Respondent Falstaff, the Nation's fourth largest beer producer,
which was desirous of achieving national status, agreed to acquire
the largest seller of beer in the New England market rather than
enter
de novo. The District Court dismissed the
Government's resultant suit charging violation of § 7 of the
Clayton Act, finding that entry by acquisition, which the court
found was the only way that respondent intended to penetrate the
New England market, would not result in a substantial lessening of
competition.
Held: The District Court erred in assuming that,
because respondent would not have entered the market
de
novo, it could not be considered a potential competitor. The
court should have considered whether respondent was a potential
competitor in the sense that its position on the edge of the market
exerted a beneficial influence on the market's competitive
conditions. Pp.
410 U. S.
531-538.
332 F.
Supp. 970, reversed and remanded.
WHITE, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which BURGER,
C.J., and BLACKMUN, J., joined, and in Part I of which DOUGLAS, J.,
joined. DOUGLAS, J., filed an opinion concurring in part,
post, p.
410 U. S. 538.
MARSHALL, J., filed an opinion concurring in the result,
post p.
410 U. S. 545.
REHNQUIST, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which STEWART, J.,
joined,
post, p.
410 U. S. 572.
BRENNAN, J., took no part in the decision of the case. POWELL, J.,
took no part in the consideration or decision of the case.
Page 410 U. S. 527
MR. JUSTICE WHITE delivered the opinion of the Court.
Alleging that Falstaff Brewing Corp.'s acquisition of the
Narragansett Brewing Co. in 1965 violated § 7 of the Clayton
Act, 38 Stat. 731, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 18, [
Footnote 1] the United States brought this
antitrust suit under the theory that potential competition in the
New England beer market may be substantially lessened by the
acquisition. The District Court held to the contrary,
332 F.
Supp. 970 (1971), and we noted probable jurisdiction [
Footnote 2] to determine whether the
trial court applied an erroneous legal standard in so deciding, 405
U.S. 952 (1972). We remand to the District Court for a proper
assessment of Falstaff as a potential competitor.
As stipulated by the parties, the relevant product market is the
production and sale of beer, and the six New England States
[
Footnote 3] compose the
geographic market. While beer sales in New England increased
approximately 9.5% in the four years preceding the acquisition, the
eight largest sellers increased their share of these sales from
approximately 74% to 81.2%. In 1960, approximately 50% of the sales
were made by the four largest sellers; by 1964, their share of the
market was 54%; and,
Page 410 U. S. 528
by 1965, the year of acquisition, their share was 61.3%. The
number of brewers operating plants in the geographic market
decreased from 32 in 1935, to 11 in 1957, to six in 1964. [
Footnote 4]
Of the Nation's 10 largest brewers in 1964, only Falstaff and
two others did not sell beer in New England; Falstaff was the
largest of the three, and had the closest brewery. [
Footnote 5] In relation to the New England
market, Falstaff sold its product in western Ohio, to the west and
in Washington, D.C. to the south.
The acquired firm, Narragansett, was the largest seller of beer
in New England at the time of its acquisition, with approximately
20% of the market; had been the largest seller for the five
preceding years; had constantly expanded its brewery capacity
between 1960 and 1965; and had acquired either the assets or the
trademarks of several smaller brewers in and around the geographic
market.
The fourth largest producer of beer in the United States at the
time of acquisition, Falstaff was a regional brewer [
Footnote 6] with 5.9% of the Nation's
production in 1964, having grown steadily since its beginning as a
brewer in 1933 through acquisition and expansion of other
breweries. As of January, 1965, Falstaff sold beer in 32 States,
but did not sell in the Northeast, an area composed of New England
and States such as New York and New Jersey, the area being the
highest beer consumption region in the
Page 410 U. S. 529
United States. Between 1955 and 1966, the company's net sales
and net income almost doubled, and, in 1964, it was planning a
10-year, $35 million program to expand its existing plants.
Falstaff met increasingly strong competition in the 1960's from
four brewers who sold in all of the significant markets. National
brewers possess competitive advantages, since they are able to
advertise on a nationwide basis, their beers have greater prestige
than regional or local beers, and they are less affected by the
weather or labor problems in a particular region. Thus, Falstaff
concluded that it must convert from "regional" to "national"
status, if it was to compete effectively with the national
producers. [
Footnote 7] For
several years, Falstaff publicly expressed its desire for national
distribution, [
Footnote 8] and,
after making several efforts in the early 1960's to enter the
Northeast by acquisition, agreed to acquire Narragansett in
1965.
Before the acquisition was accomplished, the United States
brought suit, [
Footnote 9]
alleging that the acquisition would violate § 7 because its
effect may be to substantially lessen competition in the production
and sale of beer in the New England market. This contention was
based on two grounds: because Falstaff was a potential entrant
Page 410 U. S. 530
and because the acquisition eliminated competition that would
have existed had Falstaff entered the market
de novo or by
acquisition and expansion of a smaller firm, a so-called "toe-hold"
acquisition. [
Footnote 10]
The acquisition was completed after the Government's motions for
injunctive relief were denied, and Falstaff agreed to operate
Narragansett as a separate subsidiary until otherwise ordered by
the court.
After a trial on the merits, the District Court found that the
geographic market was highly competitive; that Falstaff was
desirous of becoming a national brewer by entering the Northeast;
that its management was committed against
de novo entry;
and that competition had not diminished since the acquisition.
[
Footnote 11] The District
Court then held:
"The Government's contentions that Falstaff at the time of said
acquisition was a potential entrant into said New England market,
and that said acquisition deprived the New England market of
additional competition are not supported by the evidence. On the
contrary, the credible evidence establishes beyond a reasonable
doubt that the executive management of Falstaff had consistently
decided not to attempt to enter said market unless it could acquire
a brewery with a strong and viable distribution system such as that
possessed by Narragansett. Said executives had carefully considered
such possible alternatives as (1) acquisition of a small brewery on
the east coast, (2) the shipping of beer from its
Page 410 U. S. 531
existing breweries, the nearest of which was located in Ft.
Wayne, Indiana, (3) the building of a new brewery on the east coast
and other possible alternatives, but concluded that none of said
alternatives would have effected a reasonable probability of a
profitable entry for it in said New England market. In my
considered opinion, the plaintiff has failed to establish by a fair
preponderance of the evidence that Falstaff was a potential
competitor in said New England market at the time it acquired
Narragansett. The credible evidence establishes that it was not a
potential entrant into said market by any means or way other than
by said acquisition. Consequently it cannot be said that its
acquisition of Narragansett eliminated it as a potential competitor
therein."
332 F. Supp. at 972.
Also finding that the Government had failed to establish that
the acquisition would result in a substantial lessening of
competition, the District Court entered Judgment for Falstaff and
dismissed the complaint.
I
Section 7 of the Clayton Act forbids mergers in any line of
commerce where the effect may be substantially to lessen
competition or tend to create a monopoly. The section proscribes
many mergers between competitors in a market,
United States v.
Continental Can Co., 378 U. S. 441
(1964);
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.
S. 294 (1962); it also bars certain acquisitions of a
market competitor by a noncompetitor, such as a merger by an
entrant who threatens to dominate the market or otherwise upset
market conditions to the detriment of competition,
FTC v.
Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U. S. 568,
386 U. S.
578-580 (1967). Suspect also is the acquisition by a
company not competing in the market but so situated
Page 410 U. S. 532
as to be a potential competitor and likely to exercise
substantial influence on market behavior. Entry through merger by
such a company, although its competitive conduct in the market may
be the mirror image of that of the acquired company, may
nevertheless violate § 7 because the entry eliminates a
potential competitor exercising present influence on the market.
Id. at
386 U. S.
580-581;
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical
Co., 378 U. S. 158,
378 U. S.
173-174 (1964). As the Court stated in
United States
v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., supra, at
378 U. S.
174,
"The existence of an aggressive, well equipped and well financed
corporation engaged in the same or related lines of commerce
waiting anxiously to enter an oligopolistic market would be a
substantial incentive to competition which cannot be
underestimated."
In the case before us, Falstaff was not a competitor in the New
England market, nor is it contended that its merger with
Narragansett represented an entry by a dominant market force. It
was urged, however, that Falstaff was a potential competitor so
situated that its entry by merger, rather than
de novo,
violated § 7. The District Court, however, relying heavily on
testimony of Falstaff officers, concluded that the company had no
intent to enter the New England market except through acquisition,
and that it therefore could not be considered a potential
competitor in that market. Having put aside Falstaff as a potential
de novoo competitor, it followed for the District Court
that entry by a merger would not adversely affect competition in
New England.
The District Court erred as a matter of law. The error lay in
the assumption that, because Falstaff, as a matter of fact, would
never have entered the market
de novo, it could in no
sense be considered a potential competitor. More specifically, the
District Court failed to give separate consideration to whether
Falstaff was a potential competitor in the sense that it was so
positioned
Page 410 U. S. 533
on the edge of the market that it exerted beneficial influence
on competitive conditions in that market.
A similar error was committed by the Court of Appeals in
FTC
v. Procter & Gamble Co., supra, where one of the reasons
for the Commission's finding the acquisition in violation of §
7 was that the merger eliminated Procter as a potential entrant,
not because Procter would have entered independently, but because
the acquisition eliminated the procompetitive effect Procter
exerted from the fringe of the market.
Id. at
386 U. S. 575.
The Court of Appeals struck down this finding because there was no
evidence that Procter ever intended
de novo entry, but we
held the Commission's finding was "amply supported by the
evidence,"
id. at
386 U. S. 581, because the evidence "clearly show[ed]
that Procter was the most likely entrant,"
id. at
386 U. S. 580,
and it was "clear that the existence of Procter at the edge of the
industry exerted considerable influence on the market,"
id. at
386 U. S. 581.
Thus, the fact that Falstaff and its management had no intent to
enter
de novo, and would not have done so, does not,
ipso facto, dispose of the potential competition
issue.
The specific question with respect to this phase of the case is
not what Falstaff's internal company decisions were, but whether,
given its financial capabilities and conditions in the New England
market, it would be reasonable to consider it a potential entrant
into that market. Surely it could not be said on this record that
Falstaff's general interest in the New England market was unknown;
[
Footnote 12] and if it
would appear to rational beer merchants in New England that
Falstaff might well build a new brewery to supply the northeastern
market, then its entry by merger becomes suspect under § 7.
