Petitioner brought a treble damage Clayton Act suit for alleged
violations by respondent of §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman
Act. The District Court granted a directed verdict for respondent.
The Court of Appeals reversed as to the § 2 complaint, but
affirmed the dismissal of the § 1 charge, holding that Sunkist
qualified as a cooperative organization under the Capper-Volstead
Act, and thus could not be held for an intra-organizational
conspiracy to restrain trade. Section 1 of that Act privileges
collective activity in processing and marketing for "persons
engaged in the production of agricultural products as farmers,
planters, ranchmen, dairymen, nut or fruit growers. . . ." Sunkist,
which controls approximately 70% of the oranges grown in California
and Arizona, and approximately 67% of the "product" oranges (used
for processing), is composed of about 12,000 citrus growers, who
are organized into 160 local associations, of which 80% are
cooperative associations in which all members are growers. However,
about 15% of the local associations, called "agency associations,"
are private corporations or partnerships owning and operating
packing houses for profit. They have marketing contracts with
growers to handle fruit for cost plus a fixed fee. All the local
associations participate in the control and policy making of
Sunkist.
Held: Respondent is not entitled to assert the
Capper-Volstead Act as a defense to the suit based on § 1 of
the Sherman Act, as it was not the intention of Congress to allow
an organization with such nonproducer interests to avail itself of
the exemption provided by that Act. Pp.
389 U. S.
390-396.
369 F.2d 449, reversed and remanded.
Page 389 U. S. 385
MR. JUSTICE MARSHALL delivered the opinion of the Court.
This is a treble damage action under § 4 of the Clayton
Act, 38 Stat. 731, 15 U.S.C. § 15, for alleged violations of
both § 1 and § 2 of the Sherman Act, 26 Stat. 209, as
amended, 15 U.S.C. §§ 1, 2. The District Court granted a
directed verdict, at the close of plaintiff' case, for the
defendant, Sunkist Growers, Inc. The Court of Appeals for the Ninth
Circuit reversed as to that portion of the complaint predicated on
§ 2 of the Sherman Act, holding that sufficient evidence was
presented that Sunkist monopolized or attempted to monopolize trade
in the relevant market; [
Footnote
1] it affirmed a to the dismissal of the Sherman Act § 1
charge, holding that Sunkist qualified as a cooperative
organization under the Capper-Volstead Act, 42 Stat. 388, 7 U.S.C.
§ 291, [
Footnote 2] and
therefore could
Page 389 U. S. 386
not be held for any intra-organizational conspiracy to restrain
trade. In order to determine the scope of that exemption from the
antitrust laws, we granted certiorari. 387 U.S. 903 (1967).
The issue is whether Sunkist is an association of "[p]ersons
engaged in the production of agricultural products as . . . fruit
growers" within the meaning of the Capper-Volstead Act,
notwithstanding that certain of its members are not actually
growers. We hold that it is not.
I
The organizational structure of the Sunkist system is as
follows. At the base are some 12,000 growers of citrus fruit in
Arizona and California. The growers are organized into "local
associations," as they are designated in Sunkist's bylaws,
numbering approximately 160, each of which operates a packing house
for the preparation of the fruit for market. The vast majority of
these local associations -- about 80% by number and 82% by volume
of fruit marketed in the Sunkist system -- are, it is stipulated,
cooperative associations in which all members are fruit growers.
[
Footnote 3] A few of the local
associations
Page 389 U. S. 387
-- no more than 5% by number and volume of fruit -- are
corporate growers whose total volume is sufficient to justify
installation of their own packing house facilities.
The remainder of the local associations (also designated as
"agency associations") -- about 15% by number handling about 13% of
the fruit in the Sunkist system -- are private corporations and
partnerships, owning and operating packing houses for profit. Their
relationship to the growers whose fruit they handle is defined not
by a cooperative agreement, but by a marketing contract,
i.e., these packing houses contract with each grower to
handle his fruit for cost plus a fixed fee. It is the membership of
these agency associations in the Sunkist system that gives rise to
the issue presented here.
The local associations, including these private packing houses,
are members of "district exchanges," nonprofit membership
corporations. The principal functions of the approximately
three-score district exchanges are in the marketing of the fresh
fruit of their member associations; they negotiate sales, arrange
for shipment, and serve as conduits of communication between the
local associations and Sunkist. Representatives of the district
exchanges select the board of directors of Sunkist.
