Appellants, recipients of Aid to Families With Dependent
Children (AFDC), challenge the system whereby Texas, in order to
allocate its fixed pool of welfare money among persons with
acknowledged need, applies a percentage reduction factor to arrive
at a reduced standard of need, the factor being lower for AFDC than
for other categorical assistance programs. Appellants assert that
the State's method of applying this factor to recipients with
outside income contravenes § 402(a)(23) of the Social Security
Act, which required adjustment, by July 1, 1969, of "amounts used .
. . to determine the needs of individuals" to reflect increases in
living costs, because this method does not increase the welfare
rolls to the same extent as would an alternative procedure used by
some other States. They also make an equal protection claim on the
grounds that the distinction between the aid programs is not
rational, and that the Texas system racially discriminates against
the proportionately larger number of minority groups in AFDC than
in the other programs.
Held:
1. The Texas scheme does not contravene § 402(a)(23) of the
Social Security Act, which does not require use of a computation
procedure that maximizes individual eligibility for subsidiary
benefits. Pp.
406 U. S.
539-545.
2. The challenged system does not violate the Equal Protection
Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. Pp.
406 U. S.
545-551.
(a) The fact that there are more members of minority groups in
the AFDC program than in other categories does not indicate racial
discrimination, absent any proof of racial motivation in the Texas
scheme. There was no such proof here. Pp.
406 U. S.
547-549.
(b) Texas' decision to provide somewhat lower welfare benefits
for AFDC recipients than for the aged and infirm who are in other
categories is not invidious or irrational, and there is no
constitutional or statutory requirement that relief categories be
treated exactly alike. Pp.
406 U. S. 549-551.
Affirmed.
Page 406 U. S. 536
REHNQUIST, J., delivered the opinion of the Court, in which
BURGER, C.J., and WHITE, BLACKMUN, and POWELL, JJ., joined.
STEWART, J., filed a statement joining in Part III of the Court's
opinion,
post, p.
406 U. S. 551. DOUGLAS, J., filed a dissenting opinion,
in which BRENNAN, J., joined,
post, p.
406 U. S. 551.
MARSHALL, J., filed a dissenting opinion, in which BRENNAN, J.,
joined, and in Part I of which STEWART, J., joined,
post,
p.
406 U. S.
558.
MR. JUSTICE REHNQUIST delivered the opinion of the Court.
Appellants in this case challenge certain computation procedures
that the State of Texas uses in its federally assisted welfare
program. Believing that neither the Constitution nor the federal
welfare statute prohibits the State from adopting these policies,
we affirm the judgment of the three-judge court below upholding the
state procedures.
I
Appellants are Texas recipients of Aid to Families With
Dependent Children (AFDC). They brought two class
Page 406 U. S. 537
actions, which were consolidated in the United States District
Court for the Northern District of Texas, seeking injunctive and
declaratory relief against state welfare officials. A three-judge
court was convened pursuant to 28 U.S.C. § 2281.
The Texas State Constitution provides a ceiling on the amount
the State can spend on welfare assistance grants. [
Footnote 1] In order to allocate this fixed
pool of welfare money among the numerous individuals with
acknowledged need, the State has adopted a system of percentage
grants. Under this system the State first computes the monetary
needs of individuals eligible for relief under each of the
federally aided categorical assistance programs. [
Footnote 2] Then, since the constitutional
ceiling on welfare is insufficient to bring each recipient up to
this full standard of need, the State applies a percentage
reduction factor [
Footnote 3]
in order to arrive at a reduced standard of need in each category
that the State can guarantee.
Appellants challenge the constitutionality of applying a lower
percentage reduction factor to AFDC than to
Page 406 U. S. 538
the other categorical assistance programs. They claim a
violation of equal protection because the proportion of AFDC
recipients who are black or Mexican-American is higher than the
proportion of the aged, blind, or disabled welfare recipients who
fall within these minority groups. Appellants claim that the
distinction between the programs is not rationally related to the
purposes of the Social Security Act, and violates the Fourteenth
Amendment for that reason as well. In their original complaint,
appellants also argued that any percentage reduction system
violated § 402(a)(23) of the Social Security Act of 1935, as
amended, 81 Stat. 898, 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(23), which required
each State to make certain cost of living adjustments to its
standard of need.
The three-judge court rejected appellants' constitutional
arguments, finding that the Texas system is neither racially
discriminatory nor unconstitutionally arbitrary. The court did,
however, accept the statutory claim that Texas' percentage
reductions in the AFDC program violate the congressional command of
§ 402(a)(23).
304 F.
Supp. 1332 (ND Tex.1969).
Subsequent to that judgment, this Court decided
Rosado v.
Wyman, 397 U. S. 397
(1970).
Rosado held that, although 402(a)(23) required
States to make cost of living adjustments in their standard of need
calculations, it did not prohibit use of percentage reduction
systems that limited the amount of welfare assistance actually
paid. 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 413.
This Court then vacated and remanded the first
Jefferson
judgment for further proceedings consistent with
Rosado.
397 U. S. 821
(1970).
On remand, the District Court entered a new judgment, denying
all relief. Then, in a motion to amend the judgment, appellants
raised a new statutory claim. They argued for the first time that,
although a percentage reduction system may be consistent with the
statute, the
Page 406 U. S. 539
specific procedures that Texas uses for computing that reduction
violate the congressional enactment. The District Court rejected
this argument and denied without opinion appellants' motion to
amend the judgment. This appeal under 28 U.S.C. § 1253 then
followed, and we noted probable jurisdiction. 404 U.S. 820
(1971).
II
Appellants' statutory argument relates to the method that the
State uses to compute the percentage reduction when the recipient
also has some outside income. Texas, like many other States,
[
Footnote 4] first applies the
percentage reduction factor to the recipient's standard of need,
thus arriving at a reduced standard of need that the State can
guarantee for each recipient within the present budgetary
restraints. After computing this reduced standard of need, the
State then subtracts any nonexempt [
Footnote 5] income in order to arrive at the level of
benefits that the recipient needs in order to reach his reduced
standard of need. This is the amount of welfare the recipient is
given.
Under an alternative system used by other States, the order of
computation is reversed. First, the outside income is subtracted
from the standard of need, in order to determine the recipient's
"unmet need." Then the percentage reduction factor is applied to
the unmet need in order to determine the welfare benefits
payable.
The two systems of accounting for outside income yield different
results. [
Footnote 6] Under the
Texas system, all
Page 406 U. S. 540
welfare recipients with the same needs have the same amount of
money available each month, whether or not they have outside
income. Since the outside income is applied dollar for dollar to
the reduced standard of need, which the welfare department would
otherwise pay in full, it does not result in a net improvement in
the financial position of the recipient. Under the alternative
system, on the other hand, any welfare recipient who also has
outside income is in a better financial position because of it. The
reason is that the percentage reduction factor there is applied to
the "unmet need," after the income has been subtracted. Thus, in
effect, the income-earning recipient is able to "keep" all his
income, while he receives only a percentage of the remainder of his
standard of need. [
Footnote
7]
Page 406 U. S. 541
Each of the two systems has certain advantages. Appellants note
that, under the alternative system, there is a financial incentive
for welfare recipients to obtain outside income. The Texas
computation method eliminates any such financial incentive, so long
as the outside income remains less than the recipient's reduced
standard of need. [
Footnote 8]
However, since Texas' pool of available welfare funds is fixed, any
increase in benefits paid to the working poor would have to be
offset by reductions elsewhere. Thus, if Texas were to switch to
the alternative system of recognizing outside income, it would be
forced to lower its percentage reduction factor, in order to keep
down its welfare budget. Lowering the percentage would result in
less money for those who need the welfare benefits the most --
those with no outside income -- and the State has been unwilling to
do this.
Striking the proper balance between these competing policy
considerations is, of course, not the function of this Court.
"There is no question that States have considerable latitude in
allocating their AFDC resources, since each State is free to set
its own standard of need and to determine the level of benefits by
the amount of funds it devotes to the program."
King v. Smith, 392 U. S. 309,
392 U. S.
318-319 (1968) (footnotes omitted). [
Footnote 9] So long as the State's actions are not
in violation of any specific provision of the Constitution or the
Social Security Act, appellants' policy arguments must be addressed
to a different forum.
Page 406 U. S. 542
Appellants assert, however, that the Texas computation
procedures are contrary to § 402(a)(23):
"(a) A State plan for aid and services to needy families with
children must"
"
* * * *"
"(23) provide that, by July 1, 1969, the amounts used by the
State to determine the needs of individuals will have been adjusted
to reflect fully changes in living costs since such amounts were
established, and any maximums that the State imposes on the amount
of aid paid to families will have been proportionately
adjusted."
Recognizing that this statutory language, by its terms, hardly
provides much support for their theory, appellants seek to rely on
what they perceive to have been the broad congressional purpose in
enacting the provision.
In
Rosado v. Wyman, supra, the Court reviewed the
history of this section and rejected the argument that it had
worked any radical shift in the AFDC program.
Id. at
397 U. S. 414
and n. 17. AFDC has long been referred to as a "scheme of
cooperative federalism,"
King v. Smith, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 316,
and the
Rosado Court dismissed as "adventuresome" any
interpretation of § 402(a)(23) that would deprive the States
of their traditional discretion to set the levels of payments. 397
U.S. at
397 U. S.
414-415 and n. 17. Instead, the statute was meant to
require the States to make cost of living adjustments to their
standards of need, thereby serving "two broad purposes":
"First, to require States to face up realistically to the
magnitude of the public assistance requirement and lay bare the
extent to which their programs fall short of fulfilling actual
need; second, to prod the States to apportion their payments on a
more equitable basis."