The District Court should therefore have appraised the economic
facts about Falstaff and the New England market
Page 410 U. S. 534
in order to determine whether, in any realistic sense, Falstaff
could be said to be a potential competitor on the fringe of the
market with likely influence on existing competition. [
Footnote 13] This does not mean that
the testimony
Page 410 U. S. 535
of company officials about actual intentions of the company is
irrelevant or is to be looked upon with suspicion; but it does mean
that theirs is not necessarily the last
Page 410 U. S. 536
word in arriving at a conclusion about how Falstaff should be
considered in terms of its status as a potential entrant into the
market in issue.
Page 410 U. S. 537
Since it appears that the District Court entertained too narrow
a view of Falstaff as a potential competitor, and since it appears
that the District Court's conclusion that the merger posed no
probable threat to competition followed automatically from the
finding that Falstaff had no intent to enter
de novo, we
remand this case for the District Court to make the proper
assessment of Falstaff as a potential competitor.
II
Because we remand for proper assessment of Falstaff as an "on
the fringe" potential competitor, it is not necessary to reach the
question of whether § 7 bars a market-extension merger by a
company whose entry into the market would have no influence
whatsoever on the present state of competition in the market --
that is, the entrant will not be a dominant force in the market,
and has no current influence in the marketplace. We leave for
another day the question of the applicability of § 7 to a
merger that will leave competition in the marketplace exactly as it
was, neither hurt nor helped, and that is challengeable under
§ 7 only on grounds that the company could, but did not, enter
de novo or through "toe-hold" acquisition, and that there
is less competition than there would have been had entry been in
such a manner. There are traces of this view in our cases,
see
Ford Motor Co. v. United States, 405 U.
S. 562,
405 U. S. 567
(1972);
id. at
405 U. S. 587
(BURGER, C.J., concurring in part and dissenting in part);
FTC
v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. at
386 U. S. 580;
id. at
386 U. S. 586
(Harlan, J., concurring);
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical
Co., 378 U.S. at
378 U. S. 173,
but the Court has not squarely faced the question, [
Footnote 14] if for no other reason than
because there has
Page 410 U. S. 538
been no necessity to consider it.
See Ford Motor Co. v.
United States, supra; FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., supra;
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., supra; United States v. El
Paso Natural Gas Co., 376 U. S. 651
(1964).
The judgment of the District Court dismissing the complaint
against Falstaff is reversed, and the case is remanded for further
proceedings consistent with this opinion.
So ordered.
MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN took no part in the decision of this case.
MR. JUSTICE POWELL took no part in the consideration or decision of
this case.
[
Footnote 1]
Section 7 provides in relevant part:
"No corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the
Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the
assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in
any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of
such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to
tend to create a monopoly."
15 U.S.C. § 18. For the legislative history of the
amendment in 1950 that greatly expanded the section's scope, 64
Stat. 1125,
see Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U. S. 294,
370 U. S.
311-323 (1962).
[
Footnote 2]
Jurisdiction lies under § 2 of the Expediting Act, 32 Stat.
823, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 29.
[
Footnote 3]
Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont, Massachusetts, Connecticut, and
Rhode Island.
[
Footnote 4]
Nationally, the number of brewers decreased from 663 in 1935 to
140 in 1965.
[
Footnote 5]
Of the three "top ten" brewers that were not selling in New
England, Falstaff ranked fourth nationally, the other two ranking
eighth and ninth. From Boston, Massachusetts, the distance to
Falstaff's closest brewery was 844 miles, while the distance to the
eighth and ninth largest sellers' breweries was 1,385 and 2,000
miles respectively.
[
Footnote 6]
A "regional," as contrasted with a "national," brewer is one
that is not selling in all the significant national markets.
[
Footnote 7]
In 1958, Falstaff commissioned a study of actions it should take
to maximize profits. The study recommended,
inter alia,
that Falstaff become a national brewer by entering those areas
where it was not then marketing its product, especially the
Northeast, and that Falstaff should build a brewery on the East
Coast rather than buy.
[
Footnote 8]
For example, Falstaff in several press releases and in the
company publication expressed its desire for national distribution,
and, at a panel discussion in October, 1964, the president of
Falstaff, in response to a question as to Falstaff's reaction to
industry trends in beer sales, stated: "For long range planning, we
are aiming for national distribution. Naturally, this involves
coming East." App. 82.
[
Footnote 9]
Suit was filed against both Falstaff and Narragansett, but as to
the latter, the complaint was dismissed shortly after it was
filed.
[
Footnote 10]
Hereinafter, reference to
de novo entry includes
"toe-hold" acquisition as well.
[
Footnote 11]
Over the objections of the Government, the District Court
allowed post-acquisition evidence and noted in the opinion that the
market share of Narragansett dropped from 21.5% in 1964 to 15.5% in
1969, while the shares of the two leading national brewers
increased from 16.5% to 35.8%.
[
Footnote 12]
See n 8,
supra, and accompanying text.
[
Footnote 13]
In
FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.
S. 568,
386 U. S. 581
(1967), we found the acquiring company at the edge of the market
exerted "considerable influence" on the market because "market
behavior . . . was influenced by each firm's predictions of the
market behavior of its competitors, actual and potential"; because
"barriers to entry . . . were not significant" as to the acquiring
company; because "the number of potential entrants was not so large
that the elimination of one would be insignificant"; and because
the acquiring firm was the most likely entrant.
It is suggested that the District Court failed to consider
whether Falstaff was an "on the fringe" potential competitor with
influence on existing competition because the Government never
alleged in its complaint that Falstaff was exerting a present
procompetitive influence, never proceeded under this theory, and
further failed to introduce any evidence to support this view. But
this position merely ascribes an arbitrary meaning to the language
of the complaint. The Government, in its complaint, alleged that
the acquisition violated § 7 because it eliminated potential
competition; since potential competition may stimulate a present
procompetitive influence, the allegation certainly encompassed the
"on-the-fringe influence" that the District Court failed to
consider, and the Government was not required to be more specific
in its allegation.
The Government did not produce direct evidence of how members of
the New England market reacted to potential competition from
Falstaff, but circumstantial evidence is the lifeblood of antitrust
law,
see Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc.,
395 U. S. 100
(1969);
Interstate Circuit, Inc. v. United States,
306 U. S. 208,
306 U. S. 221
(1939);
Frey & Son, Inc. v. Cudahy Packing Co.,
256 U. S. 208,
256 U. S. 210
(1921), especially for § 7 which is concerned "with
probabilities, not certainties,"
Brown Shoe Co. v. United
States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 323.
As was stated in
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co.,
378 U. S. 158,
378 U. S. 174
(1964), "[p]otential competition cannot be put to a subjective
test. It is not
susceptible of a ready and precise
answer.'"
Nor was there any lack of circumstantial evidence of Falstaff's
on-the-fringe competitive impact. As the record shows, Falstaff was
in the relevant line of commerce, was admittedly interested in
entering the Northeast, and had, among other ways,
see
n 8,
supra, made its
interest known by prior-acquisition discussions. Moreover, there
were, as my Brother MARSHALL would put it, objective economic facts
as to Falstaff's capability to enter the New England market; and
the same facts which he would have the District Court look to in
determining whether the particular theory of potential competition
we do not reach has been violated, would be probative of violation
of § 7 through loss of a procompetitive "on the fringe"
influence.
See FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., supra, at
386 U. S.
580-581;
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co.,
supra, at
378 U. S.
173-177;
United States v. El Paso Natural Gas
Co., 376 U. S. 651,
376 U. S. 660
(1964).
And as for the contention that the Government did not proceed
under this "on the fringe" influence view, the record is to the
contrary. At one point in the trial, the Government informed the
trial judge that a deposition was being introduced into
evidence
"to establish that Falstaff was a company that was on the wings
or at the edge of the New England market. . . . What I mean by that
is that Falstaff was capable and interested in entering the New
England market, and would be waiting for the opportunity to
develop, but that Falstaff, over the long-term, would eventually or
could eventually or was a likely entrant into the New England
market, to use the terminology in
FTC v. Procter & Gamble
Company."
App. 124. Further into its presentation of proof, the Government
was introducing evidence of the trend toward concentration in the
market, and stated:
"It is this concentration, your Honor, which, as we attempted to
point out in our pretrial brief, makes potential competition. . . .
The concentration of sales within a small number of firms in New
England. This is what makes the potential competition . . . so
very, very important to this market. . . . In such a situation, the
potential entry of a fresh competitive factor is of extreme
importance."
App. 170.
That the "on the fringe" influence theory was one of the
theories the Government was proceeding under was apparent to
Falstaff. In its opening statement, Falstaff stated:
"Now, the Government has a theory which is, so far as the
judicial determinations on the point are concerned, comparatively
new. You were handed the other day a portion of the record in FTC
against Bendix-Fram Corporation, and you were handed at the same
time a typed or otherwise reproduced copy of the opinion of
Commissioner Elman of the FTC in that case."
"That opinion is not yet officially reported. The case is on its
way to an appeal. . . . The Commissioner announced a theory upon
which the Government relies and which they say lies within the
ambit of this vague, undefined creature, potential competition.
What that decision, on appeal as I say, what that decision
announces is the doctrine which is called the toe-hold doctrine,
and it goes like this: "
"If a producer of Product A is standing in the wings, as the
Commissioner says, outside the market, merely standing there, but
in a position to move into the market if he chooses. He must remain
there in the wings and forbear acquiring the producer of a like
product within the market area."
"The Commissioner fancies that the mere presence of such a
manufacturer or seller close to the market area had some effect
which could fall within his ill-defined concept of potential
competition. And he found in Bendix-Fram that Bendix was in such a
position. He found that Bendix could have acquired a small company
rather than Fram, a relatively larger one, beefed it up by
expenditures of money which Bendix could afford, and develop it
into a full-blown competitor within the market area. I do not know
whether that notion will gain substantial acceptance in the theory
of antitrust law. I do not know that it will have the approval of
the Supreme Court if and when it ever reaches it. I do know,
however, that that is an entirely different situation [than] we
have here."
"
* * * *"
"
If there is any sense to this total theory at all, it must
be that the acquiring company was, in fact, so closely located to
the market served by the acquired company that its entrance into
the market unilaterally, under its own steam, without motivation,
was a distinct threat to those who were competing in the
market."
App. 182-183. (Emphasis added.) Falstaff then proceeded to state
why it felt that the "on the fringe" influence theory did not apply
in this case.
During its proof, Falstaff had both its expert witness on
economics, App. 257, and an officer of Narragansett, App. 376,
testify as to whether Falstaff's presence had a procompetitive
effect, both stating that it did not.