Sunkist itself, since 1958, [
Footnote 4] has two classes of "members": the district
exchanges, whose principal membership
Page 389 U. S. 388
function is to select the board of directors, and the local
associations, which vote on all other matters and which have the
proprietary ownership of Sunkist's assets. The corporate entity
Sunkist Growers, Inc., owns the trade name "Sunkist" under which
the fruit of its members is marketed. It has an extensive sales
organization; employs marketing and traffic specialists, and
performs many other services for its members through, for example,
its research facilities.
More particularly, Sunkist owns processing facilities for what
is known as "product" fruit,
i.e., fruit that for various
reasons is not sold in the fresh fruit market, but rather is used
for processed fruit products such as canned or concentrated
juices.
Sunkist controls approximately 70% of the oranges grown in
California and Arizona, and approximately 67% of the product
oranges. This control is manifested through various contractual
agreements. For example, each grower in the cooperative local
associations agrees that he will market all of his fruit through
his association. Each grower who contracts with an agency
association packing house appoints it as the marketing agent for
all of his fruit. That agreement is generally for five shipping
seasons, although it may be canceled at any time "by mutual
consent" or on written notice by the grower during August of any
year in which it is in force. An escape clause permits the grower
to sell such fruit as may be "mutually agreed upon" between him and
the packing house to others, if he can obtain a price higher, in
the judgment of the packing house, than that which the grower would
obtain through his agreement with it. Should the grower be so
released from his agree ment, he is to pay to the packing house
$2.50 per ton of fruit released.
Each of the local associations, including the private packing
house agency associations, contracts with its
Page 389 U. S. 389
district exchange and with Sunkist Growers, Inc., to market all
of its fruit -- product and fresh -- in the Sunkist system. Each
association, under the Sunkist-District Exchange-Association
Agreement, reserves the right to decide to what market it will ship
and what price it is willing to receive for its fruit; however,
Sunkist may decide to pool product fruit and fruit for export, in
which event that fruit is handled solely in Sunkist's discretion.
Sunkist also determines "the maximum amount of fresh fruit to be
marketed currently," and allocates the "opportunity to ship
equitably among Local Associations." Each local association agrees
not to release any of its growers from the marketing contract
without notifying its district exchange and Sunkist, and must
obtain the approval of both if releases total more than 5% of the
volume of the particular variety of fruit handled by the
association. Further, each district exchange and local association
agrees that "[a]ll prices, quotations and allowances shall be
issued and distributed solely by Sunkist."
Petitioner Case-Swayne manufactures single-strength orange juice
and other blended orange juices. In its complaint, insofar as
relevant to the issues here, petitioner charged that the Sunkist
system was a conspiracy in restraint of trade in violation of
§ 1 of the Sherman Act, the effect of which was to limit
sharply the supply of product citrus fruit available to petitioner
during the period covered by the complaint.
II
Section 1 of the Capper-Volstead Act (
see n 2,
supra) privileges collective
activity in processing and marketing on the part of "[p]ersons
engaged in the production of agricultural products as farmers,
planters, ranchmen, dairymen, nut or fruit growers. . . ." 42 Stat.
388, 7 U.S.C. § 291. Despite that specific language,
Sunkist
Page 389 U. S. 390
argues that Congress, in enacting the measure, intended to give
sanction to any organizational form by which the benefits of
collective marketing inured to the grower, and that, because the
agency packing houses, by charging cost plus a fixed fee [
Footnote 5] for their services, do not
participate directly in the gain or loss involved in the collective
marketing of fruit through the Sunkist system, they are, in the
Sunkist system, a privileged form of organization for the growers
who contract with them. [
Footnote
6] We think that argument misconceives the requirements of the
Act and runs counter to the relevant legislative history.
Congress enacted § 6 of the Clayton Act in response to the
urgings of those who felt the Sherman Act's prohibition against
combinations in restraint of trade might be applied to imperil the
development of cooperative endeavors,
Page 389 U. S. 391
principally unions. [
Footnote
7] That section provided that the antitrust laws were not to
be
"construed to forbid the existence and operation of labor,
agricultural, or horticultural organizations, instituted for the
purposes of mutual help, and not having capital stock or conducted
for profit,"
i.e., such organizations were not to be deemed "illegal
combinations or conspiracies in restraint of trade. . . ." 38 Stat.