Id. at
397 U. S.
412-413.
Page 406 U. S. 543
Texas has complied with these two requirements. Effective May 1,
1969, the standard of need for AFDC recipients was raised 11% to
reflect the rise in the cost of living, and the State shifted from
a maximum grant system to its present percentage reduction system.
In this way, the State has fairly recognized and exposed the
precise level of unmet need, and, by using a percentage reduction
system, it has attempted to apportion the State's limited benefits
more equitably.
Although Texas has thus responded to the "two broad purposes" of
§ 402(a)(23), appellants argue that Congress also intended
that statute to increase the total number of recipients of AFDC, so
that more people would qualify for the subsidiary benefits that are
dependent on receipt of AFDC cash assistance. [
Footnote 10] The Texas computation procedures
are thought objectionable since they do not increase the welfare
rolls to quite the same extent as would the alternative method of
recognizing outside income.
We do not agree that Congress intended § 402(a)(23) to
invalidate any state computation procedures that do not absolutely
maximize individual eligibility for subsidiary benefits. The cost
of living increase that Congress mandated would, of course,
generally tend to increase eligibility, [
Footnote 11] but there is nothing in the legislative
history
Page 406 U. S. 544
indicating that this was part of the statutory purpose. Indeed,
at the same time Congress enacted § 402(a)(23), it included
another section designed to induce States to reduce the number of
individuals eligible for the AFDC program. [
Footnote 12] Thus, what little legislative
history there is on the point,
see Rosado v. Wyman, 397
U.S. at
397 U. S.
409-412, tends to undercut appellants' theory.
See
Lampton v. Bonin, 304
F. Supp. 1384, 1391-1392 (ED La.1969) (Cassibry, J.,
dissenting).
See generally Note, 58 Geo.L.J. 591
(1970).
Appellants also argue that the Texas system should be held
invalid because the alternative computation method results in
greater work incentives for welfare recipients. [
Footnote 13] The history and purpose of the
Social Security Act do indicate Congress' desire to help those on
welfare become self-sustaining. Indeed, Congress has specifically
mandated certain work incentives in § 402(a)(8). There is no
dispute here, however, about Texas' compliance with these very
detailed provisions for work incentives. Neither their inclusion in
the Act nor the language used by Congress in other sections of the
Act supports the inference that Congress mandated the States to
change their income-computation procedures in other, completely
unmentioned areas.
Nor are appellants aided by their reference to Social Security
Act § 402(a)(10), 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(10), which provides
that AFDC benefits must "be furnished
Page 406 U. S. 545
with reasonable promptness to all eligible individuals." That
section was enacted at a time when persons whom the State had
determined to be eligible for the payment of benefits were placed
on waiting lists, because of the shortage of state funds. The
statute was intended to prevent the States from denying benefits,
even temporarily, to a person who has been found fully qualified
for aid.
See H.R.Rep. No. 1300, 81st Cong., 1st Sess., 48,
148 (1949); 95 Cong.Rec. 13934 (remarks of Rep. Forand). Section
402(a)(10) also prohibits a State from creating certain exceptions
to standards specifically enunciated in the federal Act.
See,
e.g., Townsend v. Swank, 404 U. S. 282
(1971). It does not, however, enact by implication a generalized
federal criterion to which States must adhere in their computation
of standards of need, income, and benefits. [
Footnote 14] Such an interpretation would be an
intrusion into an area in which Congress has given the States broad
discretion, and we cannot accept appellants' invitation to change
this longstanding statutory scheme simply for policy consideration
reasons of which we are not the arbiter.
III
We turn, then, to appellants' claim that the Texas system of
percentage reductions violates the Fourteenth Amendment. Appellants
believe that, once the State has computed a standard of need for
each recipient, it is arbitrary and discriminatory to provide only
75% of that standard to AFDC recipients, while paying 100% of
recognized need to the aged, and 95% to the disabled and the blind.
They argue that, if the State adopts a
Page 406 U. S. 546
percentage reduction system, it must apply the same percentage
to each of its welfare programs.
This claim was properly rejected by the court below. It is clear
from the statutory framework hat, although the four categories of
public assistance found in the Social Security Act have certain
common elements, the States were intended by Congress to keep their
AFDC plans separate from plans under the other titles of the Act.
[
Footnote 15] A State is
free to participate in one, several, or all of the categorical
assistance programs, as it chooses. It is true that each of the
programs is intended to assist the needy, but it does not follow
that there is only one constitutionally permissible way for the
State to approach this important goal.
This Court emphasized only recently, in
Dandridge v.
Williams, 397 U. S. 471,
397 U. S. 485
(1970), that, in
"the area of economics and social welfare, a State does not
violate the Equal Protection Clause merely because the
classifications made by its laws are imperfect."
A legislature may address a problem "one step at a time," or
even "select one phase of one field and apply a remedy there,
neglecting the others."
Williamson v. Lee Optical Co.,
348 U. S. 483,
348 U. S. 489
(1955). So long as its judgments are rational, and not invidious,
the legislature's efforts to tackle the problems of the poor and
the needy are not subject to a constitutional straitjacket. The
very complexity of the problems suggests that there will be
more
Page 406 U. S. 547
than one constitutionally permissible method of solving
them.
The standard of judicial review is not altered because of
appellants' unproved allegations of racial discrimination. The
three-judge court found that the
"payment by Texas of a lesser percentage of unmet needs to the
recipients of the AFDC than to the recipients of other welfare
programs is not the result of racial or ethnic prejudice, and is
not violative of the federal Civil Rights Act or the Equal
Protection Clause of the 14th Amendment."
The District Court obviously gave careful consideration to this
issue, and we are cited by its opinion to a number of subsidiary
facts to support its principal finding quoted above. There has
never been a reduction in the amount of money appropriated by the
legislature to the AFDC program, and, between 1943 and the date of
the opinion below, there had been five increases in the amount of
money appropriated by the legislature for the program, two of them
having occurred since 1959. [
Footnote 16] The overall percentage increase in
appropriation for the programs between 1943 and the time of the
District Court's hearing in this case was 410% for AFDC, as opposed
to 211% for OAA and 200% for AB. The court further concluded:
"The depositions of Welfare officials conclusively establish
that the defendants did not know the racial make-up of the various
welfare assistance categories prior to or at the time when the
orders here under attack were issued."
Appellants, in their brief, in effect abandon any effort
Page 406 U. S. 548
to show that these findings of fact were clearly erroneous, and
we hold they were not.
Appellants are thus left with their naked statistical argument:
that there is a larger percentage of Negroes and Mexican-Americans
in AFDC than in the other programs, [
Footnote 17] and that the AFDC is funded at 75%, whereas
the other programs are funded at 95% and 100% of recognized need.
As the statistics cited in the footnote demonstrate, the number of
minority members in all categories is substantial. The basic
outlines of eligibility for the various categorical grants are
established by Congress, not by the States; given the heterogeneity
of the Nation's population, it would be only an infrequent
coincidence that the racial composition of each grant class was
identical to that of the others. The acceptance of appellants'
constitutional theory would render suspect each difference in
treatment among the grant classes, however lacking in racial
motivation and however otherwise rational the treatment might be.
Few legislative efforts to deal with the difficult problems posed
by current welfare programs could survive
Page 406 U. S. 549
such scrutiny, and we do not find it required by the Fourteenth
Amendment. [
Footnote 18]
Applying the traditional standard of review under that
amendment, we cannot say that Texas' decision to provide somewhat
lower welfare benefits for AFDC recipients is invidious or
irrational. Since budgetary constraints do not allow the payment of
the full standard of need for all welfare recipients, the State may
have concluded that the aged and infirm are the least able of the
categorical grant recipients to bear the hardships of an inadequate
standard of living. While different policy judgments are, of
course, possible, it is not irrational for the State to believe
that the young are more adaptable than the sick and elderly,
especially because the latter have less hope of improving their
situation in the years remaining to them. Whether or not one agrees
with this state determination, there is nothing in the Constitution
that forbids it. [
Footnote
19]
Similarly, we cannot accept the argument in MR.
Page 406 U. S. 550
JUSTICE MARSHALL's dissent that the Social Security Act itself
requires equal percentages for each categorical assistance program.
The dissent concedes that a State might simply refuse to
participate in the AFDC program, while continuing to receive
federal money for the other categorical programs.
See post
at
406 U. S. 577.
Nevertheless, it is argued that Congress intended to prohibit any
middle ground -- once the State does participate in a program, it
must do so on the same basis as it participates in every other
program. Such an all-or-nothing policy judgment may well be
defensible, and the dissenters may be correct that nothing in the
statute expressly rejects it. But neither does anything in the
statute approve or require it. [
Footnote 20]
Page 406 U. S. 551
In conclusion, we reemphasize what the Court said in
Dandridge v. Williams, 37 U.S. at
37 U. S.
487:
"We do not decide today that the [state law] is wise, that it
best fulfills the relevant social and economic objectives that [the
State] might ideally espouse, or that a more just and humane system
could not be devised. Conflicting claims of morality and
intelligence are raised by opponents and proponents of almost every
measure, certainly including the one before us. But the intractable
economic, social, and even philosophical problems presented by
public welfare assistance programs are not the business of this
Court. . . . [T]he Constitution does not empower this Court to
second-guess state officials charged with the difficult
responsibility of allocating limited public welfare funds among the
myriad of potential recipients."
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins in Part III of the Court s
opinion.
[
Footnote 1]
Originally, the Texas Constitution prohibited all welfare
programs. Section 51 of Art. III of the Constitution provided that
the legislature
"shall have no power to make any grant or authorize the making
of any grant of public moneys to any individual, association of
individuals, municipal or other corporations whatsoever. . . ."