[
Footnote 14]
It is suggested that certain language in the Court's opinion in
United States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.
S. 441,
378 U. S. 464
(1964), is to the contrary. But there, the merger was held proved
prima facie anticompetitive because the acquiring and
acquired companies were engaged in the same overall line of
commerce in the same geographic market. This notwithstanding, it is
again only arbitrary to assume that the quoted language was not
referring to the acquired company's "on the fringe" influence as a
potential competitor for certain end uses for containers.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, concurring in part.
Although I join Part I of the Court's opinion and its judgment
remanding the case to the District Court for further proceedings
consistent with the opinion, I offer the following observations
with respect to the question which the Court does not reach.
There can be no question that it would be sufficient for the
Government to prove its case to show that Falstaff would have made
a
de novo entry but for the acquisition of Narragansett or
that Falstaff was a potential competitor exercising present
influence on the market.
See Ford Motor Co. v. United
States, 405 U. S. 562;
FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.
S. 568;
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical
Co., 378 U. S. 158;
United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., 376 U.
S. 651. But, I do not believe that it was a prerequisite
to the Government's
Page 410 U. S. 539
case to prove that the acquisition had marked immediate,
i.e., present, anticompetitive effects.
Section 7 evidences a definite concern for protecting
competitive markets. It does not require "merely an appraisal of
the immediate impact of the merger upon competition, but a
prediction of its impact upon competitive conditions in the future.
. . ."
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 362.
In
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., supra, at
278 U. S.
170-171, the Court said:
"The grand design of the original § 7, as to stock
acquisitions, as well as the Celler-Kefauver Amendment, as to the
acquisition of assets, was to arrest incipient threats to
competition which the Sherman Act did not ordinarily reach. It
follows that actual restraints need not be proved. The requirements
of the amendment are satisfied when a 'tendency' toward monopoly or
the 'reasonable likelihood' of a substantial lessening of
competition in the relevant market is shown."
Moreover, we are concerned with probabilities, not certainties.
See Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.
S. 294,
370 U. S.
323.
Falstaff acquired Narragansett in 1965. Prior to that time,
Falstaff was the largest brewer in the country that did not sell in
the New England market. It had stated publicly that it wanted to
become a national brewer to allow it to compete more effectively
with the existing national brewers. Falstaff has conceded in its
brief that, "given an acceptable level of profit, it had the
financial capability and the interest to enter the New England beer
market."
During the four years preceding 1965, beer sales in New England
had increased approximately 9.5%. Nevertheless, the market had
become more concentrated. In 1960, the eight largest sellers
accounted for approximately
Page 410 U. S. 540
74% of the beer sales; by 1964, they accounted for 81.2%. From
1957 to 1964, the number of breweries decreased from 11 to 6. In
addition, there is evidence that two of the remaining breweries
were interested in being acquired. And, by Falstaff's own
admission, "[a]t the time of the acquisition, the substantial
growth in the market shares of the national brewers was just
beginning to occur."
One of the principal purposes of § 7 was to stem the
"
rising tide' of concentration in American business."
United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.
S. 546, 384 U. S. 552.
When an industry or a market evidences signs of decreasing
competition, we cannot allow an acquisition which may "tend to
accelerate concentration." Ibid.; Brown Shoe Co. v. United
States, supra, at 376 U. S.
346.
The implications of the Clayton Act, as amended by the
Celler-Kefauver Act, 15 U.S.C. § 18, are much, much broader
than the customary restraints of competition and the power of
monopoly. Louis D. Brandeis testified in favor of the bill that
became the Clayton Act in 1914.
"You cannot have true American citizenship, you cannot preserve
political liberty, you cannot secure American standards of living
unless some degree of industrial liberty accompanies it. [
Footnote 2/1]"
He went on to say [
Footnote 2/2]
in answer to George W. Perkins, who testified against the bill:
"Mr. Perkins' argument in favor of the efficiency of monopoly
proceeds upon the assumption, in the first place, and mainly upon
the assumption, that with increase of size comes increase of
efficiency. If any general proposition could be laid down on that
subject, it would, in my opinion, be the opposite. It is, of
course, true that a business unit may be too small to be efficient,
but it is equally
Page 410 U. S. 541
true that a unit may be too large to be efficient. And the
circumstances attending business today are such that the temptation
is toward the creation of too large units of efficiency, rather
than too small. The tendency to create large units is great not
because larger units tend to greater efficiency, but because the
owner of a business may make a great deal more money if he
increases the volume of his business tenfold, even if the unit
profit is in the process reduced one-half. It may, therefore, be
for the interest of an owner of a business who has capital, or who
can obtain capital at a reasonable cost, to forfeit efficiency to a
certain degree, because the result to him, in profits, may be
greater by reason of the volume of the business. Now, not only may
that be so, but, in very many cases, it is so."
"And the reason why . . . increasing the size of a business may
tend to inefficiency is perfectly obvious when one stops to
consider. Anyone who critically analyzes a business learns this:
that success or failure of an enterprise depends usually upon one
man; upon the quality of one man's judgment, and, above all things,
his capacity to see what is needed and his capacity to direct
others."
That is why the Celler Committee, reporting in 1971 on
conglomerates and other types of mergers , [
Footnote 2/3] said that
"Preservation of a competitive system was seen as essential to
avoid the concentration of economic power that was thought to be a
threat to the Nation's political and social system. [
Footnote 2/4]"
Control of American business is being transferred from local
communities to distant cities,
Page 410 U. S. 542
where men on the 54th floor with only balance sheets and profit
and loss statements before them decide the fate of communities with
which they have little or no relationship. As a result of mergers
and other acquisitions, some States are losing major corporate
headquarters and their local communities are becoming satellites of
a distant corporate control. [
Footnote
2/5] The antitrust laws favored a wide diffusion of corporate
control, and that aim has been largely defeated, with serious
consequences. Thus, a recent Wisconsin study shows that
"[t]he growth of aggregate Wisconsin employment of companies
acquired by out-of-state corporations declined substantially more
than that of those acquired by in-state corporations. [
Footnote 2/6]"
In this connection, the Celler Report states: [
Footnote 2/7]
"The Wisconsin study found also that 53 percent of acquired
companies after the merger had a slower rate of payroll growth.
Payroll growth, notably in large firms acquired by out-of-State
corporations, was depressed by mergers. Inflation in recent years
has markedly raised wages and salaries. It would be reasonable to
expect that payrolls in acquired companies, because of the
inflation, would have advanced more than employment. In this
connection, the report states:"
"The fact that this frequently did not happen in companies
acquired by out-of-state firms would lead one to believe that their
acquirers have transferred a portion of the higher salaried
employees to a location outside Wisconsin. Such transfers mean a
loss of talent, retail expenditures, and personal income taxes in
the economics of Wisconsin's communities and the state. "
Page 410 U. S. 543
The adverse influence on local affairs of out-of-state
acquisitions has not gone unnoticed in our opinions. Thus, "the
desirability of retaining
local control' over industry and the
protection of small businesses" was our comment in Brown Shoe
Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. at 370 U. S.
315-316, on one of the purposes of strengthening §
7 of the Clayton Act through passage of the Celler-Kefauver
Act.
By reason of the antitrust laws, efficiency in terms of the
accounting of dollar costs and profits is not the measure of the
public interest, nor is growth in size where no substantial
competition is curtailed. The antitrust laws look with suspicion on
the acquisition of local business units by out-of-state companies.
For then local employment is apt to suffer, local payrolls are
likely to drop off, and responsible entrepreneurs in counties and
States are replaced by clerks.
A case in point is Goldendale in my State of Washington. It was
a thriving community -- an ideal place to raise a family -- until
the company that owned the sawmill was bought by an out-of-state
giant. In a year or so, auditors in faraway New York City, who
never knew the glories of Goldendale, decided to close the local
mill and truck all the logs to Yakima. Goldendale became greatly
crippled. It is Exhibit A to the Brandeis concern, which became
part of the Clayton Act concern, with the effects that the impact
of monopoly often has on a community, as contrasted with the
beneficent effect of competition.
A nation of clerks is anathema to the American antitrust dream.
So is the spawning of federal regulatory agencies to police the
mounting economic power. For the path of those who want the
concentration of power to develop unhindered leads predictably to
socialism that is antagonistic to our system.
See Blake
& Jones, The Goals of Antitrust: A Dialogue on Policy -- In
Defense of Antitrust, 65 Col.L.Rev. 377 (1965).
Page 410 U. S. 544
It is against this background that we must assess the
acquisition by Falstaff, the largest producer of beer in the United
States that did not sell in the New England market, of the leading
seller in that market.
In
United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., 376 U.S.
at
376 U. S. 660,
we indicated that
"[t]he effect on competition in a particular market through
acquisition of another company is determined by the nature or
extent of that market and by the nearness of the absorbed company
to it, that company's eagerness to enter that market, its
resourcefulness, and so on."
Falstaff's president testified below that Falstaff for some time
had wanted to enter the New England market as part of its interest
in becoming a national brewer. And Falstaff has conceded in its
brief before this Court that, "given an acceptable level of profit,
it had the financial capability and the interest to enter the New
England beer market." With both the interest and the capability to
enter the market, Falstaff was "the most likely entrant."
FTC
v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. at
386 U. S. 581.
Thus, although Falstaff might not have made a
de novo
entry if it had not been allowed to acquire Narragansett, [
Footnote 2/8] we cannot say that it would
be unwilling to make such an entry in the future when the New
England market might be ripe for an infusion of new competition. At
this point in time, it is the most likely new competitor. Moreover,
there can be no question that replacing the leading seller in the
market, a regional brewer, with a seller
Page 410 U. S. 545
with national capabilities increased the trend toward
concentration.
I conclude that there is "reasonable likelihood" that the
acquisition in question "may be substantially to lessen
competition." Accordingly, I would be inclined to reverse and
direct the District Judge to enter judgment for the Government and
afford appropriate relief. Nevertheless, since the Court will not
reach this question and I agree with the legal principles set forth
in Part I of its opinion, I join the judgment remanding the case
for further proceedings.
[
Footnote 2/1]
Hearings on S.Res. 98 before the Senate Committee on Interstate
Commerce, 62d Cong., Vol. 1, p. 1155.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Id. at 1147.
[
Footnote 2/3]
Investigation of Conglomerate Corporations, Report by the Staff
of Antitrust Subcommittee of the House Committee on the Judiciary
on H.Res. 161, 92d Cong., 1st Sess. (Comm.Print).
[
Footnote 2/4]
Id. at 18.