731, 15 U.S.C. § 17. From the standpoint of agricultural
cooperatives, the principal defect in that exemption was that it
applied only to nonstock organizations. The Capper-Volstead Act was
intended to clarify the exemption for agricultural organizations
and to extend it to cooperatives having capital stock. [
Footnote 8]
The reports on both H.R. 13931, the predecessor bill that failed
of passage, and H.R. 2373, which became the Capper-Volstead Act,
state:
"Section 1 defines and limits the kind of associations to which
the legislation applies. These limitations are aimed to exclude
from the benefits of this legislation all but
actual
farmers and all associations not operated for the mutual help
of their members
as such producers."
(Emphasis added.) H.R.Rep. No. 24, 67th Cong., 1st Sess., 1
(1921); H.R.Rep. No. 939, 66th Cong., 2d Sess., 1 (1920). That it
was intended that only actual producers of agricultural products be
covered by the legislation is demonstrated in the debates on the
two bills,
e.g., the following
Page 389 U. S. 392
exchange involving Senator Kellogg, a principal sponsor of the
measure:
"Mr. CUMMINS. . . . Are the words 'as farmers, planters,
ranchmen, dairymen, nut or fruit growers' used to exclude all
others who may be engaged in the production of agricultural
products, or are those words merely descriptive of the general
subject?"
"Mr. KELLOGG. I think they are descriptive of the general
subject. I think 'farmers' would have covered them all."
"Mr. CUMMINS. I think the Senator does not exactly catch my
point. Take the flouring mills of Minneapolis: they are engaged, in
a broad sense, in the production of an agricultural product. The
packers are engaged, in a broad sense, in the production of an
agricultural product. The Senator does not intend by this bill to
confer upon them the privileges which the bill grants, I
assume?"
"Mr. KELLOGG. Certainly not, and I do not think a proper
construction of the bill grants them any such privileges. The bill
covers farmers, people who produce farm products of all kinds, and,
out of precaution, the descriptive words were added."
"Mr. TOWNSEND. They must be persons who produce these
things."
"Mr. KELLOGG. Yes; that has always been the understanding.
[
Footnote 9] "
Page 389 U. S. 393
To be sure, a principal concern of Congress was to prohibit the
participation in the collectivity of the predatory middleman, the
speculator who bought crops in the field and returned but a small
percentage of their eventual worth to the grower. Sunkist focuses
on the expression of that concern, urging that the agency
associations are not such predatory middlemen. That focus is wide
of the mark. We deal here with "special exceptions to a general
legislative plan,"
Allen Bradley Co. v. Local No. 3,
325 U. S. 797,
325 U. S. 809
(1945) (§ 6 of the Clayton Act), and therefore we are not
justified in expanding the Act's coverage, which otherwise appears
quite plain. The Act states those whose collective activity is
privileged under it; that enumeration is limited in quite specific
terms to producers of agricultural products. [
Footnote 10]
Nor does the proviso in § 1 -- "[t]hat such associations
are operated for the mutual benefit of the members thereof" --
broaden the earlier language. That provision, in conjunction with
the other prerequisites for qualification under the Act -- either
that each member be limited to one vote without regard to the
capital he furnished or
Page 389 U. S. 394
that dividends on capital be limited to 8%, and that dealings in
products of nonmembers be limited -- was designed to insure that
qualifying associations be truly organized and controlled by, and
for, producers. In short, Congress was aware that even
organizations of producers could serve a purpose other than the
mutual obtaining of a fair return to their members, as producers,
or be controlled by persons other than producers, and the proviso
adds a measure of insurance that such organizations do not gain the
Act's benefits. [
Footnote
11] Moreover, virtually the only mention in the legislative
history of possible participation in a Capper-Volstead cooperative
by nonproducers occurs with respect to cooperatives issuing capital
stock. [
Footnote 12]
Whatever may be the effect and significance of that recognition of
the financial stake of nonproducers in an otherwise solely producer
organization, their participation and role being narrowly
restricted by the voting and dividend prerequisites of the Act,
they are unpersuasive here. Capital participation by nonproducers
-- and that is the extent to which the debate can fairly be read as
contemplating their participation
Page 389 U. S. 395
at all [
Footnote 13] --
does not directly enlarge the market share already possessed by the
producers themselves. The participation in Sunkist of the agency
associations has precisely that effect.