However, beginning in 1933, exceptions to this rule were added
to the state constitution in § 51-a, which now allows
participation in the federal welfare programs, but limits state
financing to the sum of $80,000,000. The legislature cannot exceed
this welfare budget without a state constitutional amendment.
[
Footnote 2]
Old Age Assistance (OAA), 42 U.S.C. § 301
et seq.;
Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC), 42 U.S.C. §
601
et seq.; Aid to the Blind (AB), 42 U.S.C. § 1201
et seq.; Aid for the Permanently and Totally Disabled
(APTD), 42 U.S.C. § 1351
et seq.
[
Footnote 3]
At the present time these factors are: OAA -- 100%; AB -- 96%;
APTD -- 95%; and AFDC -- 75%. At the time this suit was instituted
the AFDC percentage was 50%, but it was raised to 75% following a
recent amendment of § 51-a.
See n 1,
supra.
[
Footnote 4]
Nineteen of the 26 States that use a percentage reduction system
follow the Texas procedure of accounting for outside income.
See Memorandum for the United States as
Amicus
Curiae 8, 15-16.
[
Footnote 5]
A certain portion of earned income must be exempted as a work
incentive.
See 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(8).
[
Footnote 6]
Assuming two identical families, each with a standard of need of
$200 and outside, nonexempt income of $100, the two systems would
produce these results:
Texas System Alternative System
$ 200 (need) $ 200 (need)
x.75 Co reduction factor) -100 (outside income)
----- -----
$ 150 (reduced need) $ 100 (unmet need)
-100 (outside income) x.75 (% reduction factor)
----- -----
$ 50 (benefits payable) $ 75 (benefits payable)
[
Footnote 7]
Assuming two families with identical standards of need, but only
one with outside income, the alternative system leaves more money
in the hands of the family with outside income:
Outside Income No Outside Income
$ 200 (need) $ 200 (need)
-100 (outside income) - O (outside income)
----- -----
$ 100 (unmet need) $ 200 (unmet need)
x.75 (% reduction factor) x.75 (% reduction factor)
----- -----
$ 75 (benefits payable) $ 150 (benefits payable)
TOTAL INCOME (outside TOTAL INCOME (outside
income plus benefits pay- income plus benefits pay-
able) = $ 175 able) = $ 150
[
Footnote 8]
Under the Texas system, once the income rises above the reduced
standard of need, the individual no longer receives any cash
assistance. He then would have a financial incentive, since his
income would be rising above the maximum he could expect from the
welfare system.
[
Footnote 9]
For a general review of the statutory scheme,
see Rosado v.
Wyman, 397 U. S. 397,
397 U. S.
407-412 (1970).
[
Footnote 10]
Certain care-and-training provisions of the Social Security Act
are available only to those who receive money payments under the
categorical assistance programs.
See 42 U.S.C.
§§ 602(a)(14), (15); 42 U.S.C. §§ 602(a)(19),
632; 42 U.S.C. § 1396a(a)(10). Under the Texas computation
procedures, those whose income exceed their reduced standard of
need receive no cash benefits, and thus do not qualify for these
subsidiary benefits, although they do have "unmet need" qualifying
them for aid under the alternative computation procedure.
[
Footnote 11]
The Court in
Rosado recognized this a one of several
effect attributable to § 402(a)(23). 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 413.
See also id. at
397 U. S. 409
n. 13. The Court did not, however, hold that each one of these
effects was intended by Congress. In fact, the
Rosado
holding as to the "two broad purposes" of Congress was stated
above, and the Texas system is perfectly consistent with it. The
Court mentioned widened eligibility simply as one of several
possible effects that might follow from the statute as so
construed.
[
Footnote 12]
Act of Jan. 2, 1968, Pub.L. No. 90-248, Tit. II, § 208, 81
Stat. 894, repealed 83 Stat. 45.
[
Footnote 13]
See n 7,
supra.
[
Footnote 14]
Appellants' reliance on language from
Dandridge v.
Williams, 397 U. S. 471,
397 U. S.
480-481 (1970), is misplaced. The Court there explicitly
failed to reach the State's argument that the purpose of §
402(a)(10) was primarily to prevent the use of waiting lists.
Id. at
397 U. S. 481
n. 12.
[
Footnote 15]
Each categorical assistance program is embodied in a separate
title of the Social Security Act,
see n 2,
supra, and requires a state plan
independent of the plans under the other titles. In 1962, however,
Congress enacted 42 U.S.C. §§ 1381-1385, which for the
first time enabled States to combine their plans, but only for the
non-AFDC programs. Thus, while Congress has now enabled States to
adopt a common plan for the other programs, it considered AFDC
sufficiently different so as to require an independent plan.
[
Footnote 16]
Since the original opinion below, there has been an additional
increase. Following a constitutional amendment,
see
n 3,
supra, the
appropriation has risen from $6,150,000 to $23,100,000.
[
Footnote 17]
Percentage of Negroes Percentage of Number of
Program Year and Mexican-Americans White-Anglos Recipients
--------------------------------------------------------------
OAA 1969 39.8 60.2
1968 38.7 61.3 230,000
1967 37.0 63.0
--------------------------------------------------------------
APTD 1969 46.9 53.1
1968 45.6 54.4 4,213
1967 46.2 53.8
--------------------------------------------------------------
AB 1969 55.7 44.3
1968 54.9 45.1 14,043
--------------------------------------------------------------
AFDC 1969 87.0 13.0
1968 84.9 15.1 136,000
1967 86.0 14.0
--------------------------------------------------------------
[
Footnote 18]
In
James v. Valtierra, 402 U.
S. 137 (1971), it was contended that a California
referendum requirement violated the Fourteenth Amendment because it
imposed a mandatory referendum in the case of an ordinance
authorizing low income housing, while referenda with respect to
other types of ordinances had to be initiated by the action of
private individuals. The Court responded:
"But, of course, a lawmaking procedure that 'disadvantages' a
particular group does not always deny equal protection. Under any
such holding, presumably a State would not be able to require
referendums on any subject unless referendums were required on all,
because they would always disadvantage some group. And this Court
would be required to analyze governmental structures to determine
whether a gubernatorial veto provision or a filibuster rule is
likely to 'disadvantage' any of the diverse and shifting groups
that make up the American people."
Id. at
402 U. S.
142.
[
Footnote 19]
Just as the State's actions here do not violate the Fourteenth
Amendment, we conclude that they do not violate Title VI of the
Civil Rights Act of 1964, 42 U.S.C. § 2000d
et seq.
The Civil Rights Act prohibits discrimination in federally financed
programs. We have, however, upheld the findings of
nondiscriminatory purpose in the percentage reductions used by
Texas, and have concluded that the variation in percentages is
rationally related to the purposes of the separate welfare
programs. The Court's decision in
Griggs v. Duke Power
Co., 401 U. S. 424
(1971), is therefore inapposite. In
Griggs, the employment
tests having racially discriminatory effects were found not to be
job-related, and, for that reason, were impermissible under the
specific language of Title VII of the Civil Rights Act. Since the
Texas procedure challenged here is related to the purposes of the
welfare programs, it is not proscribed by Title VI simply because
of variances in the racial composition of the different categorical
programs.
[
Footnote 20]
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL's dissent cites the 1950 amendments to the
Social Security Act as support for its novel statutory theory that
States must provide equal aid levels in each welfare category. The
1950 amendments included "a revised method of determining the
Federal share of assistance costs," 95 Cong.Rec. 13932, so that the
Federal Government would pay a substantially equal percentage of
matching funds to state plans in each of the categorical assistance
programs.
See S.Doc. No. 208, 80th Cong., 2d Sess., 101.
But this revision of the grant-in-aid formula in § 403 of the
Act was not accompanied by any corresponding amendment of §
402, the section of the Act dealing with congressional limitations
on state AFDC programs. Indeed, proponents of the 1950 amendments
explicitly recognized and endorsed the longstanding policy that the
Federal Government sets only minimum AFDC standards, while leaving
the States "wide discretion both in determining policies and in
setting standards of need." S.Doc. No. 208,
supra, at 101.
The enactment of a modified grant-in-aid formula hardly suggests
Congress' intent to engage in "extensive alteration of the basic
underlying structure of an established program."
Rosado v.
Wyman, 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 414
n. 17.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, with whom MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN concurs,
dissenting.
I would read the Act more generously than does the Court. It is
stipulated that 87% of those receiving AFDC aid are blacks or
Chicanos. I would therefore
Page 406 U. S. 552
read the Act against the background of rank discrimination
against the blacks and the Chicanos and in light of the fact that
Chicanos in Texas fare even more poorly than the blacks.
See L. Grebler, J. Moore, & R. Guzman, The
Mexican-American People, pt.s. 2 and 3 (1970); J. Burma,
Mexican-Americans in the United States 143-199 (1970); Schwartz,
State Discrimination Against Mexican Aliens, 38 Geo.Wash.L.Rev.
1091 (1970); U.S. Commission on Civil Rights, The Mexican American
(1968); U.S. Commission on Civil Rights, Mexican Americans and the
Administration of Justice in the Southwest (1970). In
Rosado v.
Wyman, 397 U. S. 397,
397 U. S. 413,
we aid that, in administering such a program, a State "may not
obscure the actual standard of need." Texas does precisely that, by
manipulating a mathematical formula.
In
Rosado, we described how some States establish upper
limits or maximums of aid, while others, like Texas,
"curtail the payments of benefits by a system of 'ratable
reductions' whereby all recipients will receive a fixed percentage
of the standard of need."
