The Pacific Maritime Association (PMA), representing the Pacific
Coast shipping industry employers, and the International
Longshoremen's and Warehousemen's Union reached an agreement
whereby the union consented to the use of labor-saving devices and
the elimination of certain restrictive work practices in return for
PMA's promise to create a $29,000,000 fund to mitigate the effect
of technological unemployment. The agreement reserved to PMA the
right to determine how to raise the fund from its members. PMA
approved an assessment per "revenue ton," based either on weight
(2,000 pounds) or measurement (40 cubic feet), determined by the
manner in which cargo had customarily been manifested, with the
exception of automobiles, which were to be declared by measurement.
For petitioner's automobiles, the assessment came to $2.35 per
vehicle, an increase in unloading costs of 22.5%, rather than 25
cents under an assessment by weight, or about 2.4% increase in
costs, comparable to the average fund assessment of 2.2% for all
other general cargo. Petitioner obtained a stay of the action
brought by PMA to collect the assessment from the terminal company
unloading petitioner's automobiles, to permit it to invoke the
primary jurisdiction of the Federal Maritime Commission (FMC) to
determine whether the assessments were claimed under an agreement
required to be filed with and approved by the FMC under § 15
of the Shipping Act, 1916, and whether the assessments violated
§§ 16 and 17 of that Act. The FMC dismissed petitioner's
complaint, holding that the agreement did not "affect competition,"
and did not come within § 15 in the absence of an additional
agreement by PMA to pass on all or a portion of the assessments to
the carriers and shippers served by the terminal operators; that
§ 16 was not violated, since petitioner had not shown any
unequal treatment between its cars and other automobiles or cargo
competitive therewith, and that there was no violation of §
17, since the petitioner
Page 390 U. S. 262
had received "substantial benefits" in return for the
assessment. The Court of Appeals affirmed.
Held:
1. The agreement was required to be filed with the FMC under
§ 15 of the Act. Pp.
390 U. S.
268-278.
(a) The FMC recognized that the assessment formula was a
"cooperative working agreement" clearly within the plain language
of § 15. P.
390 U. S.
271.
(b) In holding that the agreement did not "affect competition,"
the FMC ignored economic realities which required most of the
assessments to be passed on. P.
390 U. S.
273.
(c) The FMC has not previously limited § 15 to horizontal
agreements among competitors, but has applied it to other
agreements within its literal terms. P.
390 U. S.
274.
(d) The legislative history of this broad statute indicates that
Congress intended to subject to the scrutiny of a specialized
agency the myriad of restrictive maritime agreements. Pp.
390 U. S.
275-276.
(e) While the FMC may determine that some
de minimis or
routine agreements need not be filed under § 15, this
agreement, levying $29,000,000, binding the whole Pacific Coast
shipping industry, and resulting in substantially increased
stevedoring and terminal charges, was neither
de minimis
nor routine. Pp.
390 U. S.
276-277.
(f) The only agreement involved here is the one among PMA
members allocating the impact of the fund levy, and only the
assessment on automobiles is challenged. P.
390 U. S.
278.
2. When the agreement is filed, the FMC may consider anew
whether the mere absence of a competitive relationship should
foreclose inquiry under § 16. Pp.
390 U. S.
279-280.
3. The proper inquiry under § 17 is whether the charge
levied is reasonably related to the service rendered. Pp.
390 U. S.
280-282.
125 U.S.App.D.C. 282, 371 F.2d 747, reversed and remanded.
Page 390 U. S. 263
MR. JUSTICE STEWART delivered the opinion of the Court.
The petitioner, a German manufacturer of automobiles, is one of
the largest users of the ports on the West Coast of the United
States, delivering through them more than 40,000 vehicles each
year, the majority transported there by vessels chartered by the
petitioner, rather than by common carrier. This case grows out of
the petitioner's claim that charges imposed upon the unloading of
its automobiles at Pacific Coast ports are in violation of the
Shipping Act, 1916, as amended. 39 Stat. 728, 46 U.S.C. § 801
et seq. The dispute has a long and somewhat complicated
history.
The Pacific Maritime Association (the Association) is an
employer organization of some 120 principal common carriers by
water, stevedoring contractors, and marine terminal operators,
representing the Pacific Coast shipping industry. The primary
function of the Association is to negotiate and administer
collective bargaining contracts with unions representing its
members' employees, of which the International Longshoremen's and
Warehousemen's Union (ILWU) is one. In late 1960, the
Page 390 U. S. 264
Association and ILWU reached a milestone agreement which, it was
hoped, would end a long and troubled history of labor discord on
the West Coast waterfront. [
Footnote 1] The ILWU agreed to the introduction of
labor-saving devices and the elimination of certain restrictive
work practices. In return. the Association agreed to create, over
the period from 1961 to 1966, a "Mechanization and Modernization
Fund" of $29,000,000 (the Mech Fund) to be used to mitigate the
impact upon employees of technological unemployment. [
Footnote 2] The agreement specifically
reserved to the Association alone the right to determine how to
raise the Mech Fund from its members, at the rate of some
$5,000,000 a year.
A committee of the Association investigated various possible
formulas for collecting the Fund from the stevedoring contractors
and terminal operators --
i.e., those Association members
who were employers of workers represented by the ILWU. A majority
of the committee recommended that the Mech Fund assessment be based
solely on tonnage handled, and this recommendation was adopted by
the Association membership. [
Footnote 3] Under this
Page 390 U. S. 265
formula, general cargo was assessed at 27 1/2� per
"revenue ton." [
Footnote 4] A
revenue ton is based either on weight (2,000 lbs. = one ton) or
measurement (40 cu. ft. = one ton). Whether tonnage declarations on
a particular item of cargo were to be by weight or by measurement
was to depend, with one exception, upon how that cargo had
customarily been manifested (and reported to the Association for
dues purposes) in 1959. The one exception was automobiles, for
which there had been no uniform manifesting custom. [
Footnote 5] The Association decided that
automobiles were to be declared by measurement for Mech Fund
purposes, regardless of how they were or had been manifested.
Unlike shippers by common carrier, the petitioner must arrange
and pay for the unloading of its own chartered vessels upon their
arrival in port. For this purpose, it has, since 1954, contracted
with Marine Terminals Corporation and Marine Terminals Corporation
of Los Angeles (Terminals), which are members of the Association,
for the performance of stevedoring and related services in
unloading vehicles from the petitioner's chartered ships in West
Coast ports, at a negotiated price. Prior to the Mech Fund
assessment agreement, Terminals' charge to the petitioner for these
unloading services was $10.45 per vehicle, of which about a dollar
represented Terminals' profit. When the vehicles were assessed for
the Mech Fund by measurement, the assessment came to $2.35 per
vehicle -- representing, if passed on to the petitioner,
Page 390 U. S. 266
an increase in unloading costs of 22.5%. [
Footnote 6] If the vehicles had been assessed by
weight (0.9 tons), rather than by measurement (8.7 tons), [
Footnote 7] the assessment would have
been 25� per vehicle -- an increase of about 2.4%,
comparable to the average Mech Fund assessment of 2.2% for all
other general cargo. Assessment by measurement, rather than by
weight, thus resulted in an assessment rate for the petitioner's
automobiles of 10 times that for other West Coast cargo -- although
automobiles had less to gain than other cargo from the Mech Fund
agreement. [
Footnote 8] The
petitioner and Terminals both protested these seeming inequities to
a committee of the Association set up to handle such claims, but
without success. [
Footnote
9]
The petitioner refused to pay any additional charge resulting
from the Association's levy, and Terminals, while continuing to
unload Volkswagen automobiles for the petitioner, did not pay its
resulting assessment to the Association. The Association sued
Terminals in a federal court in California for its failure to pay
the Mech Fund assessments; Terminals admitted all the allegations
of
Page 390 U. S. 267
the complaint and impleaded the petitioner as a defendant. The
petitioner then obtained a stay of that action to permit it to
invoke the primary jurisdiction of the Federal Maritime Commission,
in order to determine the following issues:
"1. Whether the assessments claimed from [the petitioner] are
being claimed pursuant to an agreement or understanding which is
required to be filed with and approved by the Federal Maritime
Commission under Section 15 of the Shipping Act, 1916, as amended,
46 U.S.C. 814 (1961), before it is lawful to take any action
thereunder, which agreement has not been so filed and
approved."
"2. Whether the assessments claimed from [the petitioner] result
in subjecting the automobile cargoes of [the petitioner] to undue
or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in violation of Section
16 of the Shipping Act, 1916, as amended, 46 U.S.C. 815
(1961)."
"3. Whether the assessments claimed from [the petitioner]
constitute an unjust and unreasonable practice in violation of
Section 17 of the Shipping Act, 1916, as amended, 46 U.S.C. 816
(1961)."
The petitioner then began the present proceedings by filing a
complaint with the Commission raising the above issues. The
petitioner alleged that the Association was dominated by common
carriers, [
Footnote 10]
which had agreed upon the assessment formula in order to shift a
disproportionate share of the Mech Fund assessment onto the
petitioner,
Page 390 U. S. 268
which did not patronize those common carriers. [
Footnote 11] The Commission, after a
hearing, upheld the initial decision of its examiner and dismissed
the complaint, with two dissents. [
Footnote 12] The Court of Appeals for the District of
Columbia Circuit affirmed, [
Footnote 13] and we granted certiorari to consider
important questions under the Shipping Act. [
Footnote 14]
I
The petitioner's primary contention -- supported by the United
States, a party respondent -- is that implementation of the
Association's formula for levying the Mech Fund assessments was
unenforceable, because the agreement among Association members
imposing that formula was not filed with the Commission in accord
with § 15 of the Act. That section provides that there be
filed with the Commission "every agreement" among persons subject
to the Act
"fixing or regulating transportation rates or fares; giving or
receiving special rates, accommodations, or other special
privileges or advantages; controlling, regulating, preventing, or
destroying competition;
Page 390 U. S. 269
pooling or apportioning earnings, losses, or traffic; allotting
ports or restricting or otherwise regulating the number and
character of sailings between ports; limiting or regulating in any
way the volume or character of freight or passenger traffic to be
carried; or in any manner providing for an exclusive, preferential,
or cooperative working arrangement. . . . [
Footnote 15]"
Until submitted to and approved by the Commission, "it shall be
unlawful to carry out in whole or in part, directly or indirectly,
any such agreement. . . ." [
Footnote 16] The Commission is directed to disapprove any
agreement
"that it finds to be unjustly discriminatory or unfair as
between carriers, shippers, exporters, importers,
Page 390 U. S. 270
or ports, or between exporters from the United States and their
foreign competitors, or to operate to the detriment of the commerce
of the United States, or to be contrary to the public interest, or
to be in violation of [the Act]. [
Footnote 17] "
Page 390 U. S. 271
An agreement filed with and approved by the Commission is
immunized from challenge under the antitrust laws. [
Footnote 18]
The Commission held that, although the Mech Fund assessment
formula was a "cooperative working agreement" clearly within the
plain language of § 15, it nonetheless was not the kind of
agreement required to be filed with the Commission under that
section:
"Although the literal language of section 15 is broad enough to
encompass any 'cooperative working arrangement' entered into by
persons subject to the Act, the legislative history is clear that
the statute was intended by Congress to apply only to those
agreements involving practices which affect that competition which
in the absence of the agreement would exist between the parties
when dealing with the shipping or traveling public or their
representatives."
"
* * * *"
"It is not contested that the membership of [the Association]
entered into an agreement as to the manner of assessing its own
membership for the collection of the 'Mech' fund. Such an
agreement, however, does not fall within the confines of section 15
as, standing by itself, it has no impact upon
Page 390 U. S. 272
outsiders. What must be demonstrated before a section 15
agreement may be said to exist is that there was an additional
agreement by the [Association] membership to pass on all or a
portion of its assessments to the carriers and shippers served by
the terminal operators."
9 F.M.C. at 82-83.
The Court of Appeals affirmed. That court felt itself confined
by our decision in
Consolo v. FMC, 383 U.
S. 607, to determining simply whether the Commission's
ruling was supported by "substantial evidence." With "due deference
to the expertise of the Commission," it concluded "(albeit with
some hesitation) that there is substantial evidence in the record,
considered as a whole, to support the Commission's decision." 125
U.S.App.D.C. at 290, 371 F.2d at 755.