Sunkist suggests that "membership" of the agency associations
has no "economic significance," relying on that provision of the
Capper-Volstead Act permitting an association to deal in the
products of nonmembers. The argument is that, if the agency packing
houses were not members of the Sunkist system, Sunkist would still
be free to handle their products. But this Court has held that the
antitrust implications of the relationship between a cooperative
association and others is governed by entirely different
standards.
"The right of . . . agricultural producers thus to unite [under
the Act] . . . cannot be deemed to authorize any combination or
conspiracy with other persons in restraint of trade that these
producers may see fit to devise."
United States v. Borden Co., 308 U.
S. 188,
308 U. S.
204-205 (1939);
accord, Maryland & Virginia Milk
Producers Assn. v. United States, 362 U.
S. 458,
362 U. S. 466
467 (1960). Moreover, the agency associations participate in the
control and policy making of Sunkist, even though they may be
private profit-making operations. [
Footnote 14] We think Congress did not intend to
allow
Page 389 U. S. 396
an organization with such nonproducer interest to avail itself
of the Capper-Volstead exemption. [
Footnote 15]
The judgment below is reversed, and the case is remanded for
further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
[
Footnote 1]
369 F.2d 49 (1966),
cert. denied, 387 U.S. 932 (1967).
See Maryland Virginia Milk Producer Assn. v. United
States, 362 U. S. 458
(1960);
Sunkist Growers, Inc. v. Winckler & Smith Citrus
Products Co., 370 U. S. 19
(1962).
[
Footnote 2]
Section 1 of the Act reads:
"Persons engaged in the production of agricultural products as
farmers, planters, ranchmen, dairymen, nut or fruit growers may act
together in associations, corporate or otherwise, with or without
capital stock, in collectively processing, preparing for market,
handling, and marketing in interstate and foreign commerce, such
products of persons so engaged. Such associations may have
marketing agencies in common, and such associations and their
members may make the necessary contracts and agreements to effect
such purposes:
Provided, however, That such associations
are operated for the mutual benefit of the members thereof, as such
producers, and conform to one or both of the following
requirements: "
"First. That no member of the association is allowed more than
one vote because of the amount of stock or membership capital he
may own therein, or,"
"Second. That the association does not pay dividends on stock or
membership capital in excess of 8 percentum per annum."
"And in any case to the following: "
"Third. That the association shall not deal in the products of
nonmembers to an amount greater in value than such as are handled
by it for members."
7 U.S.C. § 291.
[
Footnote 3]
"Limitation of membership in local associations to actual citrus
fruit producers is a cardinal principle of the Exchange
[
i.e., Sunkist] system." Gardner & McKay, California
Fruit Growers Exchange System 88 (U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, FCA
Cir. No. C-135 (1950)).
See also Cumberland, Cooperative
Marketing -- Its Advantages as Exemplified in the California Fruit
Growers Exchange 87 (1917). The corporate name of Sunkist prior to
1952 was the California Fruit Growers Exchange.
[
Footnote 4]
In 1958, approximately the midpoint of the period relevant to
this complaint, Sunkist altered its structure in two principal
respects: first, local associations became members of Sunkist
Growers directly, whereas under the old bylaws they had been
represented through the district exchanges; second, two wholly
owned corporate subsidiaries of Sunkist -- Exchange Lemon Products
Co. and Exchange Orange Products Co. -- were merged into Sunkist.
Since the parties have agreed that these changes in no way affect
the issue here, we discuss Sunkist in its post-1958 form.
[
Footnote 5]
Under the marketing contract, the agency packing house obtains
for its services "all of its costs of every kind incurred in
connection with" processing and marketing the fruit; the so-called
"fixed fee," in the contract in this record, is an amount "not in
excess of 5 cents per field box on grapefruit, 10 cents on
oranges," etc. We are not advised how that fixed fee is determined,
other than that it is the result of bargaining between the company
and the grower. It may well be that the fixed fee is dependent on
the benefits of collective marketing through Sunkist, in the
limited sense that it represents to the parties what one can charge
and the other can pay, both anticipating the return the grower may
achieve through pooling his fruit with the Sunkist organization.