Id. at
397 U. S. 409.
Then, in footnote 13, we described what that meant:
"A 'ratable reduction' represents a fixed percentage of the
standard of need that will be paid to all recipients. In the event
that there is some income that is first deducted, the ratable
reduction is applied to the amount by which the individual or
family income falls short of need."
Id. at
397 U. S. 409
n. 13 (emphasis added).
If Texas first deducted outside income and then made its ratable
reduction, the welfare recipient would receive a somewhat more
generous payment, as the opinion of the Court illustrates in
footnote 6 of its opinion Not
only does the Texas system avoid this generous approach, but it
also impermissibly constricts the standard of need in conflict with
Rosado, 397 U. S.
Williams, 397 U.S.
Page 406 U. S. 553
471, and
Townsend v. Swank, 404 U.
S. 282. Under Texas' method of computation, a family --
otherwise eligible for AFDC benefits but with nonexempt income
greater than the level of benefits and less that the standard of
need -- is denied both AFDC cash benefits and other non-cash
benefits such as medicaid. [
Footnote
2/1] It seems inconceivable that Congress could have intended
that non-cash benefits be denied those with incomes less than the
standard of need solely because that income was earned, rather than
from categorical assistance. Yet this is precisely the result
sanctioned by the Court today because eligibility for these
programs is tied to the receipt of cash benefits. [
Footnote 2/2]
Page 406 U. S. 554
One of the stated purposes of the AFDC program is
"to help such parents or relatives [of needy dependent children]
to attain or retain capability for the maximum self-support and
personal independence."
42 U.S.C. § 601 (emphasis added). The Senate Finance
Committee has stated, "A key element in any program for work and
training for assistance recipients is
an incentive for people
to take employment." S.Rep. No. 744, 90th Cong., 1st Sess.,
157 (1967) (emphasis added). The majority acknowledges that "[t]he
history and purpose of the Social Security Act . . . indicate
Congress' desire to help those on welfare become self-sustaining."
Ante at
406 U. S. 544.
But it nonetheless ignores the explicit congressional policy in
favor of work incentives, and upholds a system which provides
penalties and disincentives for those who seek employment.
[
Footnote 2/3]
Page 406 U. S. 555
The California Supreme Court, in
Villa v.
Hall, 6 Cal. 3d 227,
490 P.2d 1148, struck down the system this Court approves today,
where California used a statutory maximum of payments, rather than
a ratable reduction. The California Supreme Court quite properly
said that what the State was attempting was inconsistent with
Rosado. Moreover, it had an additional reason:
"The conclusion that the Social Security Act requires outside
income to be subtracted from standards of need, rather than from
statutory maximums or ratable reductions, is also founded on a
strong public policy of encouraging welfare recipients to become
constantly more self-supporting. Yet deducting income from
statutory maximums makes gainful employment significantly less
attractive to the recipient. This follows because all nonexempt
income will be offset directly against the amount of the grant, and
not against the standard of need to determine actual need; for
every nonexempt dollar earned, the amount of aid will therefore be
decreased one dollar. Since the grant is always less than the
standard of need, in many instances, the system adopted by the
Welfare Reform Act will result in an individual's need not being
met even after adding both exempt and nonexempt income to the AFDC
payment. Such recipients will be forced to exist below the bare
minimum necessary for adequate care, even though they have
commenced, by obtaining employment, to break free from the
debilitating 'welfare syndrome.' The practice thus conflicts
with
Page 406 U. S. 556
the stated federal policy to provide incentives to obtain and
maintain an employment status."
Id. at 235-236, 490 P.2d at 1153-1154.
Moreover,
Townsend v. Swank, 404 U.
S. 282, calls for a reversal in the present case. It is
conceded that plaintiff Maria T. Davilla and 2,470 other families
are denied aid in Texas by reason of its new formula,
see 304 F.
Supp. 1332, 1343, despite the fact that their income is below
the standard of need and that of those receiving AFDC aid only 75%
of their needs is met. [
Footnote
2/4]
Under § 402(a)(10) of the Social Security Act (which
governs AFDC), "aid to families with dependent children shall be
furnished with reasonable promptness to all eligible individuals."
42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(10). In
Townsend, children 18
through 20 years of age who attended high school or vocational
training were eligible for AFDC benefits, but such children in
college were not eligible. We held that
"a state eligibility standard that excludes persons eligible for
assistance under federal AFDC standards violates the Social
Security Act, and is therefore invalid under the Supremacy Clause.
[
Footnote 2/5]"
404 U.S. at
404 U. S.
286.
Page 406 U. S. 557
What Texas does here is to exclude large numbers of AFDC
beneficiaries by application of a state eligibility test that is
narrower than the one we approved in
Rosado. While a State
has some discretion in its use of federal funds, it may not
manipulate, by its own formula, groups of "needy" claimants. The
decision to participate or not in the federal program is left to
the States.
Townsend v. Swank, supra, at
404 U. S.
290-291. When, as here, federal and state funds are in
short supply, the problem is not to lop off some categories of
those in "need," but to design a way of managing the system of
"need" so as not to raise equal protection questions. [
Footnote 2/6]
Id. at
404 U. S.
291.
Page 406 U. S. 558
Section 402(a) (10) of the Social Security Act provides that
AFDC shall be furnished with reasonable promptness to all eligible
individuals. The House Report, in commenting on it, said:
"Shortage of funds in aid to dependent children has sometimes,
as in old-age assistance, resulted in a decision not to take more
applications or to keep eligible families on waiting lists until
enough recipients could be removed from the assistance rolls to
make a place for them. . . . [T]his difference in treatment
accorded to eligible people results in undue hardship on needy
persons, and is inappropriate in a program financed from Federal
funds."
H.R. Rep No. 1300, 81st Cong., 1st Sess., 48 (1949).
As the Court said in
Dandridge v. Williams, 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 481,
"So long as some aid is provided to all eligible families and all
eligible children, the statute itself is not violated." It is
violated here, because nearly 2,500 families that satisfy the
requirements of "need" are denied any relief. [
Footnote 2/7]
[
Footnote 2/1]
The Court's acknowledgment that
"[t]he Texas computation method eliminates any . . . financial
incentive [for welfare recipients to obtain outside income], so
long as the[ir] outside income remains less than the[ir] . . .
reduced standard of need,"
ante at
406 U. S. 541,
understates the effect of the Texas system on the recipients. The
Texas system not only fails to provide an incentive for those on
the welfare rolls to break the cycle of poverty by obtaining
employment, but -- in certain cases -- it also penalizes those who
seek employment. The family with nonexempt income equal to Texas'
level of benefits stands in much the same cash position as the AFDC
recipient, but, solely because that family has earned that last
marginal dollar that makes it no longer eligible for categorical
assistance, it also is denied medical assistance, social services,
and training. The Solicitor General tells us that the value of the
medical services alone is worth $50-$60 per month to the average
Texas AFDC family. Memorandum for the United States as
Amicus
Curiae 7 n. 5.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Eligibility for family development services is keyed to the
"recei[pt] [of] aid to families with dependent children," 42 U.S.C.
§ 602(a)(14); so, too, with employment assistance,
id. at § 602(a)(15)(A) ("receiving aid under the
plan"); protection against child's neglect or abuse,
id.
at § 602(a)(16) ("receiving aid"); plans to establish
paternity and secure support,
id. at § 602(a)
(17)(A)(i) and (ii) ("receiving aid," "receiving such aid"); work
incentive programs,
id. at § 602(a) (19)(A)(i)
("receiving aid to families with dependent children"); and medical
assistance plans,
id. at § 1396a(a)(10) ("individuals
receiving aid or assistance").
Would Congress have tied needy families' eligibility for these
programs to the receipt of cash benefits had it foreseen that this
Court would disregard the statutory mandate "that aid to families
with dependent children shall be furnished with reasonable
promptness to all eligible individuals"? 42 U.S.C. §
602(a)(10).
[
Footnote 2/3]
The rationale which the Court uses to reach this result is at
odds with time-honored rules of statutory interpretation. First,
the Court gives but a grudging interpretation to the recital in
§ 401 of the Act, 42 U.S.C. § 601, that one of Congress'
purposes was to encourage welfare recipients to become
self-supporting. The Court, in effect, disregards the rule that
recitals embody "the general purpose which . . . Congress undertook
to achieve."
Carter v. Carter Coal Co., 298 U.
S. 238,
298 U. S. 297.
And see Coosaw Mining Co. v. South Carolina, 144 U.
S. 550,
144 U. S. 563;
United States v.
Fisher, 2 Cranch 358,
6 U. S. 386.
Second, the Court attributes to Congress the purpose of providing
work incentives,
e.g., 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(8), while,
at the same time, allowing the imposition of penalties and
disincentives for obtaining employment. The Court departs from the
principle that, "[i]n the exposition of statutes," various sections
of the same act "are supposed to have the same object,"
Kohlsaat v. Murphy, 96 U. S. 153,
96 U. S.
159-160, and holds instead that Congress was working at
cross-purposes in different subsections of § 402, 42 U.S.C.
§ 602. Finally, by giving the Social Security Act a miserly
interpretation, the Court disregards the canon that remedial
legislation, such a the Social Security Act, is to be interpreted
liberally to effectuate its purposes.
E.g., Peyton v.
Rowe, 391 U. S. 54,
391 U. S.
65.
[
Footnote 2/4]
The percentages of need that will be met by Texas under the
various heads are as follows:
Old Age Assistance. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .100%
Aid to the Blind. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95%
Aid to the Permanently and Totally Disabled . . . 95%
Aid to Families with Dependent Children . . . . . 75%
When this action was instituted, Texas' AFDC percentage level of
benefits was only 50% of the standard of need. During the course of
this litigation, Texas increased the AFDC level of benefits to 75%
of need.