The issue in this case, however, relates not to the sufficiency
of evidence, but to the construction of a statute. The construction
put on a statute by the agency charged with administering it is
entitled to deference by the courts, and ordinarily that
construction will be affirmed if it has a "reasonable basis in
law."
NLRB v. Hearst Publications, 322 U.
S. 111,
322 U. S. 131;
Unemployment Commission v. Aragon, 329 U.
S. 143,
329 U. S.
153-154. But the courts are the final authorities on
issues of statutory construction,
FTC v. Colgate-Palmolive
Co., 380 U. S. 374,
380 U. S. 385,
and
"are not obliged to stand aside and rubber-stamp their
affirmance of administrative decisions that they deem inconsistent
with a statutory mandate or that frustrate the congressional policy
underlying a statute."
NLRB v. Brown, 380 U. S. 278,
380 U. S. 291.
"The deference owed to an expert tribunal cannot be allowed to slip
into a judicial inertia. . . ."
American Ship Building Co. v.
NLRB, 380 U. S. 300,
380 U. S. 318.
Cf. FMB v. Isbrandtsen Co., 356 U.
S. 481,
356 U. S.
499-500 (where this Court overturned the Commission's
construction of § 14 of the Shipping Act).
Page 390 U. S. 273
In limiting § 15 to agreements which "affect competition,"
and in finding that the assessment agreement did not so "affect
competition," the Commission, in this case, used that phrase in a
highly artificial sense -- by requiring "an additional agreement by
the [Association] membership to pass on all or a portion of its
assessments. . . ." There is no question that the assessment
agreement necessarily affected the cost structures of, and the
charges levied by, individual Association members. Most, though not
all, of the stevedoring contractors and terminal operators did pass
the assessment on. The economic realities were such that many of
them had no choice -- a fact of which they apprised the Association
at the time the assessment arrangement was being devised. [
Footnote 19] In the case of
Terminals, the assessment it had to pay on Volkswagen automobiles
was more than twice its profit margin.
The Commission thus took an extremely narrow view of a statute
that uses expansive language. In support of that view, the
Commission argued in this Court that a narrow construction of
§ 15 should be adopted in order to minimize the number of
agreements that may receive antitrust exemption. However, antitrust
exemption results not when an agreement is submitted for filing,
but only when the agreement is actually approved, and, in deciding
whether to approve an agreement, the Commission is required under
§ 15 to consider antitrust
Page 390 U. S. 274
implications. [
Footnote
20]
FMC v. Aktiebolaget Svenska Amerika Linien, ante,
p.
390 U. S. 238;
see also Isbrandtsen Co. v. United States, 93 U.S.App.D.C.
293, 211 F.2d 5. [
Footnote
21]
The Commission itself has not heretofore limited § 15 to
horizontal agreements among competitors, but has applied it to
other types of agreements coming within its literal terms.
See,
e.g., Agreements Nos. 822 and 8225-1, Between Greater Baton Rouge
Port Commission and Cargill, Inc., 5 F.M.B. 648 (1959),
affirmed, 287 F.2d 86, and
Agreement No. T-4: Terminal
Lease Agreement at Long Beach, California, 8 F.M.C. 521
(1965), applying § 15 to lease agreements. [
Footnote 22] In the latter case, decided
only four months before its decision in the case before us, the
Commission said:
"Section 15 describes in unambiguous language those agreements
that must be filed; it does not speak of agreements
per se
violative of the Sherman Act.
Page 390 U. S. 275
Since the wording of section 15 is clear, we need not refer to
the legislative history; there is simply no ambiguity to
resolve."
8 F.M.C. at 31. To limit § 15 to agreements that "affect
competition," as the Commission used that phrase in the present
case, simply does not square with the structure of the statute.
[
Footnote 23]
The legislative history offers no support for a different view.
The genesis of the Shipping Act was the "Alexander Report" in 1914.
[
Footnote 24]
FMB v.
Isbrandtsen Co., 356 U. S. 481,
356 U. S. 490.
While it is true that the attention of that congressional committee
was focused primarily upon the practices that had cartelized much
of the maritime industry, it is clear that the concerns of its
inquiry were far more broadly ranging. The report summed up the
testimony before the committee:
"Nearly all the steamship line representatives . . . expressed
themselves as not opposed to government supervision . . . and
approval of
all agreements or arrangements which steamship
lines may have entered into with other steamship lines, with
shippers, or with other carriers and transportation agencies.
On the other hand, the shippers who appeared as witnesses . . .
were, in the great majority of instances, favorable to a
comprehensive system of government supervision . . . [and]
the
approval of contracts, agreements, and arrangements, and the
general supervision of all conditions of water transportation
which vitally affect the interests of shippers."
Alexander Report, at 418. (Emphasis added.)
Page 390 U. S. 276
The committee recommended, among other things:
"That all carriers engaged in the foreign trade of the United
States, parties to any agreements, understandings, or conference
arrangements hereinafter referred to, be required to file for
approval . . . a copy of all written agreements (or a complete
memorandum if the understanding or agreement is oral) entered into
(1) with any other steamship companies, firms, or lines engaged
directly or indirectly in the American trade, or (2) with American
shippers, railroads or other transportation agencies."
Alexander Report, at 419-420. Nothing in the legislative history
suggests that Congress, in enacting § 15 of the Act, meant to
do less than follow this recommendation of the Alexander Report and
subject to the scrutiny of a specialized government agency the
myriad of restrictive agreements in the maritime industry.
[
Footnote 25]
This is not to say that the Commission is without power to
determine, after appropriate administrative proceedings, that some
types or classes of agreements coming within the literal provisions
of § 15 are of such a
de minimis or routine character
as not to require formal filing. Since the Commission's decision in
the present case, Congress has explicitly given it such
authority:
"The Federal Maritime Commission, upon application or on its own
motion, may by order or rule exempt for the future any class of
agreements between persons subject to this chapter or any specified
activity of such persons from any requirement of this chapter, or
Intercoastal Shipping Act, 1933,
Page 390 U. S. 277
where it finds that such exemption will not substantially impair
effective regulation by the Federal Maritime Commission, be
unjustly discriminatory, or be detrimental to commerce."
"The Commission may attach conditions to any such exemptions and
may, by order, revoke any such exemption. [
Footnote 26]"
46 U.S.C. § 833a (1964 ed., Supp. II).
But the agreement with which we deal here -- levying $29,000,000
over five years, binding all principal carriers, stevedoring
contractors, and terminal operators on the Pacific Coast, and
necessarily resulting in substantially increased stevedoring and
terminal charges -- was neither
de minimis nor routine. We
hold that this agreement was required to be filed under § 15
of the Act.
Page 390 U. S. 278
It is to be emphasized that the only agreement involved in this
case is the one among members of the Association allocating the
impact of the Mech Fund levy. We are not concerned here with the
agreement creating the Association, or with the collective
bargaining agreement between the Association and the ILWU. No claim
has been made in this case that either of those agreements was
subject to the filing requirements of § 15. Those agreements,
reflecting the national labor policy of free collective bargaining
by representatives of the parties' own unfettered choice, fall in
an area of concern to the National Labor Relations Board, and
nothing we have said in this opinion is to be understood as
questioning their continuing validity. But, in negotiating with the
ILWU, the Association insisted that its members were to have the
exclusive right to determine how the Mech Fund was to be assessed,
and a clause to that effect was included in the collective
bargaining agreement. That assessment arrangement, affecting only
relationships among Association members and their customers, is all
that is before us in this case. Moreover, so far as the record
shows, only the assessment on automobiles is now challenged, and
there is no reason to suppose that the Commission will not consider
expeditious approval of so much of the agreement as is not in
dispute.
II
The petitioner also attacked the Association's assessment of its
automobiles under § 16 and § 17 of the Shipping Act.
Section 16 makes it unlawful "to subject any particular person,
locality, or description of traffic to any undue or unreasonable
prejudice or disadvantage," [
Footnote 27] and
Page 390 U. S. 279
§ 17 forbids any "unjust or unreasonable" regulation or
practice "relating to or connected with the receiving, handling,
storing, or delivering of property." [
Footnote 28] The Commission ruled that neither of these
sections had been violated, and the Court of Appeals affirmed.
If the agreement is now filed under § 15, the Commission
will be called upon again to consider the effect of §§ 16
and 17, since an agreement that violates a specific provision of
the Act must be disapproved. [
Footnote 29] Accordingly, it is not inappropriate,
without now passing upon the ultimate merits of the §§ 16
and 17 issues, to give brief consideration to the Commission's
handling of those issues upon the present record.
The Commission ruled that the petitioner had failed to
demonstrate any "undue or unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage"
under § 16 solely because it had not shown any unequal
treatment as between its automobiles and other automobiles or cargo
competitive with automobiles. In so ruling, the Commission applied
the "competitive relationship" doctrine which it has developed in
cases concerning rates for carriage of goods by sea. [
Footnote 30]
Page 390 U. S. 280
But the Commission, in cases not involving freight rates and the
particularized economics that result from a vessel's finite cargo
capacity, [
Footnote 31] has
often found § 16 violations even in the absence of a
"competitive relationship."
See, e.g., Practices, etc., of San
Francisco Bay Area Terminals, 2 U.S.M.C. 588 (1941) and 709
(1944), and
Storage Practices at Longview, Washington, 6
F.M.B. 178 (1960), involving storage charges, and
New York
Foreign Freight Forwarders and Brokers Assn. v. FMC, 337 F.2d
289, involving freight forwarders' fees. In a proceeding subsequent
to its decision in the present case, the Commission explicitly
dispensed with the competitive relationship requirement with
respect to port "free time."
Investigation of Free Time
Practices -- Port of San Diego, 9 F.M.C. 525 (1966);
cf.
California v. United States, 320 U. S. 577.
See also Investigation on Household Goods, North Atlantic
Mediterranean Freight Conference, F.M.C. Docket No. 669 (June
30, 1967). When the agreement in the present case is filed, the
Commission may consider anew whether the mere absence of a
competitive relationship should foreclose further § 16
inquiry. [
Footnote 32]
With respect to § 17, the Commission found that the
assessment upon the petitioner's automobiles was not
Page 390 U. S. 281
"unreasonable," because the petitioner had received "substantial
benefits" in return for the assessment, and there was no showing of
a deliberate intent to impose an unfair burden upon the petitioner.
This, we think, reflects far too narrow a view of § 17. It may
be that a relatively small charge imposed uniformly for the benefit
of an entire group can be reasonable under § 17 even though
not all members of the group receive equal benefits.
See Evans
Cooperage Co. v. Board of Commissioners of the Port of New
Orleans, 6 F.M.B. 415. [
Footnote 33] But here, a relatively large charge was
unequally imposed. The benefits received by the petitioner may have
been substantial, but other cargo received greater benefits at
one-tenth the cost. [
Footnote
34] Moreover, the question of reasonableness under § 17
does not depend upon unlawful or discriminatory intent. As the
Commission itself has said:
"[Sections 16 and 17] proscribe and make unlawful certain
conduct, without regard to intent. The offense is committed by the
mere doing of the act, and the question of intent is not
involved."
Hellenic Lines Ltd. -- Violation of Sections 16 (First) and
17, 7 F.M.C. 673, 675-676 (1964).
Page 390 U. S. 282
Cf. United States v. Illinois Central R. Co.,
263 U. S. 515,
263 U. S.
523-526;
ICC v. Chicago G. W. R. Co.,
209 U. S. 108.
The question under § 17 is not whether the petitioner has
received some substantial benefit as the result of the Mech Fund
assessment, but whether the correlation of that benefit to the
charges imposed is reasonable. The "substantial benefits" measure
of unreasonableness used by the Commission in this case is far too
blunt an instrument. Nothing in the language or history of the
statute supports so tortured a construction of the phrase "just and
reasonable." The Commission has cited no similar construction of
the phrase by any other regulatory agency or court. Indeed, in past
decisions, the Commission itself has not applied any such test.
See California Stevedore & Ballast Co. v. Stockton
Elevators, Inc., 8 F.M.B. 97 (1964), and
Practices, etc.,
of San Francisco Bay Area Terminals, 2 U.S.M.C. 588 (1941),
affirmed, 320 U. S. 320 U.S.