[
Footnote 2/5]
Id. at 52-53.
[
Footnote 2/6]
Id. at 53.
[
Footnote 2/7]
Id. at 54.
[
Footnote 2/8]
Falstaff contended below that a
de novo entry would not
be profitable. Management stated that an established distribution
system was a prerequisite to entry. The District Judge concluded
that
"[t]he credible evidence establishes that [Falstaff] was not a
potential entrant into said market by any means or way other than
by said acquisition."
332 F.
Supp. 970, 972.
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL, concurring in the result.
I share the majority's view that the District Judge erred as a
matter of law, and that the case must be remanded for further
proceedings. I cannot agree, however, with the theory upon which
the majority bases the remand.
The majority accuses the District Judge of neglecting to assess
the present procompetitive effect which Falstaff exerted by
remaining on the fringe of the market. The explanation for this
failing is rather simple. The Government never alleged in its
complaint that Falstaff was exerting a present procompetitive
influence, [
Footnote 3/1] it
introduced not a scrap of evidence to support this view, [
Footnote 3/2] and
Page 410 U. S. 546
even at this stage of the proceedings, it seemingly disclaims
reliance on this theory. [
Footnote
3/3]
Thus, our remand leaves the hapless District Judge with the
unenviable task of reassessing nonexistent evidence under a theory
advanced by neither of the parties. I submit that civil antitrust
litigation is complicated enough when the trial judge confines his
attention to the legal arguments and evidence offered by the
parties and avoids investigation of hypothetical lawsuits which
might have been brought.
Page 410 U. S. 547
The majority's departure from this self-evident proposition is
all the more startling when one realizes that the Court eschews
reliance on a well established, plainly applicable body of law in
order to reach questions not properly before it. As MR. JUSTICE
DOUGLAS ably demonstrates,
see ante at
410 U. S.
539-540, many decisions by this Court hold that § 7
is violated when a merger is reasonably likely to eliminate future
or potential competition.
See also infra at
410 U. S.
560-562. I know of no case suggesting that this
principle is only applicable when the plaintiff can show that the
merger will have present anticompetitive consequences, and the
majority cites no authority for this proposition.
In the course of a nine-day trial, the Government introduced
voluminous evidence to support its potential competition theory.
But at the conclusion of the trial, the District Judge dismissed
the Government's action in an opinion covering a scant two and
one-half pages in the Federal Supplement, [
Footnote 3/4] and without making any findings of fact or
conclusions of law. [
Footnote 3/5]
See United States v. Falstaff Brewing
Corp., 332 F.
Supp. 970 (RI 1971).
The court held that Falstaff
"was not a potential entrant into said market by any means or
way other than by said acquisition. Consequently, it cannot be
Page 410 U. S. 548
said that its acquisition of Narragansett eliminated it as a
potential competitor therein."
Id. at 972. The District Judge based this conclusion on
testimony by Falstaff executive personnel that
"Falstaff had consistently decided not to attempt to enter said
market unless it could acquire a brewery with a strong and viable
distribution system such as that possessed by Narragansett."
Ibid.
Inasmuch as the District Court grounded its dismissal on these
conclusions, I think we have a responsibility to assess the
validity of the legal standard from which they are derived. I would
hold that, where, as here, strong objective evidence indicates that
a firm is a potential entrant into a market, it is error for the
trial judge to rely solely on the firm's subjective prediction of
its own future conduct. While such subjective evidence is probative
on the issue of potential entry, it is inherently unreliable and
must be used with great care. Ordinarily, the district court should
presume that objectively measurable market forces will govern a
firm's future conduct. Only when there is a compelling
demonstration that a firm will not follow its economic
self-interest may the district court consider subjective evidence
in predicting that conduct. Even then, subjective evidence should
be preferred only when the objective evidence is weak or
contradictory. Because the District Court failed to apply these
standards, I would remand the case for further consideration.
I
Although this case ultimately turns on a point of law, it cannot
be satisfactorily understood without some appreciation of the
factual. context in which it arises. A somewhat more detailed
description of the relevant line of commerce, the relevant
geographic market, and the market structure than that provided by
the majority is therefore in order.
Page 410 U. S. 549
A. The Product Market
The relevant product market is the production and sale of beer.
The firms competing for this market can be divided into three
categories: national, regional, and local. The national firms,
Anheuser-Busch, Schlitz, Pabst, and Miller, sell their product
throughout the country and advertise on a national basis. In
contrast, the regional firms, the largest of which are Hamm's,
Carling, Coors, Falstaff, and National Bohemian, market their beer
in narrower geographical areas of varying size. Local brewers sell
their product in a small area, sometimes no larger than a single
State.
Originally, most of the market was held by a large number of
small local and regional brewers. The high cost of transporting
beer favored the local distributor in early years. But more
recently, the national brewers have been able to overcome this
difficulty to some extent by decentralizing their production
facilities. Moreover, any remaining extra transportation costs
associated with national distribution are now outweighed by the
advantages of centralized management and, especially, national
advertising. Thus, in recent years, while the beer market as a
whole has expanded, the number of breweries has declined
dramatically.
See United States v. Pabst Brewing Co.,
384 U. S. 546,
384 U. S. 550
(1966). Whereas, in 1935, there were 684 brewing plants operating
in the United States, by 1965, the number had been reduced to 178.
Economies of scale, a relatively low profit margin, and significant
barriers to market entry have all led to a concentration of beer
production among the few national and large regional brewers.
B. The Geographic Market
These national trends are reflected in the six New England
States, which constitute the relevant geographic market. In the
four years preceding Falstaff's acquisition
Page 410 U. S. 550
of Narragansett, New England beer sales increased 9.5% -- a
substantial gain, although somewhat below the increase in national
sales for the same period. At the same time, however, the number of
brewers operating plants in the region declined precipitately.
Thus, in 1957, there were 11 breweries in the New England States,
but, by 1964, the number had declined to six, and of those six, two
of the three smallest had publicly expressed an interest in merging
with a larger competitor.
Not surprisingly, this decline in the number of breweries in New
England was accompanied by an increase in the market shares of
those selling in the region. In 1960, the eight largest
participants in the New England market claimed 74% of all beer
sales, and, by 1964, this figure had risen to 81.2%. Examination of
the four largest brewers shows that their share of the market rose
from about 50% in 1960 to 54% in 1964, to 61.3% in 1965. In large
part, these figures are probably explicable in terms of the
nationwide trend in favor of the large national and regional
brewers. Seven of the Nation's 10 largest breweries, including, of
course, all the national breweries, sell beer in New England, and
their share of the market has increased as the small, local brewers
disappeared.
At the same time, however, the concentration of the market does
not yet seem to have produced blatantly anticompetitive effects. In
recent years, prices have remained fairly stable despite rising
costs, and competition seems relatively intense among the few large
firms which dominate the market. Still, there is no doubt that the
seeds of anticompetitive conduct are present, since "[a]s [an
oligopolistic] condition develops, the greater is the likelihood
that parallel policies of mutual advantage, not competition, will
emerge."
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America,
377 U. S. 271,
377 U. S. 280
(1964). One commentator's description of the national beer market
aptly characterizes the situation in New England:
"The
Page 410 U. S. 551
increasing concentration . . . and the unlikely entrance of new
rivals poses a threat to the future level of competition in this
industry. Thus, far, there is no evidence of collusion in the beer
industry. But as the. industry becomes populated by fewer and fewer
companies, the possibility and likelihood will be enhanced of their
engaging in tacit or direct collusion -- given the inelastic nature
of demand -- to establish a joint profit maximizing price and
output. Similarly, the chances will become slimmer that individual
firms in the industry will follow a truly independent price and
production strategy, vigorously striving to take sales away from
rival brewers. With only a few sellers will come the increasing
awareness that parallel business behavior might be feasible."
Elzinga, The Beer Industry, in W. Adams, The Structure of
American Industry 189, 213 (4th ed.1971).
C. Narragansett -- The Acquired Firm
Narragansett is a regional brewery with only minuscule sales
outside of New England. Within the New England market, however, the
firm has been highly successful. Although only twenty-first in
national sales and accounting for only 1.4% of the beer sales in
the United States, Narragansett was the largest seller of beer in
New England for the five years preceding its acquisition. In recent
years, the firm has expanded steadily until, in 1964, the year
before acquisition, it sold 1.275 million barrels, which was about
20% of the New England market. Net profits had increased from
$417,284 in 1960 to a record level of $713,083 in 1964.
Notwithstanding this growth, Narragansett felt itself under some
pressure from the national brewers. [
Footnote 3/6] The
Page 410 U. S. 552
corporation was closely held by the Haffenreffer family, and the
stockholders apparently concluded that it was in their interest to
diversify their personal holdings by selling Narragansett.
D. Falstaff -- The Acquiring Firm
Like Narragansett, Falstaff has been highly successful in recent
years. Beginning with a 100,000-barrel plant in St. Louis shortly
after the repeal of Prohibition, the firm has steadily grown. By
1964, it was the Nation's fourth largest producer, marketing 5.8
million barrels, or 5.9% of the total national production.
Throughout its history, Falstaff has followed a pattern of
acquiring weak breweries and expanding them so as to extend its
influence to new markets. Although still a regional brewer, by
1965, the company had expanded its network of plants and
distributorships over an area far larger than that in which
Narragansett competed. In that year, Falstaff operated eight plants
and sold its product in 32 States in the West, Midwest, and South.
Sixteen of these States were added in the period after 1950.
However, as of 1965, Falstaff sold virtually no beer in any of the
Northeastern States, including the six composing the New England
area. Falstaff marketed its product both through company-owned
branches and through some 600 independent distributorships.
[
Footnote 3/7]
Page 410 U. S. 553
In the years immediately prior to its acquisition of
Narragansett, Falstaff's steady pattern of growth had continued.
Between 1955 and 1964, its sales increased from $77 million to
$139.5 million and it net profits grew from $4.3 million to $7
million. In the year before acquisition, the company announced a
10-year expansion program in which it was prepared to invest $35
million.
Yet, despite this encouraging trend, Falstaff, like
Narragansett, was to some extent handicapped by the competitive
advantages -- in particular, national advertising -- enjoyed by
national distributors. For years, the company had publicly
expressed the desire to become a national brewer, and the logical
region for market extension was the Northeast. New England seemed a
particularly appropriate area to initiate expansion. As indicated
above, seven of the 10 largest manufacturers already sold beer in
New England, and Falstaff was the largest of the three remaining
outside the market. The New England market was expanding at a
healthy rate, and it appeared to be a fertile area for growth.
