See Citizen Publishing Co. v. United States,
394 U. S. 131
(1969). If it is, the court proceeded on an analysis made at the
wrong time, and failed to discuss the legal standards employed in
finding the defense to be established. The finding that 48 of
United's 52 million tons of strip reserves were committed related
to the time of trial. But, since the rationale of the failing
company defense is the lack of anticompetitive consequence if one
of the combining companies was about to disappear from the market
at any rate, the viability of the "failing company" must be
assessed as of the time of the merger.
United States v. Greater
Buffalo Press, 402 U. S. 549,
402 U. S. 555
(1971);
Citizen Publishing Co. v. United States, supra, at
138.
The Court urges that United's weak reserve position, rather than
establishing a failing company defense, "went to the heart of the
Government's statistical
prima facie case based on
production figures." Under this view, United's weak reserve
position at the time of trial constitutes post-acquisition evidence
which diminishes the possibility of anticompetitive impact, and
thus directly affects the strength of time-of-acquisition findings.
The problem
Page 415 U. S. 524
with this analysis is that the District Court made no
time-of-acquisition findings which such post-acquisition evidence
could affect. The majority concedes the obvious need for a
limitation on the weight given post-acquisition evidence and notes
that we have reversed cases where "too much weight" has been given.
Here, the post-acquisition events were given all the weight because
all the District Court's findings were made as of the time of the
trial. While findings made as of the time of the merger could
concededly be tempered to a limited degree by post-acquisition
events, no such findings were ever made. Many of the commitments
here which reduced United's available reserves occurred after the
acquisition; 21 million tons, for example, were committed in 1968.
Similarly, though the District Court found further mineable strip
reserves unavailable at the time of trial, there is no finding that
they were unavailable in 1959 or 1967. To the contrary, the record
demonstrates that other coal producers did acquire new strip
reserves during the 1960's. [
Footnote
2/19] United's 1959 viability is further supported by the fact
that it possessed 27 million tons of deep reserves. While we do not
know if all these reserves were economically mineable at the time
of the acquisition, there was no finding that they would not become
so in the near future with advances in technology or changes in the
price structure of the coal market. [
Footnote 2/20] Further, there was no contention or
finding that further deep reserves were not available for
acquisition. [
Footnote 2/21] The
District Court
Page 415 U. S. 525
merely concluded that United had no "ability to develop deep
coal reserves." [
Footnote
2/22]
While it is true that United is a strip-mining company which has
not extracted deep reserves since 1954, this does not mean that
United would not develop deep mining expertise if deep reserves
were all it had left, or that it could not sell the reserves to
some company which poses less of a threat to increased
concentration in the coal market than does Freeman. United Electric
was not, as the Court suggests, merely one of many companies with
the possible "inclination and the corporate treasury" to allow
expansion into "an essentially new line of business." United was a
coal company with a thriving coal marketing structure. At the time
of the merger, it had access to at least 27 million tons of deep
reserves, and it had operated a deep mine only five years
previously. While deep coal mining may have been an essentially new
line of business for many, it was for United merely a matter of
regaining the expertise it once had to extract reserves it already
owned for sale in a market where it already had a good name.
Page 415 U. S. 526
V
Thus, from product and geographic markets to market share and
industry concentration analysis to the failing company defense, the
findings below are based on legal standards which are either
incorrect or not disclosed. While the court did gratuitously state
that no § 7 violation would be found "even were this court to
accept the Government's unrealistic product and market
definitions," this conclusory statement is supported by no analysis
sufficient to allow review in this Court. The majority notes that
production figures are of limited significance because they include
deliveries under long-term contracts entered into in prior years.