577, where the Commission found violations of § 17 even though
the benefits received were clearly substantial. The proper inquiry
under § 17 is, in a word, whether the charge levied is
reasonably related to the service rendered.
The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed, and the case
is remanded for further proceedings consistent with this
opinion.
It is so ordered.
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL took no part in the consideration or
decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
All parties agree that this agreement was an enlightened,
forward-looking step in West Coast longshore labor relations.
See Kossoris, Working Rules in West Coast Longshoring, 84
Monthly Labor Rev. 1 (1961); Killingsworth, The Modernization of
West Coast Longshore Work Rules, 15 Ind. & Lab.Rel.L.Rev. 295
(1962);
ILWU (American Mail Line), 144 N.L.R.B. 1432, 1442
(1963).
The agreement was not signed in final form until November 15,
1961, although it was implemented in many respects prior to that
date.
[
Footnote 2]
The agreement has been continued, and the Mech Fund is still
being collected and paid out.
[
Footnote 3]
A minority of the committee recommended that the Mech Fund be
raised by the same formula by which the Association's dues were
levied -- a formula combining both tonnage handled and man hours
employed, in a ratio of 40/60.
Although the Mech Fund was initially assessed entirely on the
basis of tonnage, the formula was later amended to assess employers
of marine clerks on a man-hour basis. About 12% of the fund was
collected in this way.
[
Footnote 4]
Bulk cargo was assessed at 5 1/2� per revenue ton. In
December, 1961, the rates were increased to 28 1/2� for
general cargo and 9� for bulk cargo.
[
Footnote 5]
On chartered vessels automobiles, are manifested on a unit basis
(showing weight and sometimes measurement). On common carriers,
both weight and measurement are shown. In coastwise trade,
automobiles are manifested by weight.
[
Footnote 6]
Some time after the assessment agreement was implemented,
Terminals' charge to the petitioner exclusive of the assessment
decreased. The amount of the decrease does not appear in the
record.
[
Footnote 7]
These figures represent a weighted average of the petitioner's
two model lines at the time of the assessment agreement. Passenger
models were O.8 ton by weight and 7.8 tons by measurement;
unloading costs initially increased an estimated 22%. Transporter
models were 1.1 tons by weight and 11.4 tons by measurement;
unloading costs initially increased an estimated 31%.
[
Footnote 8]
When the Mech Fund agreement was reached, the unloading of
automobiles was already so highly mechanized that there was little
likelihood of improvement. Hence, shippers of automobiles stood to
receive from the agreement only the general benefits of a stable
labor situation, such as freedom from strikes and slowdowns.
[
Footnote 9]
The committee did make downward adjustments for scrap metal and
lumber.
[
Footnote 10]
By virtue of the Association's bylaws, carriers control the
Board of Directors and all membership votes. Both the committee
which devised the assessment formula and the one which later ruled
on claims of inequities were made up entirely of carriers; neither
committee had a single member who was a stevedoring contractor or
terminal operator.
[
Footnote 11]
The petitioner is the largest shipper of dry cargo by charter to
West Coast ports. It ships more than 75% of its vehicles by
charter, and most of the rest by common carriers which are not
members of the Association. About two-thirds of all automobiles
imported through West Coast ports are Volkswagens. It appears that
no other importer of automobiles through West Coast ports uses
chartered vessels.
Most, but not all, of the stevedoring contractors and terminal
operators passed the Mech Fund assessment on to their customers. In
most instances, these customers were common carriers who were
members of the Association. The member carriers did not pass the
assessment on to shippers. Hence, except in situations like the
petitioner's, the cost of the Mech Fund was borne by Association
members.
[
Footnote 12]
Volkswagenwerk Aktiengesellschaft v. Marine Terminals
Corp., 9 F.M.C. 77.
[
Footnote 13]
Volkswagenwerk Aktiengesellschaft v. FMC, 125
U.S.App.D.C. 282, 371 F.2d 747.
[
Footnote 14]
388 U.S. 909.
[
Footnote 15]
"Every common carrier by water, or other person subject to this
chapter, shall file immediately with the Commission a true copy,
or, if oral, a true and complete memorandum, of every agreement
with another such carrier or other person subject to this chapter,
or modification or cancellation thereof, to which it may be a party
or conform in whole or in part, fixing or regulating transportation
rates or fares; giving or receiving special rates, accommodations,
or other special privileges or advantages; controlling, regulating,
preventing, or destroying competition; pooling or apportioning
earnings, losses, or traffic; allotting ports or restricting or
otherwise regulating the number and character of sailings between
ports; limiting or regulating in any way the volume or character of
freight or passenger traffic to be carried; or in any manner
providing for an exclusive, preferential, or cooperative working
arrangement. The term 'agreement' in this section includes
understandings, conferences, and other arrangements."
46 U.S.C. § 814.
The original statute, in 1916, required filing with the United
States Shipping Board. 39 Stat. 728, 729, 733. The Shipping Board
was succeeded in 1933 by the United States Shipping Board Bureau of
the Department of Commerce, Exec.Order No. 6166, § 12 (1933);
in 1936, by the United States Maritime Commission, 49 Stat. 1985;
in 1950 ,by the Federal Maritime Board, 64 Stat. 1273, and in 1961,
by the Federal Maritime Commission, 75 Stat. 840. In this opinion,
the Federal Maritime Commission and its predecessors are
collectively referred to as the Commission.
[
Footnote 16]
"Any agreement and any modification or cancellation of any
agreement not approved, or disapproved, by the Commission shall be
unlawful, and agreements, modifications, and cancellations shall be
lawful only when and as long as approved by the Commission; before
approval or after disapproval it shall be unlawful to carry out in
whole or in part, directly or indirectly, any such agreement,
modification, or cancellation; except that tariff rates, fares, and
charges, and classifications, rules, and regulations explanatory
thereof (including changes in special rates and charges covered by
section 813a of this title which do not involve a change in the
spread between such rates and charges and the rates and charges
applicable to noncontract shippers) agreed upon by approved
conferences, and changes and amendments thereto, if otherwise in
accordance with law, shall be permitted to take effect without
prior approval upon compliance with the publication and filing
requirements of section 817(b) of this title and with the
provisions of any regulations the Commission may adopt."
46 U.S.C. § 814.
[
Footnote 17]
"The Commission shall by order, after notice and hearing,
disapprove, cancel or modify any agreement, or any modification or
cancellation thereof, whether or not previously approved by it,
that it finds to be unjustly discriminatory or unfair as between
carriers, shippers, exporters, importers, or ports, or between
exporters from the United States and their foreign competitors, or
to operate to the detriment of the commerce of the United States,
or to be contrary to the public interest, or to be in violation of
this chapter, and shall approve all other agreements,
modifications, or cancellations. No such agreement shall be
approved, nor shall continued approval be permitted for any
agreement (1) between carriers not members of the same conference
or conferences of carriers serving different trades that would
otherwise be naturally competitive, unless in the case of
agreements between carriers, each carrier, or in the case of
agreement between conferences, each conference, retains the right
of independent action, or (2) in respect to any conference
agreement, which fails to provide reasonable and equal terms and
conditions for admission and readmission to conference membership
of other qualified carriers in the trade, or fails to provide that
any member may withdraw from membership upon reasonable notice
without penalty for such withdrawal."
"The Commission shall disapprove any such agreement, after
notice and hearing, on a finding of inadequate policing of the
obligations under it, or of failure or refusal to adopt and
maintain reasonable procedures for promptly and fairly hearing and
considering shippers' requests and complaints."
46 U.S.C. § 814.
[
Footnote 18]
"Every agreement, modification, or cancellation lawful under
this section, or permitted under section 813a of this title, shall
be excepted from the provisions of sections 1-11 and 15 of Title
15, and amendments and Acts supplementary thereto."
46 U.S.C. § 814.
[
Footnote 19]
The dissenting opinion of Commissioner Patterson vigorously
attacked the Commission's finding that there was no implied
understanding among the Association members that the assessment
would be passed on. 9 F.M.C. at 101-104. The Court of Appeals found
considerable evidence in support of Commissioner Patterson's view.
125 U.S.App.D.C. at 290, n. 7, 371 F.2d at 755, n. 7. However,
applying the substantial evidence rule, the court upheld the
Commission's finding, although indicating that it might have found
the facts differently itself. 125 U.S.App.D.C. at 290-291, 371 F.2d
at 755-756.
[
Footnote 20]
One of the standards for approval under § 15, added in
1961, 75 Stat. 763, is whether or not the agreement is "contrary to
the public interest."
See n 17,
supra.
"We think it now beyond dispute that 'the public interest'
within the meaning of section 15 includes the national policy
embodied in the antitrust laws."
Mediterranean Pools Investigation, 9 F.M.C. 264,
289.
Any agreement subject to § 15 filing that is not both filed
and approved is not only illegal under § 15, but also subject
to attack under the antitrust laws.
Carnation Co. v. Pacific
Westbound Conference, 383 U. S. 213.
[
Footnote 21]
"[T]he Shipping Act specifically provides machinery for
legalizing that which would otherwise be illegal under the
antitrust laws. The condition upon which such authority is granted
is that the agency entrusted with the duty to protect the public
interest scrutinize the agreement to make sure that the conduct
thus legalized does not invade the prohibitions of the antitrust
laws any more than is necessary to serve the purposes of the
regulatory statute."
93 U.S.App.D.C. at 299, 211 F.2d at 57.
[
Footnote 22]
See also statement of Commission Chairman Harllee
requesting from Congress the authority for the Commission to exempt
from § 15 such otherwise included agreements as those between
two freight forwarders in different ports to perform services for
each other. H.R.Rep. No. 2248, 89th Cong., 2d Sess., 4-5
(1966).
[
Footnote 23]
Section 15 requires filing of "every agreement" in any of seven
categories, and one of the seven comprises all agreements which
"regulat[e] . . . competition."
See n 15,
supra. The other six categories
would be rendered virtually meaningless by the Commission's
construction.
[
Footnote 24]
House Committee on Merchant Marine and Fisheries, Report on
Steamship Agreements and Affiliations, H.R.Doc. No. 805, 63d Cong.,
2d Sess., 415-424 (1914).
[
Footnote 25]
The recommendations of the Alexander Report were incorporated
into both the House and Senate Reports on the Shipping Act.
H.R.Rep. No. 659, 64th Cong., 1st Sess., 27-32 (1916); S.Rep. No.
689, 64th Cong., 1st Sess., 7-12 (1916).
[
Footnote 26]
The need for this provision is set forth in S.Rep. No. 1459,
89th Cong., 2d Sess., 2 (1966):
"The Federal Maritime Commission, under the Shipping Act, 1916,
regulates certain operations of water carriers and other persons
subject to the act which have only slight effect on the foreign
commerce of this country, and are not significant in the overall
design of regulation contemplated by the 1916 act. Exacting
compliance with the act under these circumstances has proven
unnecessarily costly to the carrier and the Government."
"The authority conferred under this legislation will relieve the
Commission and affected carriers of an undue regulatory burden. In
addition, a general exemption will preclude the necessity for a
piecemeal approach in the future."
Prior to this 1966 amendment, the Commission had taken some
steps to protect itself from
de minimis filings. In
Section 15 Inquiry, 1 U.S.S.B. 121 (1927), the Commission
held "routine" intraconference changes and transactions not subject
to § 15. In
Oranje Line v. Anchor Line, 6 F.M.B.199,
209 (1961), the Commission construed its decision in
Los
Angeles By-Products Co. v. Barber S.S. Lines, 2 U.S.M.C. 106
(1939), as holding joint advertising not subject to § 15.
Proceeding under general power to issue regulations conferred on it
in 1961, 46 U.S.C. § 841a, the Commission exempted at least
one class of
de minimis agreements in 46 CFR §§
530.5(d)(4) and (5), dealing with certain terminal agreements.
[
Footnote 27]
"It shall be unlawful for any common carrier by water, or other
person subject to this chapter, either alone or in conjunction with
any other person, directly or indirectly -- "
"First. To make or give any undue or unreasonable preference or
advantage to any particular person, locality, or description of
traffic in any respect whatsoever, or to subject any particular
person, locality, or description of traffic to any undue or
unreasonable prejudice or disadvantage in any respect whatsoever. .
. ."