In 1958, Falstaff commissioned a study from Arthur D. Little,
Inc., to determine the feasibility of future expansion. The Little
Report, two years in the making, concluded that Falstaff should
enter the northeastern market sometime within the next five years.
But although it was clear that Falstaff should move into the
northeast market, the method of entry was less obvious. After a
careful review of cost estimates and the ratio of earnings to net
worth, the Little Report recommended
de novo entry through
the construction of a new plant to serve the Northeast. The report
concluded that
"[t]here appears to be ample reason . . . for building, rather
than buying, . . . [and] that major new market entrances need
Page 410 U. S. 554
not be predicated on the availability of a brewery Falstaff
could purchase."
Despite this analysis, Falstaff's own management personnel
apparently concluded that the profit return on a
de novo
entry would be inordinately low. [
Footnote 3/8] Falstaff argued at trial that it needed a
strong, preexisting distribution system to make a profitable entry.
But cf. 410
U.S. 526fn3/7|>n. 7,
supra. An independent
economist, Dr. Ira Horowitz, testified on behalf of Falstaff that
de novo entry would result in a 6.7% return, which he
characterized as "a very, very poor investment indeed." However, it
should be noted that the 6.7% figure failed to account for the
increment in Falstaff's profit margin which would result from its
newly gained status as a national brewer with modern plants to
serve the eastern part of the Nation -- the very increment which
provided the primary motivation for expansion in the first place.
While Dr. Horowitz apparently recognized that such an increment
might materialize, he stated that he was unable to estimate its
size. [
Footnote 3/9] Moreover, even
the 6.7% return rate compares favorably with Falstaff's actual rate
of return on its Narragansett purchase, which was a mere 3.7%.
In any event, whatever the abstract merits of this dispute, it
is clear that Falstaff's management personnel determined that entry
by acquisition offered the preferable avenue for expansion.
Beginning in 1962, the company held discussions with Liebmann, P.
Ballantine
Page 410 U. S. 555
& Sons, [
Footnote 3/10]
Piel Brothers, and Dawsons, all of which did a significant
percentage of their business in the New England market. All of
these possibilities were eventually rejected, and in 1965, Falstaff
finally settled on Narragansett as the most promising available
brewery.
II
With this factual background, it becomes possible to articulate
the legal standards which should govern the resolution of this
case.
A. The Purposes of § 7
As is clear from its face, § 7 was designed to deal with
the anticompetitive effects of excessive industrial concentration
caused by the corporate marriage of two competitors.
"It is the basic premise of [§ 7] that competition will be
most vital 'when there are many sellers, none of which has any
significant market share.'"
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.S. at
377 U. S.
280.
But § 7 does more than prohibit mergers with immediate
anticompetitive effects. The Act, by its terms, prohibits
acquisitions which "may . . . substantially . . . lessen
competition, or . . . tend to create a monopoly." The use of the
subjunctive indicates that Congress was concerned with the
potential effects of mergers even though, at the time they occur,
they may cause no present anticompetitive consequences.
See,
e.g., FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.
S. 568,
386 U. S. 577
(1967). To be sure, remote possibilities are not sufficient to
satisfy the test set forth in § 7. Despite substantial concern
with halting a trend toward concentration in its incipiency,
Congress did not intend to prohibit all expansion and growth
through acquisition
Page 410 U. S. 556
and merger. The predictive judgment often required under §
7 involves a decision based upon a careful scrutiny and a
reasonable assessment of the future consequences of a merger
without unjustifiable, speculative interference with traditional
market freedoms. As we stated in
Brown Shoe Co. v. United
States, 370 U. S. 294,
370 U. S. 323
(1962):
"Congress used the words '
may be substantially to
lessen competition' (emphasis supplied), to indicate that its
concern was with probabilities, not certainties. Statutes existed
for dealing with clear-cut menaces to competition; no statute was
sought for dealing with ephemeral possibilities. Mergers with a
probable anticompetitive effect were to be proscribed by this
Act."
See also United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S.
at
384 U. S. 552;
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., 378 U.
S. 158,
378 U. S. 171
(1964).
The legislative history of § 7 makes plain that this was
the intent of Congress. Before 1950, § 7 prohibited only those
mergers which lessened competition "between the corporation whose
stock is so acquired and the corporation making the acquisition."
[
Footnote 3/11] The
Celler-Kefauver Amendment, added in 1950, deleted these words and
provided instead that all mergers which substantially lessened
competition "in any line of commerce in any section of the country"
were to be outlawed.
See 64 Stat. 1126. Thus, whereas
before 1950, § 7 proscribed only
Page 410 U. S. 557
those mergers which eliminated present, actual competition
between the merging firm, the Celler-Kefauver Amendment reached
cases where future or potential competition in the entire relevant
market might be adversely affected by the merger. [
Footnote 3/12]
"Section 7 of the Clayton Act was intended to arrest the
anticompetitive effects of market power in their incipiency. The
core question is whether a merger may substantially lessen
competition, and necessarily requires a prediction of the merger's
impact on competition, present and future. . . . The section can
deal only with probabilities, not with certainties. . . . And there
is certainly no requirement that the anticompetitive power manifest
itself in anticompetitive
Page 410 U. S. 558
action before § 7 can be called into play. If the
enforcement of § 7 turned on the existence of actual
anticompetitive practices, the congressional policy of thwarting
such practices in their incipiency would be frustrated."
FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. at
386 U. S.
577.
B. Modes of Potential Competition
Since 1950, we have repeatedly applied § 7 to cases where
the merging firms competed in the same line of commerce, and we
have been willing to define the line of commerce liberally so as to
reach anticompetitive practices in their "incipiency."
See,
e.g., United States v. Phillipsburg National Bank,
399 U. S. 350
(1970);
United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.
S. 546 (1966);
United States v. Aluminum Co. of
America, 377 U. S. 271
(1964);
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
374 U. S. 321
(19&3);
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.
S. 294 (1962). But in keeping with the spirit of the
Celler-Kefauver Amendment, we have also applied § 7 to cases
where the acquiring firm is outside the market in which the
acquired firm competes. These cases fall into three broad
categories which, while frequently overlapping, can be dealt with
separately for analytical purposes.
1. The Dominant Entrant. -- In some situations, a firm
outside the market may have overpowering resources which, if
brought to bear within the market, could ultimately have a
substantial anticompetitive effect. If such a firm were to acquire
a company within the relevant market, it might drive other marginal
companies out of business, thus creating an oligopoly, or it might
raise entry barriers to such an extent that potential new entrants
would be discouraged from entering the market.
Cf. Ford Motor
Co. v. United States, 405 U. S. 562,
405 U. S.
567-568 (1972);
FTC v. Procter & Gamble
Co., 386
Page 410 U. S. 559
U.S. at 575. [
Footnote 3/13]
Such a danger is especially intense when the market is already
highly concentrated or entry barriers are already unusually high
before the dominant firm enters the market.
2. The Perceived Potential Entrant. -- Even if the
entry of a firm does not upset the competitive balance within the
market, it may be that the removal of the firm from the fringe of
the market has a present anticompetitive effect. In a concentrated
oligopolistic market, the presence of a large potential competitor
on the edge of the market, apparently ready to enter if entry
barriers are lowered, may deter anticompetitive conduct within the
market. As we pointed out in
United States v. Penn-Olin
Chemical Co., 378 U.S. at
378 U. S.
174:
"The existence of an aggressive, well equipped and well financed
corporation engaged in the same or related lines of commerce
waiting anxiously to enter an oligopolistic market [is] a
substantial incentive to competition which cannot be
underestimated."
From the perspective of the firms already in the market, the
possibility of entry by such a lingering firm may be an important
consideration in their pricing and marketing decisions. When the
lingering firm enters the market by acquisition, the competitive
influence exerted by the firm is lost with no offsetting gain
through an increase in the number of companies seeking a share of
the relevant market. The result is a net decrease
Page 410 U. S. 560
in competitive pressure. [
Footnote
3/14]
Cf. United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co.,
376 U. S. 651,
376 U. S.
659-660 (1964).
3. The Actual Potential Entrant. -- Since the effect of
a perceived potential entrant depends upon the perception of those
already in the market, it may in some cases be difficult to prove.
Moreover, in a market which is already competitive, the existence
of a perceived potential entrant will have no present effect at
all. [
Footnote 3/15] The entry by
acquisition of such a firm may nonetheless have an anticompetitive
effect by eliminating an actual potential competitor. When a firm
enters the market by acquiring a strong company within the market,
it merely assumes the position of that company without necessarily
increasing competitive pressures. Had such a firm not entered by
acquisition, it might at some point have entered
de
Page 410 U. S. 561
novo. An entry
de novo would increase
competitive pressures within the market, and an entry by
acquisition eliminates the possibility that such an increase will
take place in the future. Thus, even if a firm at the fringe of the
market exerts no present procompetitive effect, its entry by
acquisition may end for all time the promise of more effective
competition at some future date.
Obviously, the anticompetitive effect of such an acquisition
depends on the possibility that the firm would have entered
de
novo had it not entered by acquisition. If the company would
have remained outside the market but for the possibility of entry
by acquisition, and if it is exerting no influence as a perceived
potential entrant, then there will normally be no competitive loss
when it enters by acquisition. Indeed, there may even be a
competitive gain to the extent that it strengthens the market
position of the acquired firm. [
Footnote 3/16] Thus, mere entry by acquisition would
not
prima facie establish a firm's status as an actual
potential entrant. For example, a firm, although able to enter the
market by acquisition, might, because of inability to shoulder the
de novo start-up costs, be unable to enter
de
novo. But where a powerful firm is engaging in a related line
of commerce at the fringe of the relevant market, where it has a
strong incentive to enter the market
de novo, and where it
has the financial capabilities to do so, we have not hesitated to
ascribe to it the role of an actual potential entrant In such
cases, we have held that § 7 prohibits an entry by
acquisition, since such an entry eliminates the possibility of
future actual competition which would occur if there were an entry
de novo.
Page 410 U. S. 562
In light of the many decisions to this effect, the majority's
assertion that "the Court has not squarely faced [this] question"
is inexplicable. In
United States v. Continental Can Co.,
378 U. S. 441
(1964), for example, the defendant argued that "the types of
containers produced by Continental and Hazel-Atlas [the acquired
firm] at the time of the merger were for the most part not in
competition with each other and hence the merger could have no
effect on competition."