It is true that uncommitted reserves or sales of previously
uncommitted coal would be preferable indicia of competitive
strength, but the District Court made
no findings as to
United's or Freeman's respective market shares at the time of the
acquisition under either of these standards. [
Footnote 2/23]
Page 415 U. S. 527
On the basis of a record so devoid of findings based on correct
legal standards, the judgment may not be affirmed except on a
deep-seated judicial bias against § 7 of the Clayton Act. We
should remand the case to the District Court with directions to
assess the impact of the Freeman-United Electric combination on the
Illinois and EICP sales area coal markets as of 1959. [
Footnote 2/24] We should direct the court
to make findings of respective market shares, and further to
evaluate United Electric's viability as an independent producer or
as the possible "acquiree" of a company other than General Dynamics
as of 1959, in light of the strict standards applicable to the
failing company defense. Since we abdicate our duty for responsible
review and accept the mere conclusion that no § 7 violation is
established on the basis of a record with none of these necessary
findings, I dissent from the affirmance of the District Court's
judgment.
[
Footnote 2/1]
341 F.
Supp. 534 (1972).
[
Footnote 2/2]
Title 15 U.S.C. § 18 provides:
"No corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the
Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the
assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in
any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of
such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to
tend to create a monopoly."
[
Footnote 2/3]
Supra 415
U.S. 486fn2/2|>n.2.
[
Footnote 2/4]
Similarly, in
United States v. Philadelphia National
Bank, 374 U. S. 321
(1963), we held commercial banking a § 7 line of commerce even
though banks compete with other institutions with respect to some
services such as the making of small loans.
[
Footnote 2/5]
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.
S. 294,
370 U. S. 325
(1962).
[
Footnote 2/6]
341 F. Supp. at 539.
[
Footnote 2/7]
Ibid.
[
Footnote 2/8]
The only other significant use for coal is metallurgical in
nature. Metallurgical coal is used as a product in the manufacture
of steel. The use of such coal as a product sets it off in a
separate market from nonmetallurgical coal, which is used as an
energy source.
[
Footnote 2/9]
Although nuclear and geothermal power may draw some utility
consumers from the coal market in the future, nuclear fuel is not
consumable in existing fossil-fuel plants, nor is nuclear fuel
presently an alternative for nonutility coal consumers. Thus,
whatever the future inroads of alternative fuels, there remains a
significant class of energy consumers which looks only to coal.
[
Footnote 2/10]
Interruptible gas is sold at a lower rate and is available only
when it is not required by firm-rate customers which are supplied
according to their needs, and which always have priority.
[
Footnote 2/11]
Oil is used by some coal consumers for purposes to which coal is
not suited, such as starting up boilers or kilns.
[
Footnote 2/12]
Even the court below gave some recognition to coal as a separate
market in its discussion of the relevant geographic markets. The
geographic markets were delineated along "the distributive patterns
of . . . coal," separating out those "mines to which
coal
consumers can practicably turn for supplies." 341 F. Supp. at 556
(emphasis added).
[
Footnote 2/13]
Freight rate districts are producing areas grouped for ICC
ratemaking purposes; all mines within each producing area are
accorded the same rates to the same consuming destinations.
See
Ayrshire Collieries Corp. v. United States, 335 U.
S. 573,
335 U. S. 576
(1949). The other markets accepted by the District Court are
Commonwealth Edison and the Metropolitan Chicago Interstate Air
Quality Control Region. Commonwealth Edison was found to be unique
in light of its massive coal requirements, its purchasing patterns,
which are "quite distinct from [those] followed by other
consumers," and its singularly extensive commitment to nuclear
energy. The MCIAQC, consisting of six Northeastern Illinois
counties and two Northwestern Indiana counties, was found unique
because of its singular access, through water and rail arteries, to
almost all FRD's in the Midwest.
[
Footnote 2/14]
See United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374
U.S. at
374 U. S.
361.
[
Footnote 2/15]
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S.
336.
[
Footnote 2/16]
The Nation's other major coal producing regions are: (1) the
Eastern Coal Province of Western Pennsylvania, West Virginia,
Eastern Kentucky, and parts of Ohio, Tennessee, and Alabama; (2)
the Western Interior Coal Province comprised of Central Iowa,
Northern and Western Missouri, and Eastern Oklahoma; and (3)
scattered deposits in Montana, Wyoming, Colorado, and Utah.