The stipulation, we note, provides only that the agency
association
"does not itself participate in either the gain or loss involved
in marketing fruit through Sunkist
beyond the recovery of
its costs and fixed fee for packing."
(Emphasis added.) In our view, however, that discrepancy in the
record is not crucial to the decision here.
[
Footnote 6]
The majority below held that the issue here was resolved
sub
silentio in favor of Sunkist in
Sunkist Growers, Inc. v.
Winckler & Smith Citrus Products Co., 370 U. S.
19 (1962). But nongrower participation in Sunkist was
not pointed out, nor was the issue raised in that case; indeed, it
was conceded by the respondents there that Sunkist was a
Capper-Volstead cooperative.
[
Footnote 7]
See H.R.Rep. No. 627, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 14-16
(1914);
Allen Bradley Co. v. Local No. 3, 325 U.
S. 797 (1945).
[
Footnote 8]
The purpose and object of the limited exemption of the
Capper-Volstead Act is fully discussed in
Maryland &
Virginia Milk Producers Assn. v. United States, 362 U.
S. 458,
362 U. S.
464-468 (1960);
see also Hanna, Antitrust
Immunities of Cooperative Associations, 13 Law & Contemp. Prob.
488 (1948).
[
Footnote 9]
62 Cong.Rec. 2052 (1922).
See also 60 Cong.Rec. 369
(1920) (remarks of Senator Lenroot). It is significant that an
amendment was offered on the floor of the Senate to bring within
the bill processors of agricultural products where the grower's
return depended upon the price the processor obtained for the
finished product, reference being made to the beet sugar
manufacturer. 62 Cong.Rec. 2273 (1922). Like Sunkist's argument
here, it was stated that "the beneficiary of this [amendment] would
be the producer."
Id. at 2274. But as Senator Norris
stated in opposition to the inclusion of the processors
(
id. at 2275):
"They are not cooperators; they are not producers; it is not an
organization composed of producers who incorporate together to
handle their own products. . . ."
The amendment was rejected.
Id. at 2275, 2281.
[
Footnote 10]
See Hulbert, Legal Phases of Farmer Cooperatives 170
(U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, FCS Bull. No. 10, 1958):
"This and other language which appears in the act make it plain
that a cooperative, to come within the act, must be composed of
producers."
See also Hulbert, Legal Phases of Cooperative
Associations 45 (U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, Bull. No. 1106, 1922);
Mischler, Agricultural Cooperative Law, 30 Rocky Mt.L.Rev. 381, 385
(1958); 36 Op.Atty.Gen. 326, 339 (1930); Note, 44 Va L.Rev. 63,
69-70, 100 (1958).
[
Footnote 11]
Cf. Sheffield Farms Co., 44 F.T.C. 555 (1948);
Gold
Medal Farms, Inc., 29 F.T.C. 356 (1939).
[
Footnote 12]
E.g., 62 Cong.Rec. 2271 (1922); 60 Cong.Rec. 365
(1920).
Sunkist -- a membership, rather than stock, corporation --
points out that it, then known as the California Fruit Growers
Exchange, was favorably referred to during the debates,
see,
e.g., 62 Cong.Rec. 2052, 2267, 2271, 2277 (1922); 60 Cong.Rec.
312, 315, 360-361, 370 (1920). There is nothing to show, however,
that Congress was aware that nonproducers participated in the
marketing of fruit in the Sunkist system; in our reading of those
references, it is more likely that Congress assumed the
organization was solely of producers. For that matter, Senator
Walsh, for one, doubted that the Exchange's federation of
cooperative associations would even be encompassed by the Act (62
Cong.Rec. 2277-2278). In any event, we cannot take those remarks as
intending specific approval of Sunkist, in light of the language of
the Act and it other history.
[
Footnote 13]
It was recognized, for example, that producers who desired to
organize for collective marketing might not have, at the outset,
the necessary finances to do so, and might therefore seek capital
from nonproducers.
See 60 Cong.Rec. 365 (1920) (remarks of
Senator Walsh); 62 Cong.Rec. 2271 (1922) (same); 62 Cong.Rec. 2273
(1922) (remarks of Senator Norris).
See also Hearings on
H.R. 2373 before a Subcommittee of the Senate Judiciary Committee,
67th Cong., 1st Sess. (1921).