[
Footnote 2/5]
To the same effect is our recent decision in
Engelman v.
Amos, 404 U. S. 23
(1971),
aff'g sub nom. X v. McCorkle, 333
F. Supp. 1109 (NJ 1970). There, relying on
Rosado v.
Wyman, 397 U. S. 397, the
District Court held inconsistent with the Social Security Act --
and thus unconstitutional under the Supremacy Clause -- a state
provision which denied AFDC cash payments and ancillary benefits to
those whose nonexempt income was less than the standard of need
established by the State. We unanimously affirmed that decision. To
be sure,
Engelman dealt with federal provisions different
from those presently in issue (42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(8)(A)(ii);
45 CFR § 233.20(a)(3)(ii)), but that does not distinguish the
case. Rather, it merely emphasizes that which -- until today -- was
the broad scheme of the Social Security Act: those whose nonexempt
income was below the standard of need established by the State and
who met the other nonfinancial criteria for eligibility were to
receive benefits.
See 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(10).
[
Footnote 2/6]
To be sure,
"[t]here is no question that States have considerable latitude
in allocating their AFDC resources, since each State is free to set
its own standard of need and to determine the level of benefits by
the amount of funds it devotes to the program."
King v. Smith, 392 U. S. 309,
392 U. S.
318-319 (footnotes omitted). Accommodation of a State's
limited financial resources, however, is to be made in setting the
level of benefits, and not by gerrymandering the standard of need.
Rosado v. Wyman, supra, at
397 U. S. 413.
Here, the "reduced standard of need" which the majority recognizes
to be the consequence of the Texas computation procedures,
ante at
406 U. S. 543
n. 10, violates § 402(a)(23) of the Social Security Act, 42
U.S.C. § 602(a)(23), and our decision in
Rosado.
Section 402(a)(23) mandated an upward revision of the standard of
need, and the "reduced standard of need" Texas applies to certain
of its needy violates this requirement.
[
Footnote 2/7]
45 CFR § 233.10(a)(1)(ii) provides:
"The groups selected for inclusion in the plan and the
eligibility conditions imposed must not exclude individuals or
groups on an arbitrary or unreasonable basis, and must not result
in inequitable treatment of individuals or groups in the light of
the provisions and purposes of the public assistance titles of the
Social Security Act."
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL, with whom MR. JUSTICE BRENNAN joins, and
with whom MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins as to Part I only,
dissenting.
Appellants, recipients of Aid to Families With Dependent
Children (AFDC) in Texas, brought this action to challenge two
distinct aspects of the Texas AFDC program. First, appellants
challenge the manner in which
Page 406 U. S. 559
Texas arrives at the amount it will pay to persons who are
needy. Second, they urge that Texas acts illegally in providing
more money for persons receiving aid under other social welfare
legislation than for persons receiving AFDC aid. The Court rejects
both claims. I dissent.
Before proceeding to explain why I disagree with the Court, I
would like to illustrate what the disputes in this case are all
about. If a State is unable or unwilling to establish a level of
AFDC payments to meet all the needs of all recipients, federal law
permits the State to use a percentage reduction factor as a method
of reducing payments in a somewhat equitable manner. Texas has
adopted a system in which the percentage reduction factor is
applied against the standard of need before outside income is
deducted. Appellants contend that federal law requires the State to
deduct outside income before the percentage reduction factor is
applied. While describing the differences between the two
alternatives is a Herculean task, the figures themselves are not
difficult to comprehend. Footnote 6 of the Court's opinion, for
example, demonstrates that the Texas system provides less aid to a
family with outside income than the alternative system. It is also
immediately obvious that, under the Texas system, as soon as the
family's income reaches $150, it no longer receives anything from
the State, whereas, under the alternative, a family earning the
same $150 would continue to receive some state funds. Hence, the
Texas method of computation contracts the class of families
eligible to receive state aid. Appellants contend that the
characteristics of the Texas system are inconsistent with federal
legislation, and that only the alternative system comports with the
intent of Congress. I agree.
Appellants also claim that the percentage reduction factor
employed by Texas is illegal, irrespective of the
Page 406 U. S. 560
method of computing payments, because it is lower than the
factor used in other social welfare programs that have participants
with identical standards of need. I also agree with appellants on
this point, but for slightly different reasons from those they have
urged.
I
A. In considering the question whether Texas' method of
computing eligibility for AFDC payments comports with the federal
statute, 42 U.S.C. § 601
et seq., it is important to
keep in mind the words of Mr. Justice Cardozo: "When [federal]
money is spent to promote the general welfare, the concept of
welfare or the opposite is shaped by Congress, not the states."
Helvering v. Davis, 301 U. S. 619,
301 U. S. 645
(1937). Mr. Justice Harlan reiterated this point in
Rosado v.
Wyman, 397 U. S. 397,
397 U. S.
422-423 (1970), when he stated that, irrespective of the
policies that a State might wish to pursue by utilizing AFDC money
in one way or another, the ultimate question to be answered in each
case is whether the action of the State comports with the
requirements of federal law.
The Court concludes in the instant case that there is no general
congressional policy violated by Texas' choice between the
alternative methods of applying a percentage reduction factor to
its determined standard of need, and also that no specific
statutory provision prohibits Texas from choosing one alternative
rather than the other. In concluding that the legislative history
is inconclusive and that "what little legislative history there is
on the point . . . tends to undercut appellants' theory," the Court
has, in my opinion, taken only a superficial look into the history
of the statute, and has ignored the intent of Congress in various
sections of
Page 406 U. S. 561
the AFDC legislation as interpreted by this Court in prior
cases.
B. I begin by considering the impact of § 402(a)(23) of the
Social Security Act of 1935, as amended, 81 Stat. 898, 42 U.S.C.
§ 602(a)(23), on appellants' argument. That section provides
that
"(a) A State plan for aid and services to needy families with
children must"
"
* * * *"
"(23) provide that, by July 1, 1969, the amounts used by the
State to determine the needs of individuals will have been adjusted
to reflect fully changes in living costs since such amounts were
established, and any maximums that the State imposes on the amount
of aid paid to families will have been proportionately
adjusted."
Consideration of this section must, of course, begin with
Rosado v. Wyman, supra, where we examined the derivation
of this section in great detail.
The relevant facts in
Rosado are concisely stated in
397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 416.
New York State had changed its AFDC program so that it no longer
determined need on an individualized basis, but instead substituted
a system fixing maximum family allowances based on the number of
individuals per family. The result was a drastic reduction in
overall payments. New York State welfare recipients brought the
suit in
Rosado, claiming that, by changing its AFDC system
from an individualized grant program to a maximum grant program,
New York had violated § 402(a)(23).
Despite our recognition that "[t]he background of §
402(a)(23) reveals little except that we have before us a child
born of the silent union of legislative compromise," 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 412,
we determined to discover
Page 406 U. S. 562
what Congress had in mind in adding the section to the
preexisting AFDC legislation. We concluded that two general
purposes could be ascribed to the section:
"First, to require States to face up realistically to the
magnitude of the public assistance requirement and lay bare the
extent to which their programs fall short of fulfilling actual
need; second, to prod the States to apportion their payments on a
more equitable basis."
397 U.S. at
397 U. S.
412-413. These conclusions led us to reject the holding
of the District Court, 304 F. Supp. 1354, 1377, that Congress
intended to prevent any reduction whatever in AFDC payments, and to
reject the argument of the welfare recipients that, if payments
could be reduced, § 402(a)(23) would be meaningless. We
decided that
"a State may, after recomputing its standard of need, pare down
payments to accommodate budgetary realities by reducing the percent
of benefits paid or switching to a percent reduction system, but it
may not obscure the
actual standard of need."
397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 413
(emphasis in original). Far from emasculating the statute, our
reading recognized that the statute had at least three specific
salutary effects, and that these were the effects that Congress
intended in enacting the legislation:
"It has the effect of requiring the States to recognize and
accept the responsibility for those additional individuals whose
income falls short of the standard of need as computed in light of
economic realities and to place them among those eligible for the
care and training provisions. Secondly, while it leaves the States
free to effect downward adjustments in the level of benefits paid,
it accomplishes within that framework the goal, however modest, of
forcing a State to accept the political
Page 406 U. S. 563
consequence of such a cutback and bringing to light the true
extent to which actual assistance falls short of the minimum
acceptable. Lastly, by imposing on those States that desire to
maintain 'maximums' the requirement of an appropriate adjustment,
Congress has introduced an incentive to abandon a flat 'maximum'
system, thereby encouraging those States desirous of containing
their welfare budget to shift to a percentage system that will more
equitably apportion those funds in fact, allocated for welfare and
also more accurately reflect the real measure of public assistance
being given."
Id. at
397 U. S.
413-414.
Thus, it is clear that we based our decision in
Rosado,
a decision that interpreted § 402(a)(23) to permit a decrease
in actual AFDC payments, largely on the conclusion that Congress
wanted not to bar decreases, but to accomplish other objectives.
The fact is that the Court today undermines each of those
objectives and destroys the premise on which
Rosado was
decided.
One specific congressional goal we saw in § 402(a)(23) was
that
"[r]ecalculation of need may serve to render eligible for
benefits families which may appear under unadjusted standards
marginally to have attained self-sufficiency, but which, in fact,
are unable to subsist at the present cost of living."
Memorandum for the United States as
Amicus Curiae in
Rosado v. Wyman, No. 540, O.T. 1969, p. 8. In other words,
we read the section as expressing Congress' willingness to permit
reductions in actual payments in return for the addition of more
families to the rolls of AFDC recipients.
Accord, Lampton v.
Bonin, 304 F.