Jurisdictional Statement 5.
[
Footnote 2/17]
United Electric also controls some coal deposits in Colorado and
Oklahoma which are not in issue in this case. 341 F. Supp. at 538
n. 8.
[
Footnote 2/18]
The lack of competition from United for a mere 8% of Freeman's
business is simply irrelevant. In
United States v. Aluminum Co.
of America, 377 U. S. 271
(1964), we struck down a combination which affected competition in
the aluminum conductor market, and that result was not affected by
the irrelevant fact that one of the companies, Rome Cable, also
engaged in the production of copper conductor.
[
Footnote 2/19]
See Brief for United States 71.
[
Footnote 2/20]
Research into new methods of extraction or a rise in the price
of coal could make reserves which are uneconomical to mine at any
given time economically mineable in the future.
[
Footnote 2/21]
To the contrary, United Electric acquired substantial new deep
reserves after the time of the acquisition, since it now owns about
44 million tons of deep reserves and controls by location another
40 to 50 million tons. Reserves are controlled by location if, in
order to be mined at all, they must be mined by those who control,
by ownership, lease, or option, the contiguous reserves.
[
Footnote 2/22]
If that conclusion is to lend support to the combination on the
ground that United "standing alone, cannot contribute meaningfully
to competition," it must be made in light of the stringent
standards applicable to the failing company defense. In
Citizen
Publishing Co. v. United States, 394 U.
S. 131,
394 U. S. 138
139 (1969), we said that the defense is one of "narrow scope," and
that the burden of proving the defense is "on those who seek refuge
under it." We also stated that the prospects of continued
independent existence must be "dim or nonexistent," and that it
must be established that the acquiring company is the only
available purchaser.
See also United States v. Greater Buffalo
Press, 402 U. S. 549,
402 U. S.
555-556 (1971), and
United States v. Third National
Bank in Nashville, 390 U. S. 171,
390 U. S. 189
(1968).
[
Footnote 2/23]
The District Court did find that, as of 1968, Freeman controlled
6.5% of the total coal reserves dedicated to existing mines in the
EICP. At the same time, United Electric controlled 2.5% of that
total, but almost all of this was contractually committed. If
market shares are to be determined by percentage of total reserves,
what is necessary is a finding as to each company's 1959 share of
uncommitted Illinois and EICP reserves -- including reserves which
were economically mineable or which might have become so in the
reasonably near future, and further including an estimate as to
uncontrolled reserves which might have been acquired by either
company in the reasonably near future.
The District Court also found that, as of 1968, the two
companies together accounted for 10.9% of the EICP coal production,
and that this figure represented more than a 10% decrease from the
combined production for 1959. Combined 1959 production by the
companies was thus at least 12.1% of the EICP total. If market
shares are to be determined by percentage of industry sales, this
figure is in excess of percentages found illegal in markets with a
trend toward concentration (
see, e.g., United States v. Von's
Grocery Co., 384 U. S. 270
(1966) (7.5%), and
United States v. Pabst Brewing Co.,
384 U. S. 546
(1966) (4.49%)), and the court below recognized an increase in
concentration in the coal market. It might be argued, however,
that, if market share is to be determined by sales, the production
figures found by the court below are not the relevant ones, for
they include production which goes to meet obligations incurred in
long-term contracts entered into in prior years. In terms of
competition, if sales are the relevant criteria, what is needed is
a finding of "new" sales (sales of previously uncommitted coal) as
a percentage of total industry new sales in Illinois and the EICP
at the time of the acquisition.
[
Footnote 2/24]
Common control of the two companies was achieved in 1959, and
the combination was completed in 1967; at oral argument, both
parties conceded that the merger "took place" in 1959.