Id. at
378 U. S. 462.
But MR. JUSTICE WHITE, writing for the Court, rejected that
argument, holding that
"[i]t is not at all self-evident that the lack of current
competition between Continental and Hazel-Atlas for some important
end uses of metal and glass containers significantly diminished the
adverse effect of the merger on competition. Continental might have
concluded that it could effectively insulate itself from
competition by acquiring a major firm
not presently directing
its market acquisition efforts toward the same end uses as
Continental, but possessing the potential to do so."
Id. at
378 U. S. 464
(emphasis added). The majority says it is "only arbitrary" to read
this language as not referring to Hazel-Atlas' present
procompetitive influence on the market. But the
Continental
Can Court said not a word about present procompetitive
effects, and, indeed, made clear that it was relying on the future
anticompetitive impact of the merger. The Court held, for example,
that
"the fact that Continental and Hazel-Atlas were not substantial
competitors of each other for certain end uses at the time of the
merger may actually enhance the long-run tendency of the merger to
lessen competition."
Id. at
378 U. S. 465
(emphasis added).
See also Ford Motor Co. v. United
States, 405 U. S. 562
(1972);
FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.
S. 568 (1967);
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical
Co., 378 U. S. 158
(1964);
United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co.,
376 U. S. 651
(1964).
Page 410 U. S. 563
C. Problems of Proof -- The Role of Subjective
Evidence
Although § 7 deals with probabilities, not ephemeral
possibilities, all forms of potential competition involve future
events and all of them are, therefore, to some extent speculative
and uncertain. Whether future competition will be reduced by a
present merger is clearly
"not the kind of question which is susceptible of a ready and
precise answer in most cases. It requires not merely an appraisal
of the immediate impact of the merger upon competition, but a
prediction of its impact upon competitive conditions in the future;
this is what is meant when it is said that the amended § 7 was
intended to arrest anticompetitive tendencies in their
'incipiency.'"
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S.
at
374 U. S. 362.
The unavoidable problems of proof are compounded in some cases by
the relevance of subjective statements of future intent by the
managers of the acquiring firm. Although not susceptible of precise
analysis, the objective conditions of the market may at least be
measured and quantified. But there exists no very good way of
evaluating a subjective statement by the manager of a firm that the
firm does or does not intend to enter a given market at some future
date.
Fortunately, in two of the three forms of potential competition,
such subjective evidence has no role to play. Clearly, in the case
of a dominant entrant, the only issue is whether the firm's entry
by acquisition will so upset objective market forces as to
substantially reduce future competition. Since the firm will have
already taken steps to enter the market by the time a § 7
action is filed, its statements of subjective intent are
irrelevant.
Page 410 U. S. 564
Similarly, when the Government proceeds on the theory that the
acquiring firm is a perceived potential entrant, testimony as to
the subjective intent of the acquiring firm is not probative. The
perceived potential entrant exerts a pro-competitive effect because
companies in the market perceive it as a potential entrant. The
companies in the market may entertain this perception whether the
perceived potential entrant is in fact, a potential entrant or not.
Thus, a firm on the fringe of the market may exert a procompetitive
effect even if it has no intention of entering the market, so long
as it seems to those within the market that it may have such an
intention. [
Footnote 3/17] It
follows that subjective testimony by the managers of the perceived
potential entrant is irrelevant. [
Footnote 3/18]
However, subjective statements of management are probative in
cases where the acquiring firm is alleged to be an actual potential
entrant. First, management's statements that it does not intend to
make a
de novoo market entry, together with its associated
reasons, provide an expert judgment on the conclusions to be
drawn
Page 410 U. S. 565
by the trier of fact from the objective market forces. Just as
the Government may introduce expert testimony to inform and guide
the trial court with respect to the appropriate business judgments
to be derived from the objective data, so too the defendant is
entitled to present the evaluation of its own "experts" who may
include its management personnel. Although such evidence from
management is obviously biased and self-serving, it is nonetheless
admissible to prove that the objective market pressures do not
favor a
de novo entry.
More significantly, management's statement of subjective intent,
if believed, affects the firm's status as an actual potential
entrant. As indicated above, the actual potential entrant's entry
by acquisition is anticompetitive only if it eliminates some future
possibility that it might have entered
de novo. An
unequivocal statement by management that it has absolutely no
intention of entering the market
de novo at any time in
the future is relevant to the issue of whether the possibility of
such an entry exists. After all, the character of management is
itself essentially an objective factor in determining whether the
acquiring firm is an actual potential entrant.
But although subjective evidence is probative and admissible in
actual potential entry cases, its utility is sharply limited. We
have certainly never suggested that subjective evidence of likely
future entry is required to make out a § 7 case. On the
contrary, in
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co., 378
U.S. at
378 U. S. 175,
where the objective evidence of potential entry was strong, we
said,
"
Unless we are going to require subjective evidence,
this array of probability certainly reaches the
prima
facie stage. As we have indicated, to require more would be to
read the statutory requirement of reasonable probability into a
requirement of certainty. This we will not do."
(Emphasis added.)
Page 410 U. S. 566
Nor do our prior cases hold that the district courts are bound
by subjective statements of company officials that they have no
intention of making a de now entry. We have emphasized that the
decision whether the acquiring firm is an actual potential entrant
is, in the last analysis, an independent one to be made by the
trial court on the basis of all relevant evidence properly weighted
according to its credibility. Thus, in
FTC v. Procter Gamble
Co, for example, managers of Procter & Gamble testified
that they had no intention of making a ,
de novo entry, and
the Court of Appeals thought itself bound by that testimony.
See 386 U.S. at
386 U. S. 580,
and
id. at
386 U. S. 585
(Harlan, J., concurring). We reversed, holding that "[t]he evidence
. . . clearly shows that Procter was the most likely entrant."
Id. at
386 U. S.
580.
As these cases indicate, subjective evidence has, at best, only
a marginal role to play in actual potential entry cases. In order
to make out a
prima facie case, the Government need only
show that objectively measurable market data favor a
de
novo entry, and that the alleged potential entrant has the
economic capability to make such an entry. To be sure, the
defendant may then introduce subjective testimony in rebuttal, and
in the rare case where the objective evidence is evenly divided, it
is conceivable that extremely credible subjective evidence might
tip the balance. But where objectively measurable market forces
make clear that it is in a firm's economic self-interest to make a
de novo entry and that the firm has the economic
capability to do so, I would hold that it is error for the District
Court to conclude that the firm is not an actual potential entrant
on the basis of testimony by company officials as to the firm's
future intent. [
Footnote
3/19]
Page 410 U. S. 567
The reasons for so limiting the role of subjective evidence are
not difficult to discern. Such evidence should obviously be given
no weight if it is not credible. But it is in the very nature of
such evidence that in the
Page 410 U. S. 568
usual case it is not worthy of credit. [
Footnote 3/20] First, any statement of future intent
will be inherently self-serving. A defendant in a § 7 case
such as this wishes to enter the market by acquisition and its
managers know that its ability to do so depends upon whether it can
convince a court that it would not have entered
de novo if
entry by acquisition were prevented. It is thus strongly in
management's interest to represent that it has no intention of
entering
de novo -- a representation which is not subject
to external verification and which is so speculative in nature that
it could virtually never serve as the predicate for a perjury
charge.
Moreover, in a case where the objective evidence strongly favors
entry
de novo, a firm which asks us to believe that it
does not intend to enter
de novo by implication asks us to
believe that it does not intend to act in its own economic
self-interest. But corporations are, after all, profit-making
institutions, and, absent special circumstances, they can be
expected to follow courses of action most likely to maximize
profits. [
Footnote 3/21] The
Page 410 U. S. 569
trier of fact should, therefore, look with great suspicion upon
a suggestion that a company with an opportunity to expand its
market and the means to seize upon that opportunity will follow a
deliberate policy of self-abnegation if the route of expansion
first selected is legally foreclosed to it.
Thus, in most cases, subjective statements contrary to the
objective evidence simply should not be believed. But even if the
threshold credibility gap is breached, it still does not follow
that subjective statements of future intent should outweigh strong
objective evidence to the contrary. Even if it is true that
management has no present intent of entering the market
de
novo, the possibility remains that it may change its mind as
the objective factors favoring such entry are more clearly
perceived. Of course, it is possible that management will adamantly
continue to close its eyes to the company's own self-interest. But,
in that event, the chance remains that the stockholders will
install new, more competent officers who will better serve their
interests. All of these possibilities are abruptly and irrevocably
aborted when the firm is allowed to enter the market by
acquisition. And while it is conceivable that none of the
possibilities will materialize if entry by acquisition
Page 410 U. S. 570
is prevented, it is absolutely certain that they will not
materialize if such entry is permitted. All that is necessary to
trigger a § 7 violation is a finding by the trial court of a
reasonable chance of future competition. In most cases, strong
objective evidence will be sufficient to create such a chance
despite even credible subjective statements to the contrary.
[
Footnote 3/22]
To summarize, then, I would not hold that subjective evidence
may never be considered in the context of an actual potential entry
case. Such evidence should always be admissible as expert, although
biased, commentary on the nature of the objective evidence. And in
a rare case, the subjective evidence may serve as a counterweight
to weak or inconclusive objective data. But when the district court
can point to no compelling reason why the subjective testimony
should be believed or when the objective evidence strongly points
to the feasibility of entry
de novo, I would hold that it
is error for the court to rely in any way upon management's
subjective statements as to its own future intent.
III
As indicated above, the Government failed to press the argument
that Falstaff was a dominant or perceived potential entrant. Since
there is virtually no evidence in the record to support either of
these theories, I cannot
Page 410 U. S. 571
say that the District Judge erred in rejecting them. It does
appear, however, that he applied an erroneous standard in
evaluating the subjective evidence relevant to Falstaff's position
as an actual potential entrant, and that this error infected the
court's factual determinations. I would therefore remand the cause
so that a proper factfinding can be made.
The record shows that the New England market is highly
concentrated, with a few large firms gaining a greater and greater
share of the market. Although this market structure has yet to
produce overtly anticompetitive behavior, there is a real danger
that parallel pricing and marketing policies will soon emerge if
new competitors do not enter the field.
The objective evidence in the record strongly suggests that
Falstaff had both the capability and the incentive to enter the New
England market
de novo. It is undisputed that it was in
Falstaff's interest to gain the status of a national brewer in the
near future, and that New England was a logical area to begin its
expansion. Indeed, Falstaff's own actions in entering the New
England market support this conclusion. Nor can it be doubted that
Falstaff had the economic capability to enter New England. Falstaff
is the Nation's fourth largest brewer, and the largest still
outside of New England. It has been consistently profitable in
recent years, has an excellent credit rating, and had, in 1964,
enough excess capital to finance a 10-year, $35 million expansion
project. The Little Report concluded that
de novo entry
into the Northeast was feasible and, although Falstaff attacks
these findings, the trier of fact might well have accepted them had
he relied upon the objective evidence.