Supp. 1384 (ED La.1969),
vacated and remanded for
reconsideration in light of Rosado, 397 U.
S. 663 (1970);
Alvarado v.
Schmidt, 317 F.
Supp. 1027 (TD Wis.1970). As I have pointed out above, the
Texas
Page 406 U. S. 564
system limits the number of AFDC recipients and eliminates
marginal cases. This is directly contrary to the intent of Congress
as we saw it in
Rosado.
A second legislative aim that we saw in the section was to force
States to realize the political consequences of reducing welfare
payments. It must be clear that the Texas system of administering
AFDC payments effectively undermines this aim by enabling the State
to maintain a constant percentage reduction factor so that the
system on its face appears to contain no reductions in payments.
Welfare reductions are surreptitiously accomplished by eliminating
those persons who have marginal income from eligibility for AFDC
payments. While the congressional intent may not be totally
emasculated by this system, it is certainly not well served.
The third and final purpose that we found that Congress had
specifically in mind in enacting § 402(a)(23) was to provide
an incentive to States to abandon a flat "maximum" system. Even
though Texas does not now use such a system, the Court's approval
of the system that Texas does use will effectively remove the
incentive from the statute. A State that uses a flat maximum system
was required by § 402(a)(23) to adjust the maximums upward to
reflect a rise in the cost of living. Since a State that uses a
percentage reduction system may avoid the strains cost of living
adjustments place on the budget simply by lowering the percentage
that it chooses to pay, the statute encouraged abandonment of flat
maximums in favor of the more equitable percentage reductions. The
Court undermines the incentive by offering States a way to
circumvent the cost of living adjustments under the flat maximum
system. In order to maintain the maximums without increasing
expenditures, States could, under the Court's opinion, begin to use
the maximum to determine AFDC eligibility,
Page 406 U. S. 565
rather than the standard of need. The result of this approach
would be to reduce the number of persons eligible for assistance
and to reduce the grants of anyone with any outside income. Rather
than serve as an incentive to States to change to a percentage
reduction system, as Congress intended, § 402(a)(23) may now
be a powerful incentive to States to maintain or revert to maximum
grants.
The manner in which the incentive that
Rosado saw in
§ 402(a)(23) is stifled can be illustrated by another look at
the family having an income of $100 and a need of $200.
Footnote 6 of the Court's opinion
demonstrates that under the Texas percentage reduction system,
even if the family had no income, the maximum amount of aid that
the family could obtain would be $150. Let us assume that Texas
maintained a maximum grant system, and that, prior to the enactment
of § 402(a)(23), the maximum grant for a family with $200 need
was $100. We assumed in
Rosado that the following
computation would be made.
Need . . . . . . . . . . . $200
Income . . . . . . . . . . $100
----
Unmet Need . . . . . . . . $100
Maximum Grant. . . . . . . $100
----
Total Family Funds . . . . $200
Section 402(a)(23) required an increase in the standard of need
and the level of maximum grants to reflect the rise in the cost of
living. Assuming that a 20% increase was mandated by the rise in
living costs, it is obvious that, if the number of families
remained stable and if income were stable, the costs of AFDC to the
State would increase by 20%. There was an incentive to change to a
percentage reduction system to avoid this.
Page 406 U. S. 566
Until recently, no one thought that the State could change to
the following system in order to reflect the rise in the cost of
living:
New Need . . . . . . . . . $240
----
New Maximum Grant. . . . . $120
Family Income. . . . . . . $100
----
State Aid. . . . . . . . . $ 20
To state it more simply, the maximum grant is similar to, and
designed to serve the same purposes as, the percentage reduction
factor. If the percentage reduction factor can be applied to need
before income is subtracted, it is impossible to see why income
could not be set off against maximum grants. True, Texas did not
choose this alternative, but it is available under today's
decision. A State can, by changing the manner in which it sets off
income, absorb an increase in maximums and end up paying less.
Where is the incentive now to adopt percentage reduction
systems?
This illustration is much more than mere speculation as to what
might happen under today's decision. The illustration represents
what at least one State -- California -- has already done, or tried
to do. Only very recently, the California Supreme Court struck down
the State's AFDC scheme for noncompliance with the federal statute.
Villa v. Hall, 6 Cal. 3d 227,
490 P.2d 1148 (1971).
The California Supreme Court, having been referred to the
District Court opinion in the instant case as support for
California's system, took the position that neither the California
nor the Texas system could stand in light of
Rosado. I
agree. Indeed, the United States in its Memorandum as
Amicus
Curiae in this case (p. 5) concedes that, if
Rosado
represents "a binding
Page 406 U. S. 567
construction of the Act, appellants are thus entitled to
prevail." The Government proceeds to argue that the question
presented here was not before us in
Rosado. Ibid.
I must agree with appellants that the Government's argument is
disingenuous, at best.
See Brief for Appellants 80. The
question of what § 402(a)(23) means was most certainly before
us in
Rosado. It was, in fact, all that was before us. In
that case, we rejected the broad construction that the District
Court had given the section, but we endeavored as best we could to
extract some meaning from its muddled history. The United States
seeks here to have us do what we explicitly said we would not do in
Rosado, i.e., interpret the section in such a way that it
is nothing more than a "meaningless exercise in
bookkeeping.'"
397 U.S. at 397 U. S. 413.
If we were not making a "binding construction" of the statute in
Rosado, it is impossible for me to ascertain what we were
doing. Hence, I agree with the Government that appellants are
entitled to prevail.
Surprisingly enough, the Court makes even shorter shrift of
Rosado than does the Government. In a footnote, the Court
states that widened eligibility and the other effects that
Rosado said were intended by Congress when it enacted
§ 402(a)(23) were merely possible effects of the statute, not
necessary ones. I submit that this cavalier treatment of
Rosado is completely unwarranted.
Rosado was not
an easy case. The absence of a clear legislative history forced us
to examine the "muted strains" of the congressional voice and to
struggle to "discern the theme in the cacophony of political
understanding." 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 412.
Unlike the Court in this case, which simply looks to see if the
legislative history is distorted enough to be ignored, the Court in
Rosado carefully scrutinized every aspect of the history
in order to perceive the congressional intent. That was a difficult
task, but not an impossible one. The balance
Page 406 U. S. 568
that we saw Congress striking in reducing payments while
increasing eligibility has already been described. We relied on
this balance to decide
Rosado. We were not merely
speculating as to the intent of Congress; we were holding that
there was a specific intent that was binding in that case. That
decision, in my view, is also binding here. This is my first
disagreement with the majority.
C. The second provision in the AFDC legislation that I believe
is relevant is § 402(a)(8) of the Social Security Act, as
amended, 81 Stat. 881, 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(8), which was added
to the AFDC statute along with § 402(a)(23) in 1968. The
purpose of this section is to encourage AFDC recipients to seek
private employment and to end their need for public assistance.
H.R.Rep. No. 544, 90th Cong., 1st Sess. (1967); S.Rep. No. 744,
90th Cong., 1st Sess. (1967). To accomplish this objective, the
statute provides that all of the earned income of each dependent
child receiving AFDC aid who is a full or part-time student, and a
portion of the earned income of certain other relatives, will be
disregarded in the State's determination of need. We only recently
had occasion to consider the effect of this provision in
Engelman v. Amos, 404 U. S. 23
(1971).
In
Engelman, we considered a New Jersey scheme for
administering AFDC funds that established income ceilings for
families. When the families' incomes exceeded the ceilings, they no
longer were eligible for AFDC aid. The District Court analogized
Engelman to
Rosado v. Wyman, supra, and
determined that the State's system was inconsistent with the
federal Act.
333
F. Supp. 1109. The District Court recognized that the 1968
amendments to the AFDC legislation were designed to increase
eligibility for AFDC aid, not to decrease it. Because the District
Court viewed § 402(a)(8) as requiring a State to disregard
certain kinds of
Page 406 U. S. 569
income in determining eligibility for aid, the District Court
struck down the New Jersey scheme, in effect holding that New
Jersey could not evade the income disregard by imposing an income
ceiling not contemplated by Congress. Families that exceeded the
State's income ceilings were still entitled to AFDC aid so long as
their income, excluding income covered by § 402(a)(8), did not
exceed the State's standard of need. The effect of the decision was
to increase the class of persons eligible for AFDC aid. We affirmed
the decision without even hearing argument.
Both "the New Jersey and the Texas provisions . . . appear to
have been animated by the same desire. . . ." Memorandum for the
United States as
Amicus Curiae 11. Both seek to limit the
number of AFDC recipients, and both violate the federal statute.
Indeed, the very purpose of § 402(a)(8) -- to encourage people
to work by permitting them to continue to draw AFDC funds -- shows
that Congress wanted as many needy people as possible to be part of
the program.
The Texas scheme certainly does not violate § 402(a)(8) in
the way that the New Jersey scheme did, for as far as we know,
Texas excludes income as required by the statute when computing
eligibility. But, as the opinion of the Court indicates, the Texas
system has a fault not found in New Jersey:
i.e., Texas
discourages recipients from earning outside income. This is why I
believe that Texas violates the spirit of the federal statute.
It might be argued that Congress only sought to encourage
certain AFDC recipients to earn income and only in a certain amount
-- the persons and amounts specified in § 402(a)(8). This
argument might be persuasive but for one fact -- Congress never had
any idea that a State would attempt to employ a system such as that
used by Texas. Nowhere in the legislative history
Page 406 U. S. 570
is there any mention of such a system.
See, e.g., House
Committee on Ways and Means, Section-By-Section Analysis of H.R.
5710, 90th Cong., 1st Sess. (Comm.Print 1967). Congress was, in
fact, informed by HEW that a different standard from that used by
Texas was required.