46 U.S.C. § 815.
[
Footnote 28]
"Every such carrier and every other person subject to this
chapter shall establish, observe, and enforce just and reasonable
regulations and practices relating to or connected with the
receiving, handling, storing, or delivering of property. Whenever
the Board finds that any such regulation or practice is unjust or
unreasonable it may determine, prescribe, and order enforced a just
and reasonable regulation or practice."
46 U.S.C. § 816.
[
Footnote 29]
See n 17,
supra.
[
Footnote 30]
See, e.g., Boston Wool Trade Assn. v. M. & M. T.
Co., 1 U.S.S.B. 24 (1921);
Eagle-Ottawa Leather Co. v.
Goodrich Transit Co., 1 U.S.S.B. 101 (1926);
Philadelphia
Ocean Traffic Bureau v. Export S.S. Corp., 1 U.S.S.B. 538
(1936);
Huber Mfg. C. v. N.V. Stoomvaart Maatschappij
"Nederland," 4 F.M.B. 343 (1953);
West Indies Fruit Co. v.
Flota Mercante 7 F.M.C. 66 (1962).
[
Footnote 31]
See S. Bross, Ocean Shipping 189-190 (1956); C. Cufley,
Ocean Freights and Chartering 400-407 (1962).
[
Footnote 32]
The Interstate Commerce Commission has a competitive
relationship rule with respect to § 3(1) of the Interstate
Commerce Act, 54 Stat. 902, 49 U.S.C. § 3(1),
Rheem Mfg.
Co. v. Chicago, R.I. & P. R. Co., 273 I.C.C. 185;
United States v. Great Northern R. Co., 301 I.C.C. 21.
However, that Commission has said:
"This Commission has never held that competition is an
indispensable element in a situation of undue prejudice and
preference, although it has frequently said that, 'ordinarily,' or
'generally,' a competitive relation must appear."
Joseph A. Goddard Realty Co. v. New York, C. & St. L.R.
Co., 229 I.C.C. 497, 501.
[
Footnote 33]
In the
Evans Cooperage case, the Commission upheld a
uniform wharfage charge which was imposed on all those who used the
wharf, even though the various users of the wharf did not all
receive precisely equal benefits from it. But the Commission looked
beyond "substantial benefits" to the relationship between the
service and the charge:
"The [Commission of the Port of New Orleans] has made a charge
to help defray its costs of operating facilities as measured by
cargo handled in the area and the only question is
whether
its facilities are being used and
the commission is performing
a service reasonably related to its charges. The Examiner
considered the evidence, and found that it was."
(Emphasis added.) 6 F.M.B. at 418-419.
[
Footnote 34]
See n 8,
supra.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN, concurring.
Although I agree with the conclusions reached by the Court in
this case, I deem it desirable to amplify the reasons, as I see
them, for what is decided today. More especially, I think that
further justification is needed for the Court's decision (1) that
the "assessment agreement" falls within the Commission's
jurisdiction under
Page 390 U. S. 283
§ 15 notwithstanding its intimate connection with the
underlying collective bargaining agreement, and (2) that the
Commission should give further consideration to the §§ 16
and 17 issues notwithstanding that it has already determined
them.
I
The Pacific Maritime Association is a multi-employer collective
bargaining group. Its "assessment agreement," directly in question
here, is closely related to a collective bargaining agreement
covering a subject about which employers are required to bargain,
"terms and conditions of employment." [
Footnote 2/1] This underlying labor agreement was,
according to apparently unanimous industry and expert opinion, a
highly desirable step forward in the shipping industry.
Multi-employer collective bargaining units have long been
recognized as among the unit classifications that the National
Labor Relations Board may deem "appropriate." In
Labor Board v.
Truck Drivers Union, 353 U. S. 87, we
held that Congress intended
"that the Board should continue its established administrative
practice of certifying multi-employer units, and intended to leave
to the Board's specialized judgment the inevitable questions
concerning multi-employer bargaining bound to arise in the
future."
Id. at
353 U. S. 96. We
specifically referred to longshoring as an industry with a long
history of multi-employer bargaining, and we noted
"cogent evidence that, in many industries, the multi-employer
bargaining basis was a vital factor in the effectuation of the
national policy of promoting labor peace through strengthened
collective bargaining."
Id. at
353 U. S.
95.
Page 390 U. S. 284
The Board has authorized a multi-employer bargaining unit for
West Coast shipping, and the labor agreement that forms the
background to this case is additional "cogent evidence."
At the same time, the very existence of multi-employer units,
and the obvious need for the employers involved to agree on
collective policy, must invariably have competitive effects. The
signatories to a collective bargaining agreement are frequently, by
the very act of signing, agreeing with their own competitors on
matters such as labor costs, certain nonlabor costs, services to be
provided to the public, and (indirectly) price increases.
Multi-employer collective bargaining must therefore be
reconciled with the sometimes competing policies of federal laws
promoting and regulating competition,
viz., the antitrust
laws and, in the case of maritime labor relations, the Shipping
Act. This is a problem on which Congress has provided relatively
little direct guidance, [
Footnote
2/2] but it is one of a kind that the Court has repeatedly
grappled with since
Allen Bradley Co. v. Union,
325 U. S. 797. It
is a problem of line-drawing.
The Court, noting that the assessment agreement levied
$29,000,000, thus "necessarily resulting in substantially increased
stevedoring and terminal charges,"
ante at
390 U. S. 277,
holds that the assessment agreement must be filed under § 15
of the Act. It says that the underlying labor agreement is not
before us, and the "continuing validity" of that agreement is not
brought into question by today's decision.
Ante at
390 U. S.
278.
Page 390 U. S. 285
On the other hand, my Brother DOUGLAS argues that, on the
Court's premise, the assessment agreement could not be
distinguished from any collective bargaining agreement that "raised
labor costs beyond the point at which PMA members could be expected
to absorb those costs without raising prices or charges."
Post at
390 U. S. 313.
He further contends that, if part of a collective bargaining
agreement is subject to Commission approval, this will stifle labor
negotiation. [
Footnote 2/3]
Consequently, he suggests that a proper accommodation between
"labor" and "competition" interests can be reached by exempting
both labor agreements and labor-related agreements from the filing
requirement of § 15, but leaving them subject to the specific
prohibitions of the antitrust laws and § 16 and 17 of the
Shipping Act.
This suggested accommodation seems to me demonstrably wrong. In
the first place, as the Court notes, the filing requirement of 15
was drafted broadly, and the "filing and approval" process includes
review of questions arising under §§ 16 and 17, and
specifically creates an exemption from antitrust attack. Hence, if
the question were simply whether substantive challenge to a
maritime agreement (dealing with labor or with any other matter) is
to take place in advance of implementation of the agreement or,
instead, during its operation, I should have thought it clear that
Congress chose the former alternative. Furthermore, I would find it
very difficult to see why provision for advance approval and
exemption of labor-related agreements would not be
Page 390 U. S. 286
preferable, from the standpoint of facilitating collective
bargaining, to the "wait and see" approach.
The real difficulty in this case is not to distinguish between
agreements that must be filed and agreements whose impact on
competition will be evaluated after implementation, but to define
the Commission's jurisdiction in such a way that, whether
challenges arise before or after implementation, the Commission
will not improperly be brought into labor matters where it does not
belong. The Court's only suggestion is that the labor agreements
involved in this case "fall in an area of concern to the National
Labor Relations Board."
Ante at
390 U. S.
278.
More circumspect analysis than this is needed, I believe. In the
first place, since the later validity and antitrust immunity of all
agreements subject to § 15 depend upon filing, it is desirable
that signatories to agreements be given more precise instructions
than that they need not file if they are in an area of Labor Board
"concern." Furthermore, I see no warrant for assuming, in advance,
that a maritime agreement must always fall neatly into either the
Labor Board or Maritime Commission domain; a single contract might
well raise issues of concern to both.
The Commission took the position that § 15 of the Act,
requiring filing, was meant to apply
"only to those agreements involving practices which affect that
competition which, in the absence of the agreement, would exist
between the parties when dealing with the shipping or traveling
public or their representatives. [
Footnote 2/4]"
I agree with the Court's conclusion that proper application of
that principle to this case would require the opposite result from
the one the Commission reached. The difficulty, however, is that
the principle is excessively
Page 390 U. S. 287
broad: any significant multi-employer agreement on economic
matters "affects competition" with respect to prices and services
to the public, even if it is a collective bargaining agreement or
an employer agreement collateral thereto.
Since maritime employers are permitted to bargain as a group,
and since they are required to bargain about certain subjects, the
resulting agreements must have some exemption from the filing
requirements of § 15 and from successful challenge under the
antitrust laws or under the substantive principles in §§
16 and 17 of the Shipping Act. The exact extent of the "labor
exemption" or "labor immunity" from statutes regulating competition
has troubled this Court before; [
Footnote 2/5] however, since no collective bargaining
agreement in the maritime industry is now before us, it would be
inappropriate to suggest the affirmative extent of the immunity.
The important point in this case is an opposite and two-edged one:
the assessment agreement before us is
not immune or
exempt, for it raises "shipping" problems logically distinct from
the industry's labor problems; at the same time, Commission review
itself must be circumscribed by the existence of labor problems
that it is not equipped to resolve.
The assessment agreement was, of course, consequent upon the
labor agreement committing PMA to raise the fund. The union side
was concerned with a guarantee that the fund would be raised
somehow, and the
Page 390 U. S. 288
labor agreement guaranteed only that much. But whenever any
multi-employer bargaining unit agrees to provide benefits for
employees, there arises a problem of how to allocate the costs
among the various employers and, in consequence, among their
customers.
Often, the "allocation" decision follows directly from the terms
of the labor agreement. In the case of a multi-employer agreement
to raise wages, for example, each employer simply bears the cost of
benefiting his own employees. In the present case, had it been
possible to make the levy on each employer directly proportional
to, and roughly simultaneous with, the savings to that employer
from modernization, two things would have followed: the
"allocation" decision could be said to stem directly from the terms
of the labor agreement, and the modernization program would "pay
for itself" as it went along, leaving shipping customers
unaffected.
The PMA, however, did not (and presumably could not) apportion
costs in this manner. To the extent that, under the plan chosen,
individual employers were unable to absorb the levy and debit it
against future savings from modernization, the decision how much
each employer was to pay necessarily affected that employer's
customers as a class. To the extent that the plan went on to
determine which of an employer's customers would ultimately pay
which share of an employer's dues, the agreement also made choices
among customers of an individual employer.
The Commission nevertheless held that the agreement did not
"affect competition," because there was "no agreement" to pass the
levy on to individual customers. Whether the error be deemed one of
"fact" or one of "law," these conclusions are irreconcilable with
reality. Terminal companies such as MTC compete with each other for
the business of unloading Volkswagens.
Page 390 U. S. 289
The allocation agreement involved in this case increases the
cost to a terminal company of unloading one Volkswagen by $2.35.
This is a substantial (25%) increase in the company's cost for
handling this one product. Since the mechanization and
modernization program is not expected to produce a significant
(much less a compensatory) saving in the other costs of handling
Volkswagens, no terminal company could, in the long run, "absorb"
this cost: companies do not absorb costs that are not expected to
pay dividends in the future. [
Footnote
2/6] MTC's only choice was whether to pass the $2.35 on
directly to Volkswagen or to pass it on to its other customers in
the form of higher charges or lower future savings from
mechanization. Since the latter alternative would presumably have
driven these other customers to deal with other terminal companies
not bearing the Volkswagen curse, MTC was, in practice, compelled
to pass at least a large part of the additional cost on to
Volkswagen.
The statements of numerous officials of the participating
companies to the effect that there were no "agreements" affecting
Volkswagen (statements constituting in large part the "substantial
evidence" on which the Commission is supposed to have relied, 125
U.S.App.D.C. at 291, 371 F.2d at 756), are, at best, quibbles about
the meaning of words. The members of the Association must be taken
to have agreed to the obvious consequences of the paper they all
signed. That paper did not destroy price competition for
Volkswagen's trade; nor would a specific agreement to "pass on" the
additional
Page 390 U. S. 290
$2.35 charge have done so. But the allocation agreement made
Volkswagen a less desirable customer to each and every terminal
company unless it did pass on the $2.35 charge. How the Commission
could conclude that this collective imposition, by the terminal
companies on themselves, of a heavy tax for handling one kind of
product did not "affect" competition among them for the trade of
shippers of that product I simply cannot understand.