[
Footnote 14]
As such, the agency association's interests may in some
situations be antithetical to those of the growers with which it
has contracted. For example, Sunkist has the power to review
contracts between growers and the agency associations. Obviously,
to the extent that the agency associations are represented in the
councils of Sunkist, they in effect review their own contracts.
[
Footnote 15]
All we decide is that Sunkist Growers, Inc., is not entitled to
assert Capper-Volstead as a defense to the suit based on § 1
of the Sherman Act. We express no views on the merits of that
suit.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN, concurring in part and dissenting in
part.
I agree with the Court's holding that Congress did not intend
that nonstock organizations with nonproducer members should qualify
for the antitrust exemption conferred by § 1 of the
Capper-Volstead Act, 7 U.S.C. § 291, and that the Sunkist
system therefore is technically not a properly constituted
Capper-Volstead cooperative. However, like my Brother WHITE, I am
unable to ignore the possible effect of the Court's holding insofar
as it subjects this large agricultural organization to antitrust
liability extending far beyond the confines of this suit.
There is nothing in the record to indicate that Sunkist intended
to evade the mandate of the Capper-Volstead Act when it allowed
privately owned "agency association" packing houses to become
members of the Sunkist system. Sunkist's only apparent motive in
including the agency associations as members was to provide a
greater range of packing facilities for citrus growers who desired
to market through Sunkist. The agency associations have been an
integral part of the Sunkist system for many years. [
Footnote 2/1] Until the bringing of the
present action,
Page 389 U. S. 397
this aspect of Sunkist's organization had apparently gone
without challenge from private persons who dealt with Sunkist. Its
legality never seems to have been questioned by any agency of
government. Sunkist argued before us, without challenge to its
sincerity, that the membership of the agency associations did not
deprive it of antitrust immunity so long as all of its actions were
taken for the benefit of the growers. There is no reason to doubt
that this has been Sunkist's belief through the years.
In these circumstances, it seems inequitable that the membership
of the agency associations should cause Sunkist to lose all of its
previously assumed immunity from liability under § 1 of the
Sherman Act. This would evidently be the consequence of the Court's
holding, and, if not mitigated in any way, it would appear to
expose Sunkist to very large liabilities. Many of the activities of
a marketing organization the size of Sunkist presumably amount to
restraints of trade, and, under the Court's rationale, Sunkist
would be subject to treble damage suits in respect of all of them.
The chief result would be to allow windfall treble damage
recoveries to persons with whom Sunkist dealt at arm's length and
in good faith. The main burden would ultimately fall on the growers
at the base of the Sunkist organization.
I would hold that Sunkist is not liable under § 1 of the
Sherman Act for past acts merely because the agency associations
participated in its government by virtue of their membership. It
seems to me that this result is not only more equitable, but
accords better with the basic purpose of Congress, which was to aid
producers, than does the Court's holding, which burdens the growers
with heavy potential liabilities. This belief is supported by the
frequent reference in the congressional debates to the forerunner
of this very organization as one which Congress intended by the Act
to protect. [
Footnote 2/2]
Page 389 U. S. 398
Sufficient precedent for this type of equitable mitigation is
found in
Sunkist Growers, Inc. v. Winckler & Smith Citrus
Products Co., 370 U. S. 19, in
which this Court held that Sunkist's former "tripartite" structure
did not deprive it of its § 1 immunity. The Court there stated
that
"To hold otherwise would be to impose grave legal consequences
upon organizational distinctions that are of
de minimis
meaning and effect to these growers who have banded together for
processing and marketing purposes within the purview of the Clayton
and Capper-Volstead Acts."
Id. at
370 U. S. 29.
The very words of Capper-Volstead § 1, however, make it clear
that Congress granted antitrust immunity to agricultural
cooperatives only on condition that all of the benefits of
cooperative organization were received by agricultural producers.
Therefore, I would also hold that Sunkist may not assert antitrust
immunity if the damage complained of resulted from attempts by the
agency associations to use their power within Sunkist for their own
benefit, as distinguished from that of the growers.