To be sure, Falstaff introduced a great deal of evidence tending
to show that entry
de novo would have been less profitable
for it than entry by acquisition.
Page 410 U. S. 572
I have no doubt that this is true. Indeed, if it can be assumed
that Falstaff is a rational, profit-maximizing corporation, its own
decision offers strong proof that entry by acquisition was the
preferable alternative. But the test in § 7 cases is not
whether anticompetitive conduct is profit-maximizing. The very
purpose of § 7 is to direct the profit incentive into channels
which are procompetitive. Thus, the proper test is whether Falstaff
would have entered the market
de novo if the preferable
alternative of entry by acquisition had been denied it. The
objective evidence strongly suggests that such an entry would have
occurred.
The District Court, however, chose to ignore this objective
evidence almost totally. Instead, the trial judge seems to have
considered himself bound by Falstaff's subjective representations
that it had no intention of entering the market
de novo.
As noted above, even if these subjective statements are credible,
they appear to be insufficient to outweigh the strong objective
evidence to the contrary.
Findings of fact are, of course, for the trial judge in the
first instance, and even in antitrust cases where the evidence is
largely documentary, appellate courts should be reluctant to set
them aside. But when the facts are found under a standard which is
legally deficient, the situation is fundamentally different. It is
the duty of appellate courts to establish the legal standards by
which the facts are to be judged. The facts in this case were
judged by a wrong standard, and the cause should therefore be
remanded for a new, error-free determination.
[
Footnote 3/1]
The Government's complaint alleged that the merger violated
§ 7 because "
[p]otential competition in the
production and sale of beer between Falstaff and Narragansett will
be eliminated." (Emphasis added.) While it is true, as the majority
asserts, that "potential competition may stimulate a present
procompetitive influence,"
see ante at
410 U. S. 534
n. 13, the complaint nowhere alleges that such a procompetitive
influence occurred in this case.
[
Footnote 3/2]
Significantly, the majority cites no evidence at all from the
record indicating that firms within the New England market were
deterred from anticompetitive practices by Falstaff's presence at
the market fringe. Indeed, my Brethren concede that "[t]he
Government did not produce direct evidence of how members of the
New England market reacted to potential competition from Falstaff,"
ibid. While the majority contends that there was
"circumstantial evidence" relevant to determining whether there was
a loss of procompetitive influence, the evidence it points to
suggests only that Falstaff might have been perceived as a
potential entrant -- not that this perception produced a present
procompetitive effect. In fact, the little evidence on the question
which does appear in the record strongly suggests that Falstaff was
exerting no procompetitive influence. Thus, an economist testifying
for the defense stated that, in his expert judgment, Falstaff's
presence on the fringe of the market "had no effect" on the
practices of firms within the market (App. 257). Similarly, the
director of marketing for Narragansett testified that those within
the market did not view Falstaff as a threat, and that it never
occurred to them that Falstaff would attempt a
de novo
entry (App. 376).
To be sure, this testimony may well have been biased and might
properly have been discounted by the trier of fact. But it is
harder to dismiss the documentary evidence showing continued
vigorous competition after Falstaff's entry by acquisition. If
Falstaff was exerting a substantial procompetitive influence by
threatening entry, it would seem to follow that anticompetitive
practice should have emerged when this threat was removed. The
majority nowhere accounts for the continuing absence of such
practices.
[
Footnote 3/3]
In its brief before this Court, the Government characterizes its
cause of action as follows:
"The theory of the suit was that
potential competition
in the New England beer market may be substantially lessened by the
acquisition."
Brief for United States 2-3.
[
Footnote 3/4]
Cf. United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co.,
376 U. S. 651,
376 U. S. 663
(1964) (opinion of Harlan, J.):
"Both as a practitioner and as a judge, I have more than once
felt that a closely contested government antitrust case, decided
below in favor of the defendant, has foundered in this Court for
lack of an illuminating opinion by the District Court. District
Courts should not forget that such cases, the trials of which
usually result in long and complex factual records, come here
without the benefit of any sifting by the Courts of Appeals. The
absence of an opinion by the District Court has been a handicap in
this instance."
[
Footnote 3/5]
See Fed.Rule Civ.Proc. 52(a).
Cf. United States v.
El Paso Natural Gas Co., supra, at
376 U. S.
656-657.
[
Footnote 3/6]
This pressure continued during the post-acquisition period. From
1964 to 1969, Narragansett's share of the market slipped from 21.5%
to 15.5%, while Anheuser-Busch and Schlitz, two large national
firms, increased their combined share from 16.50 to 35.8%.
[
Footnote 3/7]
At trial, Falstaff argued that it was unlikely to make a
de
novo entry into the New England market since it had learned
through experience that a strong, preexisting organization of
distributors was essential to success. It is true that Falstaff
sold most of its beer through independent distributors. However, it
should be noted that between 20% and 25% of its sales were made
through company branches which Falstaff had established itself. As
might be expected, Falstaff's profit margin was significantly
higher in areas where it used its own distribution facilities.
Moreover, Falstaff's assertion is belied by its own prior history.
As noted above, for years Falstaff had successfully expanded by
purchasing failing breweries with weak distribution facilities and
turning them into effective competitors.
[
Footnote 3/8]
At trial, Falstaff also argued that the other Little
recommendations which Falstaff did follow led to disastrous
consequences, that Little's estimate of construction costs were
unrealistic, and that the Little Report was premised on Falstaff's
penetration of the mid-Atlantic as well as the New England
market.
[
Footnote 3/9]
Dr. Horowitz' estimates were based on the assumption that
Falstaff's profit margin would be $1.16 per barrel, which was the
margin currently enjoyed by the company. However, Anheuser-Busch
and Pabst, two of the larger national breweries, both earned more
than $2.50 per barrel in their modern plants.
[
Footnote 3/10]
Ultimately, on March 6, 1972, Falstaff announced plans to
acquire Ballantine's trademarks and tradename.
[
Footnote 3/11]
The original § 7 provided in relevant part:
"[N]o corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where the
effect of such acquisition may be to substantially lessen
competition between the corporation whose stock is so acquired and
the corporation making the acquisition, or to restrain such
commerce in any section or commmunity, or tend to create a monopoly
of any line of commerce."
38 Stat. 731.
[
Footnote 3/12]
The legislative history of the 1950 amendment was traced in
detail in our opinion in
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U. S. 294
(1962).
"The deletion of the 'acquiring-acquired' test was the direct
result of an amendment offered by the Federal Trade Commission. In
presenting the proposed change, Commission Counsel Kelley made the
following points: this Court's decisions had implied that the
effect on competition between the parties to the merger was not the
only test of the illegality of a stock merger; the Court had
applied Sherman Act tests to Clayton Act cases and thus judged the
effect of a merger on the industry as a whole; this incorporation
of Sherman Act tests, with the accompanying 'rule of reason,' was
inadequate for reaching some mergers which the Commission felt were
not in the public interest; and the new amendment proposed a middle
ground between what appeared to be an overly restrictive test
insofar as mergers between competitors were concerned, and what
appeared to the Commission to be an overly lenient test insofar as
all other mergers were concerned. Congressman Kefauver supported
this amendment and the Commission's proposal was then incorporated
into the bill which was eventually adopted by the Congress.
See Hearings [before Subcommittee No. 2 of the House
Committee on the Judiciary] on H.R. 515, [80th Cong., 1st Sess.] at
23, 117-119, 238-240, 259; Hearings before a Subcommittee of the
Senate Judiciary Committee on HR. 2734, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. . . .
147."
370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 317
n. 30.
[
Footnote 3/13]
To be sure, in terms of anticompetitive effects, the dominant
firm's acquisition of another firm within the market might be
functionally indistinguishable from a
de novo entry, which
§ 7 does not forbid. But
"surely one premise of an anti-merger statute such as § 7
is that corporate growth by internal expansion is socially
preferable to growth by acquisition."
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 370
(1963). Moreover, entry by acquisition has the added evil of
eliminating one firm in the market, and thus increasing the burden
on the remaining firms which must compete with the dominant
entering firm.
[
Footnote 3/14]
Thus, whereas the practical difference between entry by
acquisition and entry
de novo may be marginal in the case
of a dominant entrant,
see 410
U.S. 526fn3/13|>n. 13,
supra, it is crucial in the
case of a perceived potential entrant. If the perceived potential
entrant enters
de novo, its deterrent effect on
anticompetitive practices remains and the total number of firms
competing for market shares increases. But when such a firm enters
by acquisition, it merely steps into the shoes of the acquired
firm. The result is no net increase in the actual competition for
market shares and the removal of a threat exerting procompetitive
influence from outside the market.
[
Footnote 3/15]
Still, even if the market is presently competitive, it is
possible that it might grow less competitive in the future. For
example, a market might be so concentrated that, even though it is
presently competitive, there is a serious risk that parallel
pricing policies might emerge sometime in the near future. In such
a situation, an effective competitor lingering on the fringe of the
market -- what might be called a
potential perceived
potential entrant -- could exert a deterrent force when
anticompetitive conduct is about to emerge. As its very name
suggests, however, such a firm would be still a further step
removed from the exertion of actual, present competitive influence,
and the problems of proof are compounded accordingly --
particularly in light of the showing of reasonable probability
required under § 7.
[
Footnote 3/16]
However, if the acquired firm is strengthened to such an extent
that it upsets the market balance and drives its competitors out of
the market, the acquiring firm takes on the characteristics of a
dominant entrant, and the merger may therefore violate § 7
under that theory.
See supra at
410 U. S.
558-560 and n. 14.
[
Footnote 3/17]
Thus, in
United States v. Penn-Olin Chemical Co.,
378 U. S. 158
(1964), for example, management testified that the company had no
intention of making a
de novo, nonacquisitive entry,
id. at
378 U. S. 166,
and in part on the basis of this testimony, the District Court
found that such an entry was unlikely,
id. at
378 U. S. 173.
But we rejected this finding as irrelevant to the company's status
as a perceived potential entrant since "the corporation . . . might
have remained at the edge of the market, continually threatening to
enter,"
ibid., and so affected competition within the
market.