Commission review of the fairness of the agreement allocating
the cost burden of mechanization does not mean Commission review of
a labor agreement and does not imply consequences in conflict with
national labor policy. Whether to mechanize, or otherwise
modernize, and what provision should be made for displaced workers,
are obviously matters of union concern, and negotiations about
these things should be governed by the law of collective
bargaining. Resolution of such questions by a decision to create a
"Mech Fund" gave rise to a subsidiary "allocation" question. The
union was concerned that the question receive some answer, but had
no proper interest in which of the possible cost allocation plans
was adopted, so long as any such plan raised the amount promised.
On the other hand, in the present case, no one has suggested that
Maritime Commission review of a particular method of cost
allocation may properly reach the question whether the obligation
necessitating the allocation should have been entered into, or that
the Commission may reject an allocation plan when there are no
preferable alternative routes to collection of the necessary
amount. Review of the fairness and propriety of a taxing scheme is
not the same thing as reviewing the fairness and propriety of the
uses to which the tax money, once collected, is put. When the Court
notes that only the assessment agreement must be filed and
examined, it seems clear that it contemplates a Commission
Page 390 U. S. 291
examination starting from the premise that the obligation to
collect the Mech Fund will be fulfilled; at issue will be only the
propriety of the choice of the route to that objective. [
Footnote 2/7]
II
With respect to the §§ 16 and 17 issues, I consider
that the Commission's approach to those questions rested, as indeed
the Court's opinion now intimates, upon an erroneous understanding
of the "assessment agreement" necessitating reconsideration of
those matters on remand of the case.
The agreement that was before the Commission was, so far as
appears, quite unlike any agreement that body had considered
before. It dealt neither with a charge for particularized services
in the carrying, handling, or storage of goods nor with how such
services would be provided. Rather, the agreement levied a "tax" on
Association members, a tax which (insofar as the modernization
program did not directly "pay its own way") would be passed on to
members' customers, and ultimately to the public. The tax would be
used to pay for a general benefit to the shipping industry, but the
allocation of that tax bore no direct relationship to benefits
received by customers.
The Court holds that it was error for the Commission to reject
challenges to this agreement under § 16 simply because there
was no showing that the tax was discriminatory as between
competitive customers. It declares that such a rule may be sound in
cases involving rates
Page 390 U. S. 292
for sea carriage of goods because of the "particularized
economics" resulting from the finite capacity of ships, but that it
is not sound elsewhere, including this case, for unspecified
reasons.
On the surface, it might appear that the argument should be the
other way around: it makes some sense to speak of an "undue or
unreasonable preference or advantage" to, say, watermelons over
automobiles when they are "competing" for a finite amount of
shipping space; it becomes much more difficult to find anything
that can be called a "preference" between such products with
respect to any services that are available to both in unlimited
quantities.
My Brother DOUGLAS states that the Commission has consistently
adhered to its insistence upon a competitive relationship between
the product preferred and the product disadvantaged, except where
"there are services that are not dependent upon the nature of the
cargo and the various charges therefor."
Post at
390 U. S. 314,
n. 30. Yet, if ever it was clear that "the nature of the
[products]" was not the basis for a difference in rates, it is in
this case.
The true solution of the matter, it seems to me, is that, in
each situation, the problem has been to devise some workable basis
for determining whether rates are fair
vis-a-vis other
rates. It simply would not be feasible, as the Second Circuit has
noted, [
Footnote 2/8] to assess the
fairness of charges for shipping heavy industrial equipment by
comparison with the cost of shipping bananas. The notion of a
"preference" for bananas over heavy equipment is simply too elusive
to be implemented. At the same time, when the service rendered is,
for example, procuring insurance or arranging for cartage,
Page 390 U. S. 293
the nature of the product has very little to do with either the
value to the customer of the services rendered or the cost of
supplying them; in such cases, the Commission has quite reasonably
held that charging different classes of shippers different amounts
for equivalent services may be preferential. [
Footnote 2/9]
In the present case, the problem before PMA was the allocation
of a pre-specified total cost among its various members and their
customers. Since this was very much a case of first impression, the
Commission would have done well to go back to the language of
§ 16, which proscribes any "undue or unreasonable preference
or advantage to any . . . description of traffic in any respect
whatsoever." [
Footnote 2/10]
Certainly, since a "modernization tax" on any one group of
customers lowered, by an equivalent amount, the cost of
modernization to others obligated to pay for it, an unfair
allocation of the burden could properly be described as a
"preference" between that "description of traffic" bearing a heavy
burden and that "description of traffic" whose burden was
correspondingly lightened.
The real difficulty in this case is to formulate a workable
definition of whether the burdens have been "unfairly" allocated.
Obviously, as the debates in the PMA indicate, there was no
"perfect" way to apportion the costs. Any analysis of the present
problem must leave room for the implementation of some uniform,
practical, general rule of assessment even though it have some
features that are less desirable than some alternative imperfect
rule. The difficulty with the method of assessment adopted by PMA
is that it was not uniform and general, but made special provision
for automobiles. The fact that all automobiles are treated alike
should
Page 390 U. S. 294
not have prevented the Commission from inquiring whether special
treatment for this class of goods was necessary under the
circumstances and, if so, whether the special rule adopted was the
fairest that could be devised.
The Commission's interpretation of § 17 was also erroneous.
The Commission held that, since petitioner received substantial
benefits from the modernization program, it would not make minute
inquiry into whether petitioner's benefits precisely corresponded
to the costs imposed. The first difficulty is with the conclusion
that petitioner received "substantial benefits." Petitioner
apparently is not in a position to profit appreciably from maritime
modernization. Petitioner will, of course, benefit from any
lessening of labor disputes in shipping and related services, but
the only disruptions that are avoided by the labor agreement
reached here are those that would otherwise have resulted from the
efforts of other shippers and of maritime employers to institute
the very modernization practices that will not benefit petitioner.
It may be that those who will directly benefit from modernization
and those who will benefit only from increased stability during the
course of a modernization program in which they have no interest
(and which others have imposed on them) should both pay part of the
cost of the Mech Fund. However, the existence of such a categorical
difference between the benefits received by different groups should
at least invite inquiry whether charges are as appropriately
proportioned as would be feasible.
In fact, the tax assessed is not "equal" as between Volkswagen
and other shippers who will benefit more. The charge to MTC per
Volkswagen was figured on a different basis from the assessments
for handling other products; the figure reached was a substantially
higher percentage of existing costs and charges, and the figure was
so high that the additional cost apparently could
Page 390 U. S. 295
not be absorbed and debited against future savings from
modernization, but had to be passed on to the customer. Of course,
charges need only be "reasonably" related to benefits, and not
perfectly or exactly related,
Evans Cooperage Co. v. Board of
Commissioners of the Port of New Orleans, 6 F.M.B. 415, 418,
but, in this case, inquiry ceased before it had reached even that
nearer point.
Finding no disagreement in principle between myself and the
Court, I join the Court's opinion upon the premises stated in this
opinion.
[
Footnote 2/1]
61 Stat. 142, 29 U.S.C. § 158(d)
[
Footnote 2/2]
Section 6 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 731, 15 U.S.C. § 17,
provides that "[t]he labor of a human being is not a commodity or
article of commerce." Section 15 of the Shipping Act, 39 Stat. 733,
46 U.S.C. § 814, provides that agreements filed and approved
by the Commission "shall be excepted from the provisions of
sections 1-11 and 15 of Title 15 [antitrust provisions]. . . ."
[
Footnote 2/3]
Of course, Congress did not, in § 15, require "good"
agreements to be filed, and exempt bad ones. Nor did Congress
provide a special exemption for cases in which it would create a
special hardship to require filing of an agreement that was not
filed when it should have been. My Brother DOUGLAS is making a much
more relevant and serious point than that the Court's decision will
do incidental damage to a "good" agreement.
[
Footnote 2/4]
9 F.M.C. at 82.
[
Footnote 2/5]
E.g., Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.
S. 657;
Meat Cutters v. Jewel Tea, 381 U.
S. 676;
cf. Kennedy v. Long Island R. Co., 319
F.2d 366, 372-374. In
Mine Workers, the Court said,
"We think it beyond question that a union may conclude a wage
agreement with the multi-employer bargaining unit without violating
the antitrust laws. . . ."
381 U.S. at
381 U. S. 664.
It seems equally obvious that the employers are not violating the
antitrust laws either when they confer about wage policy
preparatory to bargaining or when they sign an agreement.
[
Footnote 2/6]
The fact that the figure $2.35 was, in fact, arithmetically
larger than MTC's computed profit per Volkswagen on the accounting
basis MTC used is, of course, not, in itself, critical. If MTC's
computed profit per vehicle had been $2.36, it would have had
nevertheless to make up the $2.35 additional cost somewhere.
[
Footnote 2/7]
The fact that the "labor" agreement and the "assessment"
agreement were on different pieces of paper is, of course, not
critical. What is important is that the whole process raised both
labor problems and distinct shipping problems. It would not be
impossible for there to be a single agreement raising some problems
of Labor Board "concern" and other, separate problems appropriate
to Commission review.
[
Footnote 2/8]
New York Foreign Freight Forwarders and Brokers Assn. v.
FMC, 337 F.2d 289, 299.
[
Footnote 2/9]
Ibid.; see, e.g., Investigation of Free Time Practices --
Port of San Diego, 9 F.M.C. 525.
[
Footnote 2/10]
46 U.S.C. § 815.
MR. JUSTICE FORTAS, concurring in the judgment.
I agree with the judgment and with Part I of the opinion herein.
I do not understand that the Court's opinion purports to determine
the effect of §§ 16 and 17, and I believe that the Court
certainly should not do so. I do not join Part II of the opinion
dealing with these sections.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS, dissenting in part.
I believe the Court has misconstrued § 15 of the Shipping
Act, 1916, [
Footnote 3/1] and I
fear that its erroneous construction will cause serious disruption
in the process of
Page 390 U. S. 296
collective bargaining in the maritime industry. If the tariff
exacted from petitioner is discriminatory or unreasonable,
§§ 16 and 17 of the Shipping Act [
Footnote 3/2] provide a remedy. If it violates the
antitrust laws, there is also a remedy, as I shall indicate. But to
require the funding part of maritime collective bargaining
agreements to receive prior approval from the Maritime Commission
is to use a sledge hammer to fix a watch. I cannot read § 15
so as to attribute to Congress such a heavy-handed management of
sensitive labor problems.
The collective bargaining agreement involved in this case, with
its Mechanization and Modernization Fund (Mech Fund), cannot be
evaluated properly without an understanding of maritime labor
relations and technological developments in the shipping
industry.
The history of maritime labor relations in this country has been
punctuated with lengthy major strikes and
Page 390 U. S. 297
continuous minor disruptions. [
Footnote 3/3] The maritime industry has long been faced
with problems of instability -- economic and managerial. Employment
for maritime workers is generally both irregular and insecure.
[
Footnote 3/4] That condition lies
behind the large number of major strikes and work stoppages on our
coasts.
Because the shipping industry is vitally important both to our
national commerce and national defense, the Federal Government has
maintained a special interest in trying to promote its growth and
stability. The Shipping Act, 1916, is one example of this concern.
[
Footnote 3/5] With respect to
maritime labor relations, however, the activities of the Federal
Government were, until our entry into World War I, primarily
devoted to laws protecting or disciplining seamen as individual
workers. The war years saw the Government actively encouraging
collective bargaining
Page 390 U. S. 298
in the maritime industry, its efforts resulting by 1920 in a
significant expansion of collective bargaining. There followed a
general retrogression, with wages and working conditions reaching
low levels. That condition prevailed until the highly disruptive
and violent Pacific Coast strike of 1934.
That strike was the product of deep-seated grievances of
maritime employees regarding low wages and poor working conditions.
[
Footnote 3/6] The situation on the
Atlantic Coast was not much better. Although an agreement was
reached in late 1934 for Atlantic Coast workers, labor relations
remained unstable, and work stoppages were rampant. On both coasts,
intra-union and inter-union disagreements, coupled with
employer-union hostility, made agreement highly difficult. Quickie
strikes dotted the ports, and another general strike followed in
1936. On the Pacific Coast, the employers and the ILWU (which had
achieved recognition after the 1934 strike) were in constant
conflict through 1948, when still another general strike erupted.