The Court holds, and, for the future, I agree, that even those
organizations in which all gains are channeled to the producers may
not qualify under Capper-Volstead § 1 if they have nonproducer
members. Congress may have excluded nonproducers simply because it
felt that the benefits to producers from nonproducer membership
were outweighed by the dangers of admitting nonproducer foxes into
the cooperative hen roost. However, as the Court recognizes,
see ante at
389 U. S.
394-395, the evident congressional concern about the
possibility of monopoly by organizations immunized from antitrust
prosecution by Capper-Volstead [
Footnote 2/3] indicate that, in restricting membership
to producers, Congress
Page 389 U. S. 399
also intended to limit in a rough way the amount of market power
which could be controlled by such organizations. The resources of
nonproducers were to be available to the cooperatives, not through
the broad avenue of membership, but by the narrower path of
contract: the Act provides that qualifying organizations and their
members "may make the necessary contracts and agreements" to effect
the Act's purposes. To give effect to this legislative intent, I
would hold that the marketing agreements of the agency associations
with Sunkist and with individual growers must be tested by the
standard applicable to contracts with nonmembers.
The Court of Appeals held that, treated as contracts with
nonmembers, the agreements in question were proper under the Act.
369 F.2d 449, 461-462. I agree. Regarded as contracts, these
agreements provide essentially that a grower who desires to market
through the Sunkist system and have his fruit packed by an agency
association shall deliver to such association his entire crop for
the year, that the agency association shall pack it in return for
cost plus a fixed fee, and that the entire crop shall then be
marketed by Sunkist. The contract may be canceled by the grower in
August of any year. Since the main effect of these agreements is
simply to give the growers who want to market through Sunkist a
wider choice of packing facilities than they would enjoy if limited
to cooperative packing houses, I would hold that the agreements are
permissible when looked upon as contracts with nonmembers.
In accord with this opinion, I would remand the case to the
District Court so that Case-Swayne may show what, if any, of the
damage allegedly suffered by it resulted from actions taken by the
agency associations for their own benefit, as distinguished from
that of the growers. I need hardly say that, for the future,
Sunkist
Page 389 U. S. 400
would forfeit its entire Capper-Volstead antitrust exemption
were it to elect to continue the membership of the agency
associations.
[
Footnote 2/1]
It appears that the agency associations have been members of the
system at least since 1924.
See McKay & Stevens,
Organization and Development of a Cooperative Citrus-Fruit
Marketing Agency 22-23 (U.S. Dept. of Agriculture, Bull. No. 1237,
1924).
[
Footnote 2/2]
See n 12,
ante at
389 U. S.
394.
[
Footnote 2/3]
See, e.g., 62 Cong.Rec. 2217-2226, 2257-2280.
MR. JUSTICE WHITE, with whom MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins,
concurring in the result.
I agree with the Court's basic judgment that Congress intended
to grant immunity from the antitrust laws only to the cooperative
efforts of "[p]ersons engaged in the production of agricultural
products as farmers, planters, ranchmen, dairymen, nut or fruit
growers. . . ." Arrangements between growers and nongrowers are
subject to scrutiny under the antitrust laws. Under the controlling
decisions any combination between Sunkist and nongrower packing
houses, were they not members of Sunkist, would have to meet the
standards of the antitrust statutes.
United States v. Borden
Co., 308 U. S. 188
(1939). Making the nongrower a member of the cooperative should not
and does not immunize grower-nongrower transactions from any of the
antitrust laws. Despite such membership, these transactions
continue to be forbidden if they violate § 1. Indeed,
membership should itself be looked upon as an agreement or
combination between growers and nongrowers which, if it restrains
trade, is subject to suit under the Sherman Act. Hence, since the
complaint in this case encompassed a charge that certain
arrangements between Sunkist and the nongrower agency associations
denied product fruit to Case-Swayne and violated the antitrust
laws, I agree that it was error to dismiss the § 1 charge on
immunity grounds.
But it does not follow that Sunkist has lost its antitrust
immunity completely. The bulk of its members are grower
cooperatives or marketing agencies, and the great majority of its
transactions are dealings with and for the account of these
agricultural cooperatives which Congress clearly intended to exempt
from the antitrust laws. An
Page 389 U. S. 401
exempt organization may not conspire with an outsider to violate
§ 1, but if it does, it does not forfeit its immunity except
for that transaction. I see no reason for a different consequence
where the conspiracy or combination takes the form of granting
membership in the exempt organization. If nongrower membership is a
combination in restraint of trade or if any agreements between
Sunkist and the nongrower member violate the Sherman Act,
Case-Swayne should be able to collect treble damages for any injury
flowing from such violations. But I see little basis for concluding
that the membership of the agency association strip Sunkist of it
status as an exempt cooperative and exposes it to what would be
very extensive liability under the antitrust laws wholly unrelated
to the nongrower affiliation.