See Hearings on H.R. 12080 before the
Senate Committee on Finance, 90th Cong., 1st Sess., pt. 1, pp.
255-266 (testimony of Wilbur Cohen). Until very recently, every
indication by HEW was that the Texas system would be unlawful. In
light of the state of ignorance in which Congress found itself, it
is not surprising that there is no specific rejection of the Texas
system in the 1968 amendments. But § 402(a)(8) and everything
in the legislative history certainly indicate that Congress had a
strong desire to encourage AFDC recipients to work. Because the
Texas program is inconsistent with this desire, I believe it is
illegal.
This is the second reason for my disagreement with the
Court.
D. Another section of the statute that must be examined is
§ 402(a)(10) of the Social Security Act, 64 Stat. 550, as
amended, 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(10), which requires that a state
AFDC plan shall
"provide . . . that all individuals wishing to make application
for aid to families with dependent children shall have opportunity
to do so, and that aid to families with dependent children shall be
furnished with reasonable promptness to all eligible
individuals."
The Court states that the primary purpose of this section was to
outlaw the use of waiting lists as a means of minimizing a State's
welfare expenditures. There is clearly support for this view, as
the Court noted in
Dandridge v. Williams, 397 U.
S. 471,
397 U. S. 481
n. 12 (1970).
Page 406 U. S. 571
Before the Court in
Dandridge was the question whether
maximum grant limitations were inconsistent with the federal
statute. The Court upheld the maximums, but said in the course of
so doing: "So long as some aid is provided to all eligible families
and all eligible children, the statute itself is not violated."
Id. at
397 U. S. 481.
This is plainly dictum, but I believe that it is well considered
dictum that should be followed in this case.
It must be remembered that
Dandridge and
Rosado were decided on the same day. Thus, the Court
assumed in
Dandridge that the 1968 amendments to the AFDC
legislation expanded the list of eligible recipients in the manner
suggested in
Rosado. The Court was also aware in
Dandridge that § 402(a)(7) of the Social Security
Act, as amended, 53 Stat. 1379, 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(7), had
been part of the AFDC statute since 1939. That section provides
that,
"except as may be otherwise provided [in § 402(a)(8),
discussed,
supra] . . . the State agency shall, in
determining need, take into consideration any other income and
resources of any child or relative claiming aid to families with
dependent children. . . ."
The Court assumed, therefore, that, in offering aid, a State
would first set a standard of need and then examine the income
levels of applicants for aid. Anyone whose income was less than the
standard of need would be eligible for assistance, or so the Court
assumed.
Dandridge, of course, established that the aid
that might be forthcoming did not have to equal need, and that
large families could get proportionately less aid than small
families. Just as in
Rosado, the Court in
Dandridge viewed the intent of Congress to be to aid as
many needy people as possible, rather than to offer as much aid as
possible to a lesser number of people. In light of this, I
believe
Page 406 U. S. 572
that today's decision violates the spirit of
Dandridge
as well as the holding of
Rosado.
Moreover, in my view, § 402(a)(7) tells the States how to
compute eligibility, and that section does not allow for the Texas
scheme. Despite the position of the Government in this case, I find
support for my reading of § 402(a)(7) in HEW's own
regulations, especially 45 CFR §§ 233.20(a)(2),
233.20(a)(3)(ii), which indicate to me that income is to be
subtracted from the standard of need before any determination is
made as to how much aid the State will give.
Because I believe the Texas system violates § 402(a)(7), it
seems to me that eligible persons are being denied aid in violation
of § 402(a)(10), which requires that aid be furnished to all
eligible persons promptly. For me, this case is no different from
King v. Smith, 392 U. S. 309
(1968) (striking down substitute father regulation) or
Townsend
v. Swank, 404 U. S. 282
(1971) (striking down restriction on receipt of aid by college
students). The state procedure denies eligible persons aid, and,
regardless of the State's purposes, the procedure cannot stand in
conflict with the federal statute.
I disagree with the Court a third time.
E. The last portion of the federal statute that I believe should
be considered is that portion dealing with the social services that
are available to AFDC recipients.
See, e.g., 42 U.S.C.
§§ 602(a)(14), (15) (assistance in family planning and
child welfare services; assistance in entering the workforce and
reducing the incidence of births out of wedlock); 42 U.S.C.
§§ 602(a)(19), 632 (employment training programs); 42
U.S.C. § 1396a(a)(10) (medical assistance). Congress keyed all
of these provisions to persons or families that were receiving aid.
By limiting the number of such persons and families receiving aid,
Texas has also limited the availability of
Page 406 U. S. 573
these social services. At least one other court has concluded
that
". . . Congress' major concern was the provision of family
counseling and rehabilitation services, work incentives, and family
planning programs to reduce out-of-wedlock births, for all persons
in the family, in order to promote self-support and child
development and to strengthen family life. . . . By making those
with marginal incomes eligible for AFDC by raising the standard of
need, more persons would be eligible for such services, which
Congress considered vital to cut down in the long run the numbers
dependent on welfare."
(Citation omitted.)
Lampton v. Bonin, 304 F. Supp. at
1389. We suggested the same thing in
Rosado, 397 U.S. at
397 U. S. 413.
While the Court recognizes that the Texas system deprives persons
with an "unmet need" of an opportunity to utilize these services
(n. 10), and thus relegates these persons to perpetual dependence
on welfare, the realization is apparently a source of no concern.
But it was a source of tremendous concern to Congress. The value of
medical assistance alone to an average Texas AFDC family is in the
range of $50-$60 per month. Memorandum for the United States as
Amicus Curiae 7 n. 5. Since needy families are rendered
more needy by Texas' system, their ability to escape the confines
of the welfare rolls is substantially impaired. At the same time,
the goals of Congress as described in the preceding quotation are
also impaired. There is no reason, nor any justification, for
reading the statute this way. Since I believe that Congress
intended that as many needy persons as possible be permitted to
avail themselves of the various services provided or improved in
the 1968 amendments, I again disagree with the conclusions of the
Court.
Page 406 U. S. 574
F. In concluding my analysis of this aspect of Texas' percentage
reduction system, I add one final note. Thus far, I have confined
myself to examining the specific provisions of the AFDC
legislation. In attempting to focus on each section individually in
order to determine its role in the statutory scheme, something of
the general flavor of the overall legislation is undoubtedly lost.
That flavor, it seems to me, is to assist needy families to
maintain strong family bonds and to assist needy individuals to
realize their potential as unique human beings by providing them
with the basic necessities of life, along with incentives and
training to encourage them to work to help themselves. The Texas
system negates the salutary aspects of the legislation by deterring
the needy from working, by depriving the needy of social services,
and by excluding some needy from any AFDC aid whatsoever. There is
no conceivable reason to permit Texas to subvert the aims of
Congress in this way.
II
Appellants also challenge the percentage reduction figure
itself. It is agreed that Texas has established an identical
standard of need for the four social welfare programs that it
administers -- Old Age Assistance (OAA), Aid to the Blind (AB), Aid
for the Permanently and Totally Disabled (APTD), and AFDC. But
Texas provides 100% of recognized need to the aged and 95% to the
disabled and the blind, while it provides only 75% to AFDC
recipients. It is this disparity to which appellants also
object.
A. Appellants base their primary attack on the Fourteenth
Amendment; they argue that the percentage distinctions between the
other welfare programs and AFDC reflect a racially discriminatory
motive on the part of Texas officials. Thus, they argue that there
is a violation of the Equal Protection Clause. I believe that
it
Page 406 U. S. 575
is unnecessary to reach the constitutional issue that appellants
raise, and, therefore, I offer no opinion on its ultimate merits. I
do wish to make it clear, however, that I do not subscribe in any
way to the manner in which the Court treats the issue.
If I were to face this question, I would certainly have more
difficulty with it than either the District Court had or than this
Court seems to have. The record contains numerous statements by
state officials to the effect that AFDC is funded at a lower level
than the other programs because it is not a politically popular
program. There is also evidence of a stigma that seemingly attaches
to AFDC recipients and no others. This Court noted in
King v.
Smith, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S. 322,
that AFDC recipients were often frowned upon by the community. The
evidence also shows that 87% of the AFDC recipients in Texas are
either Negro or Mexican-American. Yet both the District Court and
this Court have little difficulty in concluding that the fact that
AFDC is politically unpopular and the fact that AFDC recipients are
disfavored by the State and its citizens have nothing whatsoever to
do with the racial makeup of the program. This conclusion is
neither so apparent nor so correct, in my view.
Moreover, because I find that each one of the State's reasons
for treating AFDC differently from the other programs dissolves
under close scrutiny, as is demonstrated
infra, I am not
at all certain who should bear the burden of proof on the question
of racial discrimination. Nor am I sure that the "traditional"
standard of review would govern the case as the Court holds. In
Dandridge v. Williams, supra, on which the Court relies
for the proposition that strict scrutiny of the State's action is
not required, the Court never faced a question of possible racial
discrimination. Percentages themselves are certainly not
conclusive, but, at some point, a showing that
Page 406 U. S. 576
state action has a devastating impact on the lives of minority
racial groups must be relevant.
The Court reasons backwards to conclude that, because appellants
have not proved racial discrimination, a less strict standard of
review is necessarily tolerated. In my view, the first question
that must be asked is what is the standard of review, and the
second question is whether racial discrimination has been proved
under the standard. It seems almost too plain for argument that the
standard of review determines, in large measure, whether or not
something has been proved.
Whitcomb v. Chavis,
403 U. S. 124,
403 U. S. 149
(1971);
Gomillion v. Lightfoot, 364 U.