This period, from 1934 to 1948, has been
Page 390 U. S. 299
aptly described as something like "class warfare." [
Footnote 3/7] As one commentator put
it:
"The ILWU (then a part of the AFL International Longshoremen's
Association) gained formal employer recognition as a result of the
general strike of 1934, which followed years of exploitation and
abuse of longshoremen by their employers. The bitterness which had
characterized the industry carried over into the subsequent
employer-union relationship. The employers did their best to break
the union, and the union retaliated just as militantly. The years
which followed were among the stormiest in U.S. labor history.
Between 1934 and 1948, the West Coast had over 20 major port
strikes, more than 300 days of coastwide strikes, about 1,300 local
'job action' strikes, and about 250 arbitration awards. [
Footnote 3/8]"
During the stormy 1930's, the Federal Government was greatly
expanding its role in labor relations. The NIRA and NLRA greatly
revived unionism among both seamen and longshoremen, in addition to
workers in other industries. Those Acts guaranteed the right of
collective bargaining, and offered a means for recognition of
unions; the unions gained members and strength. And with stronger
unions, collective bargaining became more widespread. But the
explosive situation in the maritime industry was not solved by
these general enactments, and Congress passed a series of laws to
deal with the labor problems in that industry. First was the
Merchant Marine Act, 1936, 49 Stat. 1985, creating a United States
Maritime Commission to investigate conditions of seamen on ships
and to determine minimum wage scales and working conditions on
vessels that were receiving government
Page 390 U. S. 300
subsidies. Despite the 1936 Act, labor relations did not improve
significantly, and Congress, in 1938, amended the Act, creating a
Maritime Labor Board (MLB) with the duty of encouraging collective
bargaining and assisting in the peaceful settlement of labor
disputes through mediation. A provision of the 1938 amendment,
§ 1005, 52 Stat. 967, required all maritime employers to file
with the MLB within 30 days a copy of every contract with any group
of its employees covering wages, hours, rules, and working
conditions. Any new contract or change in an existing contract also
had to be filed with the Board. The contracts did not require
approval by the Board, but were to be used to assist the Board in
its mediation activities and in its promotion of peaceful
settlement of labor disputes. [
Footnote
3/9]
The Board was instructed in the 1938 Act to submit to Congress
by 1940 its recommendations for establishing a permanent federal
maritime labor policy ensuring stable labor relations. The Board,
in its 1940 report, concluded that conditions in the industry were
still uneasy, and recommended a permanent federal body with wide
jurisdiction over questions of maritime labor -- including
representation [
Footnote 3/10]
and settlement of disputes.
Page 390 U. S. 301
The 1938 Act provided that the Board was to be discontinued in
1941; but, in 1940, Congress extended its life until mid-1942 to
permit further studies by he Board and Congress. Nothing more was
done until 1955, when Congress again turned its attention
specifically to the problems of maritime labor relations. [
Footnote 3/11] In the meantime, the MLB
had expired. Although several bills were introduced providing for
specialized federal control over maritime labor relations, no
special machinery was established, and the maritime industry
remains subject to the various provisions of federal labor laws.
[
Footnote 3/12]
In 1948, another general maritime strike rocked the Pacific
Coast. Following that strike, which lasted about 100 days, there
was a "period of relative calm." [
Footnote 3/13] The 1948 strike had led to a change in
employer leadership, a less hostile attitude on the part of the
union leadership,
Page 390 U. S. 302
and a consequent lessening of tension along the Pacific Coast.
Both sides recognized that the reduction of strife was desirable,
since a substantial amount of traffic had been diverted from the
Pacific Coast to other ports or to other means of transportation on
account of chronic maritime labor difficulties and work stoppages.
But, despite the reduction in hostility between labor and
management, solutions to problems were not readily forthcoming.
Business was bad for the shipping companies -- foreign competitors
had cut heavily into the market, and a decline in business meant
less work for both seamen and longshoremen. Modernization was
sorely needed, but it was also greatly feared, for mechanization
would cut out jobs. But without improved techniques and facilities,
the employers could not regain a strong competitive position.
[
Footnote 3/14] In addition to
lack of modern
Page 390 U. S. 303
equipment, employers were further hampered by highly restrictive
work rules that had been in effect since the 1930's, such as
multiple handling, [
Footnote
3/15] sling-load weight, [
Footnote 3/16] and gang-size restrictions. [
Footnote 3/17]
Page 390 U. S. 304
It is only against this background of chronic strikes and
restrictive labor practices that the tremendous impact of the Mech
Fund can be appreciated. That was the heart of the 1960-1961
settlement. As noted by one commentator intimately acquainted with
the negotiations of the parties, "[t]his agreement did not spring
full-blown from the brow of Zeus, or from the brain of Bridges."
[
Footnote 3/18] Rather,
"[t]he agreement, which was hammered out in 5 months of
negotiations ending in October, 1960, culminated 4 years of
discussion between the PMA and the ILWU. [
Footnote 3/19]"
Earnest bargaining began in 1957. PMA wanted to obtain a
guarantee from the ILWU that strikes and work stoppages would not
result from the introduction and use of mechanization and other
labor-saving devices. In return, the union wanted its workers to
share in the cost savings resulting from modernization, and desired
assurances that changes in work methods would neither create unsafe
working conditions nor accelerate the productivity required of
individual workers. After two years of preliminary negotiations, an
agreement was made in August, 1959, which provided for a further
study of the problems of mechanization and for the establishment by
PMA of a fund of $1,500,000 for the benefit of union workers.
[
Footnote 3/20]
Negotiations beginning in May, 1960, led to a "Memorandum of
Agreement on Mechanization and Modernization,"
Page 390 U. S. 305
concluded in October, 1960, and providing for a $29,000,000
trust fund to be financed by PMA. The fund was to consist of the
$1,500,000 due under the 1959 agreement plus another $27,500,000 to
be accumulated over a five-and-one-half-year period at the rate of
$5,000,000 per year. The fund was to be used to protect
longshoremen and marine clerks from the consequences of reduced
employment caused by mechanization. The agreement was to enter into
force upon approval by the members of PMA and the ILWU, and was to
expire on July 1, 1966. [
Footnote
3/21] The agreement also provided management with the
relatively free rein it had sought to eliminate restrictive work
practices. The former practice of multiple handling was eliminated,
and the minimum size of a gang for loading and unloading operations
was specified. The sling-load limit for loads was to remain
unchanged if the manner of operation was the same as when the limit
was first negotiated; otherwise, the employer could set the weight,
provided that he acted "within
Page 390 U. S. 306
safe and practical limits and without speed up of the
individual."
Thus, the agreement satisfied the desire of employers to
modernize and eliminate outmoded and restrictive work rules, and at
the same time provided a measure of security for the workers whose
jobs would be affected by the use of the new devices. The
agreement, however, left open the question of how the employers'
contributions of $5,000,000 a year would be raised. The question of
a proper method of assessment had been discussed by the union and
management during the preceding negotiations; several suggestions
were offered by the parties. But, in return for a commitment from
the PMA members obligating themselves individually and collectively
to the payment of the fund, the ILWU agreed to permit PMA to
establish the method of payment.
PMA then set up a Work Improvement Fund Committee to determine
the best method of raising the money. That Committee considered
various bases for assessing contributions -- man-hours of each
employer, cargo tonnage, a combination of the two, cargo tonnage
moving in containers, measurement of improvements in longshore
productivity. The Committee majority recommended a cargo tonnage
basis; its reasons for doing so were summarized by the court below
as follows:
"The Committee recommended a formula based on cargo tonnage as a
'rough-and-ready' way to divide the cost, admittedly lacking the
refinement of the productivity measurement method, but also lacking
its infeasibility and avoiding the inequity of the man-hour method
whereby contributions are in inverse proportion to benefits
received. It considered that cargo volume, though not necessarily
proportional, was some indicator of stevedoring activities, and
that administrative simplicity was a cardinal consideration. "
Page 390 U. S. 307
"The Committee recognized further that there were also
objectionable features of the tonnage formula, but considered these
to be less weighty than the objections inhering in the other
formulae. It recommended that the formula be reviewed to prevent
the continuation of any hardship or inequity that might develop.
[
Footnote 3/22]"
In recommending the tonnage formula, the Committee noted that
the same system was used for assessing a part of PMA dues. It had
also been the practice of PMA to use a tonnage formula for
assessments allocating other types of labor costs, such as joint
maintenance of dispatch halls and the payment of arbitrators'
salaries. [
Footnote 3/23] In
fact, it appears that the ILWU had itself proposed a tonnage
formula during the negotiations and asked that it be incorporated
into the collective bargaining agreement; but PMA resisted this
approach, apparently wishing to keep its options open and fearing
that incorporation in the agreement might tend to commit the PMA to
a fixed formula that would also be included in a future agreement.
The tonnage formula recommended by the Committee was subsequently
adopted by the PMA membership.
It was specifically provided in the agreement that each employer
would abide by the formula adopted by the
Page 390 U. S. 308
Association, and this promise to comply was the
quid pro
quo for the union's agreement not to write any particular
formula into the contract or take part in the determination of the
method of assessment. [
Footnote
3/24] Thus, the PMA decision on the method of assessment was
part and parcel of the collective bargaining agreement. Indeed,
the
Page 390 U. S. 309
modernization plan was the heart of that agreement, and the
subsequent assessment plan merely implemented the employers' duty
under the collective bargaining agreement to establish a fund
specifically marked to protect maritime workers against the
far-reaching effects of modernization.
PMA treated the financing of the fund as an integral part of the
collective bargaining process. The Committee established by PMA to
recommend a funding formula was appointed by the negotiating
committee which worked on the collective bargaining agreement;
[
Footnote 3/25] and the PMA
membership ratified both the collective bargaining agreement and
the funding formula at the same time.
It is not, I submit, possible, as a practical matter, to
separate the Mech Fund provision in the collective bargaining
agreement from the subsequent decision of
Page 390 U. S. 310
the PMA membership concerning how the fund was to be raised. A
collective bargaining agreement is the product of negotiations. How
can negotiators sitting at a table arrive at an agreement if they
know that a major part of it depends on the approval of the Federal
Maritime Commission? How many months -- or years -- will it take to
get approval? What will happen meanwhile? Will not the imposition
of that kind of administrative supervision bring an end to, or at
least partially paralyze, collective bargaining?
The Mech Fund is a labor expense. Increased labor costs normally
are passed on at least in part by increased prices. When the Auto
Workers were recently negotiating with General Motors for a
guaranteed annual wage, what would have been the consequence if
nothing could have been decided until a federal agency had
determined whether the impact on prices or on the economy was
proper? I can imagine a regime of total controls where such prior
approval would be required. But we have no such regime at present,
and I can see no possible justification for a judicially created
one in the explosive maritime field. To meet the costs increased by
any collective bargaining agreement, a company might have to raise
its prices and pass at least part of the added cost on to the
consumer. But this happens all the time in the maritime industry,
as well as in other industries, and does not constitute rate fixing
of the type at which the Shipping Act is aimed. There is nothing in
the legislative history of the Shipping Act which suggests that
§ 15 gives the FMC the power or license to oversee labor
negotiations. But that is the effect of what the Court does today
when it decides that the employers' agreement here must be
submitted to that body for approval.
My Brother HARLAN suggests that the assessment agreement can be
distinguished from the collective bargaining agreement because
"[t]he union was concerned
Page 390 U. S. 311
that the question [of how the cost burden of the fund was to be
allocated] receive some answer, but had no proper interest in which
of the possible cost allocation plans was adopted. . . ."
(
Ante at
390 U. S.
290.) But to argue that the union does not care from
what source the PMA gets the money for the fund is both
questionable [
Footnote 3/26] and
irrelevant, for such an approach ignores the fact that there are
two parties to a collective bargaining agreement. The PMA members
do care how they will be assessed $27,500,000 for a fund dedicated
to the benefit of their employees. The Mech Fund was the key
provision in the agreement, and, without it, there may well have
been no agreement at all. The parties should not be expected to
wait to settle their differences while the FMC decides under §
15 whether the employers' funding plan is in the public interest.
Speedy resolution of labor disputes by collective bargaining has
been the consistent federal policy.