[
Footnote 3/18]
Public statements by management that the firm does not intend to
enter the market may be relevant. To the extent that such
statements are believed by the firms within the market, they affect
their perception of the firm outside the market as a potential
entrant. But in that event, the statements of intent are
admissible, not to show subjective state of mind, but, rather, as
one of the objective factors controlling the perception of the
firms within the market.
[
Footnote 3/19]
It might be argued that economic decisions are "inherently
subjective," and that any attempt to derive objective conclusion
from economic data is futile. If this observation means that
different people reach different conclusions from the same
objective data, then the point must, of course, be conceded.
Similarly, if the point is that economic predictions are difficult
and fraught with uncertainty, it is well taken. As we recognized in
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, such
questions are "not . . . susceptible of a ready and precise answer
in most cases." 374 U.S. at
374 U. S. 362.
But although the factual controversies in § 7 cases may prove
difficult to resolve, the statutory scheme clearly demands their
resolution. As this Court held years ago, in response to a similar
argument:
"So far as the arguments proceed upon the conception that, in
view of the generality of the statute, it is not susceptible of
being enforced by the courts because it cannot be carried out
without a judicial exertion of legislative power, they are clearly
unsound. The statute certainly generically enumerates the character
of acts which it prohibits and the wrong which it was intended to
prevent. The propositions therefore but insist that . . . it never
can be left to the judiciary to decide whether, in a given case,
particular acts come within a generic statutory provision. But to
reduce the propositions, however, to this their final meaning makes
it clear that, in substance, they deny the existence of essential
legislative authority, and challenge the right of the judiciary to
perform duties which that department of the government has exerted
from the beginning."
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U. S.
1,
221 U. S. 69-70
(1911). Section 7, by its terms, requires the trial judge to make a
prediction, and it is entirely possible that others may reasonably
disagree with the conclusion he reaches. But a holding that the
fact of such disagreement requires the judge to delegate his
decisionmaking authority to one of the parties would strike at the
heart of the very notion of judicial conflict resolution. While it
may be true that different people see economic facts in different
light, § 7 gives federal judges and juries the responsibility
to reach their conclusions as to the economic facts. And "[i]f
justice requires the fact to be ascertained, the difficulty of
doing so is no ground for refusing to try." O. Holmes, The Common
Law 48.
[
Footnote 3/20]
The Government directs our attention to a case which
dramatically illustrates the unreliable character of such evidence.
When the Government challenged Bethlehem Steel's acquisition of
Youngstown Steel in a § 7 proceeding, Bethlehem vigorously
argued that it would never enter the Midwestern steel market
de
novo. But when the merger was disallowed,
see United
States v. Bethlehem Steel Corp., 168 F.
Supp. 576 (SDNY 1958), Bethlehem nonetheless elected to make a
de novo entry.
See Moody's Industrial Manual 2861
(1966).
[
Footnote 3/21]
It is possible to imagine a small, closely held corporation
which is not solely concerned with profit maximization and which
through excessive conservatism or inertia would not seize upon an
opportunity to expand its profits. But such a corporation is
exceedingly unlikely to become the defendant in a § 7 lawsuit.
Section 7 suits of this type are triggered when a firm tries to
expand its market by entering hitherto foreign territory by
acquisition. A firm caught in the act of expanding by acquisition
can hardly be heard to say that it is uninterested in
expansion.
It is also possible that a firm might make a good faith error as
to the nature of objective market forces. Thus, even though the
objective factors favor entry
de novo, the firm's managers
might think that the same factors are unfavorable. But as the
objective evidence favoring entry becomes stronger, the possibility
of good faith error correspondingly decreases, so that, if the
objective forces favoring entry are clear, the chance of good faith
error becomes
de minimis. Moreover, the mere fact that a
firm is presently making a good faith error does not demonstrate
that it will continue to do so in the future.
See supra,
this page.
[
Footnote 3/22]
The distinction between subjective statements of intent and
objectively verifiable facts is not unknown in other areas of the
law.
See, e.g., Wright v. Council of City of Emporia,
407 U. S. 451,
407 U. S.
460-462 (1972);
NLRB v. Erie Resistor Corp.,
373 U. S. 221,
373 U. S.
227-228 (1963). Indeed, perhaps the oldest rule of
evidence -- that a man is presumed to intend the natural and
probable consequences of his acts -- is based on the common law's
preference for objectively measurable data over subjective
statements of opinion and intent. Nor have we hesitated to apply
this principle to antitrust law.
See, e.g., Utah Pie Co. v.
Continental Baking Co., 386 U. S. 685,
386 U. S.
702-703 (1967);
United States v. Gypsum Co.,
333 U. S. 364,
333 U. S. 394
(1948).
MR. JUSTICE REHNQUIST, with whom MR. JUSTICE STEWART concurs,
dissenting.
Civil litigation in our common law system is conducted within
the framework of the time-honored principle that the plaintiff must
introduce sufficient evidence to convince
Page 410 U. S. 573
the trier of fact that his claim for relief is factually
meritorious. However large the societal interest in the area of
antitrust law, so long as Congress assigns the vindication of those
interests to civil litigation in the federal courts, antitrust
litigation is no exception to that rule. The plaintiff, whether
public or private, must prove to the satisfaction of the judge or
jury that the defendant violated the antitrust laws.
United
States v. Yellow Cab Co., 338 U. S. 338
(1949). It is the exclusive responsibility of the trier of fact to
weigh, as he sees fit, all admissible evidence in resolving
disputed issues of fact,
ibid., and his findings of fact
cannot be overturned on appeal unless "the reviewing court on the
entire evidence is left with the definite and firm conviction that
a mistake has been committed."
United States v. Gypsum
Co., 333 U. S. 364,
333 U. S. 395
(1948).
Cf. FTC v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.
S. 568 (1967). The Court today simply disregards these
principles.
The Court remands this case to the District Court to
consider
"whether Falstaff was a potential competitor in the sense that
it was so positioned on the edge of the market that it exerted
beneficial influence on competitive conditions in that market."
Ante at
410 U. S.
532-533. The antitrust theory underlying the remand is
that the competitors in the relative geographic market, aware of
Falstaff's presence on the periphery, would not exercise their
ostensible market power to raise prices because of the possibility
that Falstaff, sufficiently tempted by the high prices in that
market, would enter. A Government suit challenging a merger or
acquisition can, of course, be premised on this theory, and, if
sufficient evidence to convince the trier of fact is introduced,
the determination that the merger or acquisition violated § 7
would not be reversed on appeal.
As my Brother MARSHALL convincingly demonstrates, however, in
this case, the Government neither proceeded on the theory advanced
by the Court nor introduced
any
Page 410 U. S. 574
evidence that would support that theory. The theory that the
Government did advance, and upon which it offered its evidence, is
concisely summarized in the Government's statement in opposition to
Falstaff's motion to dismiss.
"In our opening statement, we attempted to show that the
Government would prove -- and I believe we have -- that Falstaff,
the fourth largest brewing corporation in the nation, had a
continuous intensive interest in entering New England; that it
carried on negotiations for five years with companies serving New
England; that alternative methods of entry other than the
acquisition of the largest New England brewer were available to
Falstaff; and that it was, in fact, one of a few and the most
likely entrant into this market; that its entrance into this market
was especially important, because the market is concentrated; that
is, the sales of beer in New England are highly concentrated in the
hands of the relatively few number of brewers."
"The entry by Falstaff by building a brewery, by shipping into
this market, and opening it up, by the acquisition of a company
less than number 1, thereby eliminating its most significant
potential competitor, were all available to it. Because of the
concentration in the market and because of Falstaff's being the
most potential entrant, the acquisition by Falstaff of the leading
firm in this market eliminated what we consider to be one of a few
potential competitive effects that this market could expect for
years."
Transcript, Vol. 3, p. 7.
For this Court to reverse and to remand for consideration of a
possible factual basis for a theory never advanced by the plaintiff
is a drastic and unwarranted departure from the most basic
principles of civil litigation
Page 410 U. S. 575
and appellate review. In this case, the Government originally
advanced one theory, but failed to introduce sufficient evidence to
convince the trier of fact. That failure is "a not uncommon form of
litigation casualty, from which the Government is no more immune
than others."
United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 338 U.S. at
338 U. S. 341.
The Court now resuscitates this "casualty" by use of a theory
transplant, allowing the Government a second opportunity to
vindicate its position by arguing a different theory not originally
propounded before the District Court or on appeal. I cannot join in
the Court's rescue operation for this "litigation casualty," an
operation which succeeds only by flagrantly disregarding some of
the axioms upon which our judicial system is founded.
Although agreeing with my Brother MARSHALL's criticism of the
Court's reason for remanding this case, I cannot agree with his
grounds for remanding to the District Court for reconsideration.
That theory is based, erroneously I believe, on the notion that
there is an identifiable difference between "objective" and
"subjective" evidence in an antitrust case such as this. My Brother
MARSHALL would have the District Court weigh "objective" evidence
more heavily than "subjective" evidence. In the field of economic
forecasting in general, and in the area of potential competition in
particular, however, the distinction between "objective" and
"subjective" evidence is largely illusory. It is, I believe,
incorrect to state that a trier of fact can determine "objectively"
what "is in a firm's economic self-interest." Such a determination
is guesswork. The term "economic self-interest" is a convenient
shorthand for describing the economic decision reached by an
individual or firm, but does not connote some simple, mechanical
formula which determines the input values, or their assigned
weight, in the process of economic decisionmaking. The simple fact
is that any economic decision is largely subjective.
Page 410 U. S. 576
In the instant case, Falstaff sought to prove why it was not in
the "economic self-interest" of that firm to enter a new geographic
market without an established distribution system. Its explanation
is as "objective" as any of the evidence offered by the Government
to show why a hypothetical Falstaff should enter the market. The
question of who is an "actual potential competitor" is entirely
factual. In deciding questions of fact, it is the province of the
trier to weigh all of the evidence; but it is peculiarly his
province to determine questions of credibility.
"Findings as to the design, motive and intent with which men act
depend peculiarly upon the credit given to witnesses by those who
see and hear them. . . ."
". . . There is no exception [to the 'clearly erroneous' rule of
appellate review] which permits [the Government], even in an
antitrust case, to come to this Court for what virtually amounts to
a trial
de novo on the record of such findings as intent,
motive and design."
United States v. Yellow Cab Co., 338 U.S. at
338 U. S.
341-342.
I would not ignore our prior decisions or rewrite the rules of
evidence simply to afford the Government a second chance, which is
uniformly denied to other litigants, to convince the trier of
fact.