S. 339, (1960).
These are all complex problems, and I do not propose to resolve
any of them here. It is sufficient for me to note that I believe
that the constitutional issue raised by appellants need not be
reached, and that, in choosing to reach it, the Court has so
greatly oversimplified the issue as to distort it.
B. Appellants also challenge the distinction between programs
under Title VI of the 1964 Civil Rights Act, 42 U.S.C. §
2000d:
"No person in the United States hall, on the ground of race,
color, or national origin, . . . be subjected to discrimination
under any program or activity receiving Federal financial
assistance."
Only last Term, in
Griggs v. Duke Power Co.,
401 U. S. 424
(1971), we had occasion to strike down under Title VII of the 1964
Act, 42 U.S.C. § 2000e, employment practices that had a
particularly harsh impact on one minority racial group and that
could not be justified by business necessity. We indicated in that
case that
"good intent or absence of discriminatory intent does not redeem
employment procedures or testing mechanisms that operate as
'built-in headwinds' for minority groups. "
Page 406 U. S. 577
Id. at
401 U. S. 432.
We said, in fact, that "Congress directed the thrust of the Act to
the
consequences of employment practices, not simply the
motivation."
Ibid. (emphasis in original). That decision
even placed the burden on the employer "of showing that any given
requirement must have a manifest relationship to the employment in
question."
Ibid.
There has been a paucity of litigation under Title VI, and I am
not prepared at this point to say whether or not a similar analysis
to that used in
Griggs should be used in Title VI cases.
This is a question of first impression in this Court, and I do not
think we have to reach it in this case. I include this section only
to make plain that I do not necessarily reject the argument made by
appellants; I simply do not reach it.
C. This brings me to what I believe disposes of the question
presented: the disparity between the various social welfare
programs is not permissible under the federal statutory
framework.
The four social welfare programs offered by Texas are funded in
part by the Federal Government. Each program is governed by a
separate statute: OAA, 42 U.S.C. § 301
et seq.; AFDC,
42 U.S.C. § 601
et seq.; AB, 42 U.S.C. § 1201
et seq.; APTD, 42 U.S.C. § 1351
et seq. No
State is compelled to participate in any program, and any State
that wants to participate can choose to do so in one, several, or
all of the programs.
There is no doubt that States are free to choose whether or not
to participate in these programs, and it is also clear that each
State has considerable freedom to allocate what it wants to one or
more programs by establishing different standards of need to
compute eligibility for aid.
Kin v. Smith, 392 U.S. at
392 U. S.
318-319. It is also true, however, that the basic aims
of the four programs are identical. Indeed, when Congress first
enacted the programs in 1935, it viewed them all as necessary
to
Page 406 U. S. 578
provide aid to families unable to obtain income from private
employment. The beneficiaries of the various programs shared the
basic characteristics of need and dependence. H.R.Rep. No. 615,
74th Cong., 1st Sess., 3. While the programs as they now exist go
well beyond merely furnishing financial assistance as they did
originally, they still maintain similar goals.
Moreover, all four programs were simultaneously amended in 1956
to provide for social and rehabilitative services to enable all
needy individuals to attain the maximum economic and personal
independence of which they were capable. Each program now requires
a State to describe, in its plan for each social welfare program it
administers, the services it offers to accomplish this objective.
See 42 U.S.C. §§ 302(a)(11); 602(a)(14);
1202(a)(12); 1352(a)(11).
Congress has given the States authority to set different
standards of need for different programs. But where, as here, the
State concludes that the standard of need is the same for
recipients of aid under the four distinct statutes, it is my
opinion that Congress required that the State treat all recipients
equally with respect to actual aid. In other words, as I read the
federal statutes, they are designed to accomplish the same
objectives, albeit for persons disadvantaged by different
circumstances.
States clearly have the freedom to make a
bona fide
determination that blind persons have a greater need than dependent
children, that adults have a higher standard of need than children,
that the aged have more need than the blind, and so forth.
But, in this case, Texas made an independent determination of
need, and it determined that the need of all recipients was equal.
In this circumstance, I find nothing in the federal statute to
enable a State to favor one group of recipients by satisfying more
of its need,
Page 406 U. S. 579
while at the same time denying an equally great need of another
group. The purposes and objectives of the statutes are the same,
those eligible for aid are suffering equally, and Congress intended
that, once a State chose to participate in the programs, similarly
situated persons would be treated similarly.
Everything in this record indicates that the recipients of the
various forms of aid are identically situated. Although the
District Court accepted the State's contentions that there are
differences between AFDC children and other recipients which
warranted different treatment under the federal statutes, I find
each of the reasons offered totally unpersuasive.
First, Texas argues that AFDC children can be employed, whereas
recipients of other benefits cannot be. Assuming
arguendo
that this is true, it is an argument that falls of its own weight.
Whatever income the children earn is subtracted from need, or it is
excluded from consideration under § 402(a)(8) to encourage
self-help. Thus, income is already reflected in the computation of
payments, or it is excluded in order that a specific legislative
goal may be furthered. Thus, income is irrelevant in any
explanation of the differences between the percentage reductions
applied to the various programs. It should also be noted that a
recipient's income is also taken into consideration in programs
other than AFDC.
See 42 U.S.C. §§ 302(a)(10)(A);
1202(a)(8); 1352(a)(8).
Second, the State maintains that AFDC families can secure help
from legally responsible relatives more easily than recipients
under other programs. Assuming again, for purposes of discussion,
that this is true, it should be plain that any support from any
relatives is subtracted from the State's grant. Moreover,
appellants properly point out that recipients of aid in non-AFDC
programs
Page 406 U. S. 580
often have a source of aid unavailable to AFDC recipients -- the
federal old age insurance, 42 U.S.C. § 201
et seq.
Thus, there is no substance to this argument.
Third, Texas points to the likelihood of future employment for
AFDC recipients, a likelihood that it says is nonexistent for older
persons and others who receive aid. Federal law provides that a
State may only consider income that is currently available in
allocating funds. 45 CFR § 233.20(a)(3)(ii). This contention
is therefore irrelevant.
The State makes only two other arguments. One has already been
rejected. Texas urges that the purposes of the federal programs
differ, but the history belies this contention. The other is that
the numbers of AFDC recipients is rising, and this program should
therefore bear the burden of monetary limitations. The obvious
problem with this argument is that one fundamental purpose of AFDC
aid is to enable people to escape the welfare rolls. But, under the
Texas system, the aid is presently insufficient, people are unable
to escape from dependency, and the rolls become larger. Had Texas
not funded AFDC at a lower level than other programs, it is
possible that the number of recipients would not have grown so
large. The State's argument is a self-fulfilling prophecy on which
it cannot rely to penalize AFDC recipients. Furthermore, there is
nothing in the federal legislation to indicate that aid is to be
reduced in a program merely because the number of beneficiaries of
that program increases at a more rapid rate than in other programs.
On the contrary, Congress has indicated that increased eligibility
for AFDC is desirable,
see 42 U.S.C. § 602(a)(23);
Rosado v. Wyman, supra. It would be extreme irony if AFDC
recipients were penalized by a State because their numbers grew in
accordance with congressional intent.
Page 406 U. S. 581
The conclusion that I draw from the statutes is that Congress
intended equal treatment for all persons similarly situated.
Congress left to the States the determination of who was similarly
situated by permitting States to determine levels of need. Since
Texas has decided that AFDC recipients have precisely the same need
as recipients of other social welfare benefits, it is my opinion
that the federal legislation requires equal treatment for all.
This conclusion finds support in the legislative history of the
1950 amendments to the social welfare legislation. In those
amendments, Congress made clear its intent to put AFDC recipients
on a par with recipients of other welfare aid.
"Today, more than 1.1 million children under 18 years of age are
receiving aid to dependent children through the State-Federal
program because one or both of their parents are dead, absent from
the home, or incapacitated. These children, regardless of the State
in which they now live, will someday find their place in the
productive activities of the Nation and, should the necessity
arise, will take part in defending our Nation. Many of these
children will be seriously handicapped as adults because, in
childhood, they are not receiving proper and sufficient food,
clothing, medical attention, and the other bare necessities of
life. The national interest requires that the Federal Government
provide for dependent children
at least on a par with its
contributions toward the support of the needy aged and blind."
S.Doc. No. 208, 80th Cong., 2d Sess., 105 (emphasis added).
Congress recognized that "families with dependent children need as
much in assistance payments as do aged and blind persons."
Id. at 106. It concluded that
Page 406 U. S. 582
sound national policy was "for the States to provide payments
for aid to dependent children comparable to those for the needy
aged and blind."
Ibid. It is evident that Congress
rejected the notion that, where AFDC recipients had the same need
as other welfare beneficiaries, they should get less money. As
Senator Benton said on the floor of the Senate:
"There seems no reasonable basis for such inequitable treatment
of mothers and of children by the Federal Government."
"All of us with children know that it costs as much, if not
more, to rear children in health, decency, and self-respect than to
maintain an adult. It is surely no less important to make this
investment in our future citizens than it is to provide decently
for those who have retired. . . ."
96 Cong.Rec. 881-8814. In the 1950 amendments, Congress
increased the federal funding of AFDC so that its beneficiaries
would receive treatment equivalent to that received by
beneficiaries of the other federal state social welfare
legislation. Where the needs of the people receiving aid under the
various programs differed, Congress recognized that the amount of
aid forthcoming should also differ. But where need was determined
by the State to be equal for all recipients, Congress intended that
all should receive an equal amount of aid. S.Doc. No. 208, 80th
Cong., 2d Sess., 108. There is absolutely no indication in any
subsequent congressional action that the intent of Congress has
changed.
Accordingly, I would reverse the judgment of the District Court
and remand the case for formulation of relief consistent with this
opinion.