The Solicitor General would have us atomize the collective
bargaining agreement and treat the schedule of charges that create
the fund as a mere "side agreement." But without the so-called
"side agreement," there would have been no collective bargaining
agreement. And it must be remembered that § 15, if applicable,
requires that an agreement be filed "immediately with the
Commission." What would have to be filed is the entire agreement,
not merely the proviso to which petitioner now objects. The
Commission then must give notice and a hearing and "disapprove,
cancel or modify" the agreement. Which persons would be entitled to
participate in the hearing presents an initial problem. [
Footnote 3/27] Thereafter, what
provisions would become the target in the hearing
Page 390 U. S. 312
is conjectural. The target might be small or large. But
certainly no collective bargaining agreement could become operative
until its underpinning -- the fund -- was thoroughly litigated.
Meanwhile, years might pass as the contest wound its way slowly
through various tribunals and the labor problems continued to
fester.
This is what my Brother HARLAN overlooks when he suggests that
advance approval of "labor-related agreements" might be more
desirable from the standpoint of facilitating collective bargaining
than leaving open the question whether the agreement, or parts of
it, would be subject to the antitrust laws. Presumably, he means
that legal uncertainty concerning the possible vulnerability of
certain provisions of an agreement to attack under the antitrust
laws might stall negotiations or lead some association members to
decline to cooperate in carrying out the agreement, fearing a
treble damage action. To be sure, the parties to a collective
bargaining pact must frame their agreement to fit within the
standards of the antitrust laws or any other governing statutes.
But without a requirement of advance approval of the terms of the
agreement, they remain free to bargain speedily. Frustration of the
collective bargaining process comes not so much from the
possibility that one or more provisions in a collective bargaining
pact might be found illegal at some future date under the antitrust
laws, or other statutes such as §§ 16 and 17 of the
Shipping Act, but rather from the undue and possibly lengthy
freezing or stultification of solutions to troublesome labor
problems while an intimate part of the proposed agreement is sent
to the FMC for approval.
With all respect, the Court's approach in requiring the funding
plan to be submitted to the FMC for approval under § 15 of the
Shipping Act will frustrate legitimate and speedy collective
bargaining in the maritime industry.
Page 390 U. S. 313
Neither the Court nor my Brother HARLAN is able to refer to any
legislative history which indicates that Congress considered the
Shipping Act to require the filing of labor agreements or
provisions of those agreements under § 15. [
Footnote 3/28] The Court instead takes the
approach that the Shipping Act provisions were purposely drawn
broad enough to encompass association agreements which have more
than a
de minimis effect on commerce. This rationale would
require the filing of any collective bargaining provision agreed to
by PMA members that raised labor costs beyond the point at which
PMA members could be expected to absorb those costs without raising
prices or charges.
The Court may well mean, as my Brother HARLAN suggests, that the
"obligation to collect the Mech Fund," contained in the collective
bargaining agreement, is not to be examined by the Commission on
remand, but rather the question is to be limited to the "propriety
of the choice of the route to that objective." But that misses the
mark. My point is that the latter question is as much a part of the
bargaining process as the former. Commission control over either
question runs substantial risk of frustrating agreement by the
parties on both issues, not to mention other matters in the
collective bargaining pact. For example, if an allocation formula
satisfactory to PMA members and to the Commission could not be
devised, the fund might never be established, requiring perhaps
other changes in the agreement, such as higher wages or continuance
of some or all of the restrictive work rules.
If the present practice is an abuse, there is an existing
remedy. This agreement between employers could, of
Page 390 U. S. 314
course, be challenged in the courts as violative of the
antitrust laws. [
Footnote 3/29]
Moreover, §§ 16 and 17 of the Shipping Act afford
protection to foreign commerce in cases of undue discrimination or
unreasonable practices affecting that commerce. While I cannot say
that the Commission erred in finding no violation of § 16, I
concur in a remand to the Commission for further findings under
§ 17. [
Footnote 3/30]
Page 390 U. S. 315
If the finding is for petitioner, there may be an incidental and
after-the-fact effect on the provisions of the collective
bargaining agreement. But it will not produce
Page 390 U. S. 316
the paralyzing effect which will follow when prior approval is
required. The application of §§ 16 and 17 in particular
instances can indeed realistically be compared with enforcement of
federal antitrust laws directed against specific practices.
[
Footnote 3/1]
Section 15 provides, in relevant part, that every person subject
to the Shipping Act "shall file immediately with the Commission"
every agreement with another person subject to the Act
"fixing or regulating transportation rates or fares; giving or
receiving special rates, accommodations, or other special
privileges or advantages; controlling, regulating, preventing, or
destroying competition; pooling or apportioning earnings, losses,
or traffic; allotting ports or restricting or otherwise regulating
the number and character of sailings between ports; limiting or
regulating in any way the volume or character of freight or
passenger traffic to be carried; or in any manner providing for an
exclusive, preferential, or cooperative working arrangement."
46 U.S.C. § 814 (§ 15).
The Commission is instructed in § 15 to "disapprove, cancel
or modify any agreement" which it finds, after notice and hearing,
to be
"unjustly discriminatory or unfair as between carriers,
shippers, exporters, importers, or ports, or between exporters from
the United States and their foreign competitors, or to operate to
the detriment of the commerce of the United States, or to be
contrary to the public interest, or to be in violation of this
chapter. . . ."
Any agreement which is not approved, or which is disapproved, by
the Commission is declared by § 15 to be "unlawful." And it is
also provided that, "before approval or after disapproval, it shall
be unlawful to carry out in whole or in part, directly or
indirectly, any such agreement. . . ."
[
Footnote 3/2]
Those sections read, in relevant part:
"It shall be unlawful for any . . . person subject to this
chapter, either alone or in conjunction with any other person,
directly or indirectly . . . to subject any particular person,
locality, or description of traffic to any undue or unreasonable
prejudice or disadvantage in any respect whatsoever. . . ."
46 U.S.C. § 815 (§ 16).
"Every . . . person subject to this chapter shall establish,
observe, and enforce just and reasonable regulations and practices
relating to or connected with the receiving, handling, storing, or
delivering of property. Whenever the Board finds that any such
regulation or practice is unjust or unreasonable it may determine,
prescribe, and order enforced a just and reasonable regulation or
practice."
46 U.S.C. § 816 (§ 17).
[
Footnote 3/3]
For a comprehensive study of the history of labor relations in
the maritime industry up to 1940,
see Maritime Labor
Board, Report to the President and to the Congress, H.R. DOC. No.
646, 76th Cong., 3d Sess. (1940). For a valuable history of
maritime labor relations on the West Coast,
see B.
Schneider, Industrial Relations in the West Coast Maritime
Industry, Institute of Industrial Relations, University of
California (Berkeley, 1958).
[
Footnote 3/4]
Longshoremen and seamen depend, of course, on the amount of work
to be done. If business is bad, the workers are without work, and
without pay. With respect to longshoremen on the Pacific Coast,
hiring is done through hiring halls operated jointly by the union
and management. Employers can obtain longshoremen only through
these halls, and only for specific jobs. No longshoreman may be
employed steadily by any one employer; rather, each is dispatched
to an employer as part of a gang to perform a specific loading or
unloading job.
See Kossoris, Working Rules in West Coast
Longshoring, 84 Monthly Labor Rev. 1 (1961), for an account of the
hiring practice on the West Coast.
[
Footnote 3/5]
This Act was the direct result of the Alexander Report of 1914.
House Committee on Merchant Marine and Fisheries, H.R. DOC. No.
805, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. (1914).
[
Footnote 3/6]
In that strike, the International Longshoremen's Association
demanded wage increases, a six-hour day, a closed shop, and union
control of hiring halls. The employers refused to accede to these
demands, and the ensuing strike tied up shipping for almost three
months at all Pacific ports. President Roosevelt appointed a
National Longshoremen's Board to intervene, after a mediation board
had failed to settle the dispute. The union and management agreed
to submit to arbitration by the Board, and to end the strike while
arbitration was proceeding. Both sides agreed to abide by the
Board's decision. The arbitration proceedings took several months,
and the award which was eventually rendered represented substantial
gains for the union. Hiring halls were to be operated jointly, wage
increases were granted, and a six-hour day established. In
addition, port labor relations committees were established on which
both employers and the union were represented equally, and all
issues not decided by those committees were to be submitted to
arbitration.
[
Footnote 3/7]
Killingsworth, The Modernization of West Coast Longshore Work
Rules, 15 Ind. & Lab.Rel.Rev. 295, 296 (1962).
[
Footnote 3/8]
Kossoris,
supra, 390
U.S. 261fn3/4|>n. 4, at 1.
[
Footnote 3/9]
It was noted in a 1941 House Committee Report on a bill
providing for a two-year extension of the MLB that the MLB was
the
"only Government agency with which copies of all labor
agreements are required to be filed, and these have been studied by
the Board with a view to promoting stable labor relations in the
maritime industry."
House Committee on Merchant Marine and Fisheries, Two-Year
Extension of the Maritime Labor Board, H.R.Rep. No. 354, 77th
Cong., 1st Sess., 2 (1941).
[
Footnote 3/10]
Under the 1938 Act, questions of representation were reserved to
the NLRB. Section 1002 of the Merchant Marine Act, as amended,
provided that:
"The provisions of this title shall not in any manner affect or
be construed to limit the provisions of the National Labor
Relations Act, nor shall any of the unfair labor practices listed
therein be considered a dispute for the purposes of this title.
Questions concerning the representation of employees of a maritime
employer shall be considered and determined by the National Labor
Relations Board in accordance with the provisions of the National
Labor Relations Act:
Provided, however, That nothing in
this title shall constitute a repeal or otherwise affect the
enforcement of any of the navigation laws of the United States or
any other laws relating to seamen."
52 Stat. 965.
[
Footnote 3/11]
Hearings on H.R. 5734, before the House Committee on Merchant
Marine and Fisheries, 84th Cong., 1st and 2d Sess. (19551956).
[
Footnote 3/12]
See, e.g., Hanna Mining Co. v. Marine Engineers,
382 U. S. 181
(preemption of state law by federal labor enactments);
McCulloch v. Sociedad Nacional, 372 U. S.
10 (jurisdiction of NLRB over employees of foreign-flag
ships);
Marine Engineers v. Interlake S.S. Co.,
370 U. S. 173
(preemption);
Marine Cooks v. Panama S.S. Co.,
362 U. S. 365
(application of Norris-LaGuardia Act);
Benz v. Compania Naviera
Hidalgo, 353 U. S. 138
(application of Labor Management Relations Act to disputes between
maritime employees and foreign ships);
Longshoremen v. Juneau
Spruce Corp., 342 U. S. 237
(right of action by employer against union under § 303(a)(4)
of L.M.R.A.);
NLRB v. Pittsburgh S.S. Co., 337 U.
S. 656 (unfair labor practice);
Southern S.S. Co. v.
NLRB, 316 U. S. 31
(representation; refusal to bargain);
NLRB v. Waterman S.S.
Corp., 309 U. S. 206
(unfair labor practice).
[
Footnote 3/13]
Kossoris,
supra, 390
U.S. 261fn3/4|>n. 4, at 2.
[
Footnote 3/14]
As one commentator noted in 1961:
"The longshore industry is technologically among the most
backward. An industrial engineer from any one of the mass
production industries would be horrified to find sacks of coffee on
the San Francisco docks being handled just as they have been
handled since sailing ship days. No one of the many separate
corporate links in the transportation chain has sufficient interest
in greater efficiency to force the changes in coffee handling
methods, for example, which, to be effective, must start in Brazil
and be carried right through to Hills Brothers or Folgers in San
Francisco."
Fairley, The ILWU-PMA Mechanization and Modernization Agreement,
12 Lab.L.J. 664, 665 (1961).
The first big change in technology along the docks, notes Mr.
Fairley, was the use of lift trucks, propelled by wartime demands
for greater efficiency during World War II. Since that time, new
methods of bulk handling of cargo have been developed, and unit
loads have been increasingly used (such as those made by gluing
items together or strapping them together or containerizing them).