At the base of the Sunkist organization are 12,000 growers who
themselves are not members of Sunkist, but who are members of local
associations which operate packing houses and which pick, pack, and
arrange for the marketing of the fruit grown by their members. Most
of these local associations appear to qualify as exempt
agricultural cooperatives. A relatively small number, however, the
so-called agency associations, are privately owned packing houses
which buy and pack the fruit of those growers with whom they
contract. The local associations, including the agency
associations, are, in turn, organized into district exchanges
which, unless agency association membership disqualifies some of
them, would seem also to be exempt cooperatives. The district
exchanges are primarily marketing organizations. Sunkist, a member
corporation, is at the top of the pyramid. Among other things, it
has ultimate authority and responsibility for the marketing of both
fresh and product fruit.
Membership in Sunkist is made up of the local associations and
the district exchanges. The agency associations make up about 15%
of the membership. They
Page 389 U. S. 402
have, however, no direct voice in the election of Sunkist
directors, since the selection of directors is vested in the
exchange members alone. The directors have very wide authority to
conduct the affairs of Sunkist. Under the charter and bylaws,
general membership carries with it little power and influence.
Membership does, however, involve the execution of a membership
application and agreement binding the member to Sunkist's charter
and bylaws, which give Sunkist extensive powers over the marketing
of its members' fruit, including the power to confine the packing,
processing, and marketing functions to the Sunkist family. In
addition, local associations and exchanges apparently execute the
standard "Sunkist District Exchange Association Agreement," which,
among other things, contains the agreement by the local association
to market fruit exclusively through the exchanges and by the
exchange to market exclusively through Sunkist.
If Sunkist's exemption is completely lost because of the
membership of the nongrower agency associations, several
consequences follow. Those district exchanges which have nongrower
members will likewise forfeit their exemption. The arrangements
among Sunkist, exempt exchanges, and exempt local associations will
be looked upon as arrangements between exempt and nonexempt
organizations. Thus, for all practical purposes, the entire Sunkist
structure will be exposed to antitrust liability for a great many
transactions which are wholly between growers or between their
cooperative organizations, transactions which Congress intended to
exempt from the antitrust laws.
Neither the agency associations themselves nor their
arrangements with growers are claimed by Sunkist to be
Capper-Volstead cooperatives exempt because of that status from
examination under the Sherman Act. Also, the contracts and
arrangements between the agency associations, nonexempt entities,
and the exchanges and
Page 389 U. S. 403
Sunkist, which should be treated as otherwise exempt entities,
are themselves within the reach of § 1. Among these nonexempt
arrangements is the membership of an agency association in either
an exchange or Sunkist itself. Case-Swayne should be able to
recover from Sunkist those damages which flow from restraints of
trade resulting from the agreements between the agency associations
and Sunkist or between the agency associations and the district
exchanges and from the membership of the agencies in either Sunkist
or the exchanges. But Case-Swayne should not recover for injury to
its business caused by other inter-cooperative or inter-grower
transactions and not resulting from the forbidden relationship
between an exempt and a nonexempt entity. This result, in my view,
will more nearly serve the policy of Congress in granting antitrust
exemption to growers and their cooperative activities.
I would remand to the District Court for a trial of the § 1
case under the above principles.
MR. JUSTICE Douglas,
dubitante.
I am not as certain as MR. JUSTICE WHITE appears to be that the
immunity of the growers or cooperatives granted by the
Capper-Volstead Act is only partially lost in case nongrowers
combine with the growers or cooperatives. But the question is
certainly not free of doubt, and it has not been argued. Nor have
the questions discussed by MR. JUSTICE HARLAN been fully presented
and argued. So far as we can tell at this stage of the litigation,
all of those problems may turn out to be wholly abstract. The
extent, let alone the nature, of participation by nongrower
elements in the agreements and practices alleged to violate the
antitrust laws has indeed hardly been explored. Therefore I think
it is the part of wisdom specifically to reserve the questions with
regard to the scope of the immunity that may survive today's
ruling.