Id. at 666. One of the most efficient operations of
containerization has been used by the Matson Navigation Co. In
August, 1964, that company cut its rates by nearly 10%, citing cost
reductions made possible by a ship improvement and
"containerization" plan. The plan relates to container cargo, where
the containers are boxes holding up to 40 tons of freight. They are
loaded at a factory or distribution point and lifted aboard a ship
and unloaded as single units. Matson Co. reported that it took
about 850 man-hours to load and unload a specially designed
container ship carrying 6,500 tons using mechanized equipment. The
same cargo carried in conventional loose form would take 11,000
man-hours (about 13 times as much labor) to load and unload. An
added attraction of this saving in time is the fact that ships get
in and out of port faster, providing additional cost savings. For
example, Matson's container ships stay in port less than a day,
compared with five days for a conventional ship. Shippers estimate
that it cost in 1964 about $3,000 to $5,000 for such things as
depreciation, seamen's wages and pier charges for each day a ship
stays in port. The Wall Street Journal, Nov. 20, 1964, at 8, col.
2. For a more thorough consideration of the changes in technology
that promise great benefits for the shipping industry,
see
the comprehensive eight-volume study of the United States
Department of Labor, Manpower Utilization, Job Security in the
Longshore Industry (1964).
See also Shils, Industrial
Unrest in the Nation's Maritime Industry, 15 Lab.L.J. 337, 356-358
(where the author notes improvements in construction of vessels,
the use of highly mechanized cargo ships, changes in engine room
operation, in the Deck Department and in the Steward Department,
and a new line of semi-automated vessels); O. Hagel & L.
Goldblatt, Men and Machines, Joint Publication of the I.L.W.U. and
P.M.A. (San Francisco, 1963).
[
Footnote 3/15]
Multiple handling refers to the labor practice requiring the
cargo to touch the "skin of the dock" after being unloaded before
someone other than a longshoreman can handle it. For loading of
cargo, only the longshoreman can place it on the ship after a
teamster has unloaded it from his truck onto the dock. Kossoris,
supra, 390
U.S. 261fn3/4|>n. 4, at 2.
[
Footnote 3/16]
Sling-load weight is the weight limit for a load of cargo. In
1961, the maximum weight was usually about 2,100 pounds per pallet
(although much heavier loads apparently could have been carried
safely). Larger pallets were "skimmed down" to 2,100 pounds by
longshoremen.
Ibid.
[
Footnote 3/17]
Each major port would have its own rules stipulating the number
of men needed on gangs. Frequently, the number was more than was
needed for the job. For example, the "four-on four-off" gang
required eight men in the hold of a ship, although only four
actually worked while the other four rested.
Id. at 3.
See generally Killingsworth,
supra, 390
U.S. 261fn3/7|>n. 7; P. Hartman, Union Work Rules: A Brief
Theoretical Analysis and Some Empirical Results, U. of Ill.Bull.,
Institute of Labor & Industrial Relations (1967).
[
Footnote 3/18]
Fairley,
supra, 390
U.S. 261fn3/14|>n. 14, at 666.
[
Footnote 3/19]
Kossoris,
supra, n.
390
U.S. 261fn3/4|>4, at 1.
[
Footnote 3/20]
Although the method of raising this amount of money was not
specified in the agreement, PMA accumulated the fund by assessing
its members under a man-hour formula.
[
Footnote 3/21]
In August, 1966, a new agreement was signed which continued the
Mech Fund until 1971; but this time, the employers agreed to pay
even more into the fund each year -- $6,900,000. Both the union and
the employers were highly satisfied with the way the plan had
worked. For a general description of the 1966 contract,
see Business Week, July 30, 1966, at 108; Kossoris, 1966
West Coast Longshore Negotiations, 89 Monthly Labor Rev. 1067.
Kossoris points out the great effect which abolition of restrictive
work practices and increased use of modern technology had had for
the employers:
"Tonnage increased by about 32 percent, but man-hours remained
about the same. Despite an increase over the period of 56 cents in
the basic wage and liberalization of fringe benefits, including the
$5 million the employers paid into the fund, the cost per ton
dropped from $6.26 to $6.16. . . . Making allowance for all
important factors involved, the gain to employers from the M&M
agreement may be placed conservatively as well in excess of $150
million. Subtracting from this the $27.5 million paid into the
M&M fund over the 5 1/2-year period of the last contract makes
the employer estimate of $120 million net gain appear
realistic."
Id. at 1068-1069.
[
Footnote 3/22]
125 U.S.App.D.C. 282, 293, 371 F.2d 747, 758 (1967).
[
Footnote 3/23]
We are told that this is not the first time that PMA members
have entered into agreements among themselves to form and finance
their collective bargaining agreements. They have agreed to the
presentation of uniform bargaining terms, and have provided,
through agreements among themselves, for the administration and
implementation of their union contracts. All of these would affect
transportation rates. In essence, such agreements, no less than the
funding method employed by PMA, have established uniform costs for
all employers of maritime labor -- indeed, the primary object of
industry-wide bargaining has been to establish uniform wages,
fringe benefits, and working conditions.
[
Footnote 3/24]
Mr. Paul St. Sure, President of PMA, testified:
"It [the method of payment of the fund] was a definite part of
the negotiations in that the union took a position with regard to
the method of collection. PMA took a position with regard to the
method of collection. There were discussions with the union during
negotiation as to the problems that had been presented by the
method of collection used with relation to the million dollars and
a half."
"We discussed with the union the differences of opinion among
our own members as to the equitable method of providing for the
collection of this money."
"We ended up with an agreement by the union that, inasmuch as
the employer members of the bargaining unit had committed
themselves specifically to the payment of the sum, that, whereas
they were interested in the assurance that the sum would be
collected, they would allow us to work out among ourselves the
method of actual collection within the membership of PMA."
Such action, however, did not make the union a disinterested
party; rather, the union certainly had a continuing interest in the
method of financing the fund. Mr. St. Sure, who was deeply involved
since 1948 in negotiations with the ILWU, testified:
"There was a continuing interest and a continuing concern as to
whether or not the collections under the fund were being met.
Obviously they have, by joint trusteeship, joint custody of the
fund, and I can assure you that they were alert as to whether or
not the method of the custody was working, because they believed
this and, in fact, knew it was their money to spend in accordance
with the agreement."
"
* * * *"
"After all, this was a continuing relationship that we have, by
the collective bargaining agreement, and my experience would
suggest to me that we couldn't have adopted the method which would
defeat the very purpose for which we had reached a bargain without
having further negotiations."
The Hearing Examiner stated in his opinion that
"Mr. St. Sure testified that the ILWU's interest in the method
to be adopted, ceased after it was agreed that the method of
collection was to be reserved to PMA."
In the printed record before the Court, however, I find no
reference in Mr. St. Sure's testimony to a lack of interest on the
part of the union concerning the method of collection of the fund.
The Hearing Examiner does not indicate the testimony on which his
interpretation of Mr. St. Sure's presentation is based; and, at the
least, that part of his testimony quoted would appear to raise a
strong doubt whether it could be said that the interest of the
union ceased. In any event, it is clear from Mr St. Sure's
testimony that the method of collection was a prime topic of
negotiations between the parties, and that the employers' decision
on the matter was intimately tied with the collective bargaining
agreement.
[
Footnote 3/25]
Mr. St. Sure testified:
"Well, this was still part of the bargaining process. We were
still actually trying to conclude the bargain which we had
developed and had signed a memorandum to cover. We still had the
responsibility as a negotiating committee of reporting back to the
board of directors, and then to the membership, and this was simply
a convenient means of calling in some men that we felt were more
expert in this field than the negotiators were who were operating
people to make a recommendation as to a method of payment."
[
Footnote 3/26]
See 390
U.S. 261fn3/24|>n. 24,
supra.
[
Footnote 3/27]
See FMC Rule 5(1), 46 CFR § 502.72 (petitions for
intervention in FMC proceedings).
See also FMC Rule 10(c),
46 CFR § 502.143 (notice of hearings).
[
Footnote 3/28]
Indeed, the legislative history would appear to be to the
contrary.
See 390
U.S. 261fn3/9|>n. 9,
supra.
[
Footnote 3/29]
The circumstance that the funding plan originated in collective
bargaining and was a part of a collective bargaining agreement
would not automatically create an exemption from the antitrust
laws.
See Mine Workers v. Pennington, 381 U.
S. 657;
Meat Cutters v. Jewel Tea, 381 U.
S. 676;
Allen Bradley Co. v. Union,
325 U. S. 797.
[
Footnote 3/30]
The Commission held under § 16 that that section is
violated only if there is discrimination between competitors, which
was not the situation here, because the marine terminal companies
have imposed no higher charges on Volkswagens than on other
automobiles. Although such an interpretation is supported by the
construction placed on § 3(1) of the Interstate Commerce Act,
49 U.S.C. § 3(1),
United States v. Great Northern R.
Co., 301 I.C.C. 21, 26-27, on which § 16 of the Shipping
Act is modeled,
United States Nav. Co. v. Cunard S.S. Co.,
284 U. S. 474,
284 U. S.
480-481, it has been suggested that the Commission has
undermined its own rule by not requiring a competitive relationship
in cases not involving freight rates:
Investigation of Free
Time Practices -- Port of San Diego, 9 F.M.C. 525 (1966) (port
free time);
New York Foreign Freight Forwarders and Brokers
Assn. v. FMC, 337 F.2d 289 (C.A.2d Cir.1964),
cert.
denied, 380 U.S. 910 (billing methods of freight forwarders);
Swift & Co. v. Gulf & South Atlantic Havana
Conference, 6 F.M.B. 215 (1961) (route restrictions);
Storage Practices at Longview, Washington, 6 F.M.B. 178
(1960) (storage charges). Moreover, it is argued that the
competitive relationship test employed by the ICC under § 3(1)
of the Interstate Commerce Act is not "an indispensable element in
a situation of undue prejudice and preference. . . ."
Joseph A.
Goddard Realty Co. v. New York, C. & St. L.R. Co., 229
I.C.C. 497, 501. The Maritime Commission's refusal to require a
competitive relationship in certain cases, however, has diluted
that principle only in those situations in which there are services
that are not dependent upon the nature of the cargo and the various
charges therefor. In the instant case, however, there are different
charges levied depending upon the nature of the cargo involved.
Petitioner conceded before the Hearing Examiner that
"[w]e do not claim that the measurement formula, 'regardless of
how manifested,' subjects Volkswagen automobiles to 'prejudice or
disadvantage' as compared to other automobiles, and we admit that
there is no other cargo classification in competition with
automobiles."
The competitive relationship rule has been applied consistently
by the Commission in appropriate circumstances. The same rule has
also been used by the ICC. Since I cannot say in the circumstances
of this case that the requirement of a competitive relationship is
unreasonable or inconsistent with the provisions of the Shipping
Act, I would defer to the Commission's expertise.
Consolo v.
FMC, 383 U. S. 607.
With respect to § 17, the Commission expressly noted that
(1) the measurement basis for assessing automobiles resulted in an
assessment almost 10 times greater than a weight basis ($2.35 per
vehicle as against approximately $0.25); (2) that, although other
cargo was assessed as manifested, vehicles were always assessed on
a measurement basis, and (3) while automobile cargo would probably
receive only general benefits from the mechanization plan (such as
freedom from strikes and slowdowns), such cargo, unlike some other
cargo, was unlikely to benefit from technological improvements in
loading and unloading. Yet the Commission held that the difference
in treatment was not unreasonable, because, although automobile
cargo may not have benefited as much as other cargo, it did receive
"substantial benefits" from the mechanization agreement. As the
Court holds, however, such a standard, which focuses on only the
benefits received, represents too narrow a view of § 17. What
petitioner is contesting essentially is PMA's decision to adopt as
the revenue ton for automobiles not a weight ton (2,000 pounds),
but a measurement ton expressed in volumetric terms (40 cubic
feet/ton). Since the average Volkswagen weighs only 1,800 pounds,
but measures about 8.7 tons on a volume basis, it is being assessed
$2.35, compared with the $0.25 it would otherwise have to pay on
the basis of a weight-ton measurement. It is argued that this
exaction is grossly disproportionate in light of the limited
benefits which petitioner could expect to receive from the
mechanization agreement as compared with those which other shippers
could anticipate. To focus an inquiry solely on the benefits
received may obscure the disparity between the charges ultimately
falling upon petitioner and those exacted from other shippers. The
Commission should compare the benefits received with the charges
imposed on petitioner's cargo and with those levied upon other
cargo, which receives substantially similar benefits, before the
question of reasonableness can be resolved. This determination is
for the Commission to make in the first instance.