The Government brought a civil action against Grinnell
Corporation and three affiliated companies, which it controlled
through preponderant stock ownership, alleging violations of
§§1 and 2 of the Sherman Act. Grinnell manufactures
plumbing supplies and fire sprinkler systems, and its affiliates
supply subscribers with fire and burglar alarm services from
central stations through automatic alarm systems installed on
subscribers' premises. The affiliates, which had participated in
market allocation agreements, discriminatory price manipulation to
forestall competition, and the acquisition of competitors, had
acquired 87% of the country's insurance company accredited central
station protective service market. One affiliated company, American
District Telegraph Co. (ADT), itself controls 73% of the national
market. The District Court treated the accredited central station
service business as a single "market," and held that the geographic
market is national. It found that the four companies had violated
§§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act and entered a decree
enjoining them from restraining trade or monopolizing the market,
ordering the filing of price information, enjoining them from
acquiring any other enterprise in that market, requiring
divestiture by Grinnell of its affiliates, and enjoining them from
employing the president of Grinnell. All parties challenged the
decree.
Held:
1. The existence of monopoly power may be inferred from the
predominant share of the market, and where Grinnell and its
affiliates have 87% of the accredited central station service
business, there is no doubt they have monopoly power, which they
achieved in part by unlawful and exclusionary practices. Pp.
384 U. S.
570-571,
384 U. S.
576.
Page 384 U. S. 564
2. The District Court was justified in treating the accredited
central station service business as a single market. Pp.
384 U. S.
571-575.
(a) There is no barrier to combining in a single market a number
of different products or services where the combination reflects
commercial realities. Here, there is a single basic service, the
protection of property through use of a central station, that must
be compared with all other forms of property protection. P.
384 U. S.
572.
(b) Just as, under § 7 of the Clayton Act's "line of
commerce," a "cluster of services" marks the appropriate market for
"part" of commerce within the meaning of § 2 of the Sherman
Act. Pp.
384 U. S.
572-573.
(c) Accredited, as distinguished from nonaccredited, central
station service is a relevant part of commerce, with specific
requirements, recognition and approval by insurance companies, and
distinct customer needs and demands. P.
384 U. S.
575.
3. The geographic market for the accredited central station
service, as the District Court found, is a national one. While the
main activities of an individual central station may be local, the
business of providing such service is operated on a national level,
with national planning and agreements covering activities in many
States. Pp.
384 U. S.
575-576.
4. Adequate relief in a monopolization case should terminate the
combination and eliminate the illegal conduct, and render impotent
the monopoly power found to be in violation of the Act.
Schine
Theatres v. United States, 334 U. S. 110,
334 U. S.
128-129. Pp.
384 U. S.
577-580.
(a) The mere dissolution of the combination by Grinnell's
divestiture of its affiliates will not reach the root of the evil;
there must be some divestiture on the part of ADT, with 73% of the
market, to be determined by the District Court. Pp.
384 U. S.
577-578.
(b) On the record it appears that ADT's requirements of
five-year contracts and retention of title to equipment installed
on subscribers' premises constitute substantial barriers to
competition and relief against them by the District Court is
appropriate. P.
384 U. S.
578.
(c) A provision that the companies be required to sell devices
manufactured by them for use in furnishing central station service
is inadequate unless purchasers are assured of replacement parts to
maintain those systems. P.
384 U. S. 579.
Page 384 U. S. 565
(d) The District Court should reconsider its denial of the
Government's request for "visitation rights," that is, requiring
report, examining documents and interviewing company personnel,
relief commonly granted to determine compliance ith an antitrust
decree. P.
384 U. S.
579.
(e) While the barring of Grinnell's president from emploment
might have been appropriate in a case where predatory conduct was
conspicuous, such is not the situation here. P.
384 U. S.
579.
(f) On remand, the general terms of the restraining order should
be recast so that the precise practices in violation of the Act are
specifically enjoined. Pp.
384 U. S. 579-580.
(g) The dissolution of the combination and the proscription
against acquiring firms in the acredited central station business
are fully warranted. P.
384 U. S.
580.
5. The claim of bias and prejudice against the District Judge
who tried the case below is not made out. Pp.
384 U. S.
580-583.
236 F.
Supp. 244, affirmed and remanded.
Page 384 U. S. 566
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case presents an important question under § 2 of the
Sherman Act, [
Footnote 1] which
makes it an offense for any person to "monopolize . . . any part of
the trade or commerce among the several States." This is a civil
suit brought by the United States against Grinnell Corporation
(Grinnell), American District Telegraph Co. (ADT), Holmes Electric
Protective Co. (Holmes) and Automatic Fire Alarm Co. of Delaware
(AFA). The District Court held for the Government, and entered a
decree. All parties appeal, [
Footnote 2] the United States because it deems the relief
inadequate and the defendants both on the merits and on the relief
and on the ground that the District Court denied them a fair trial.
We noted probable jurisdiction. 381 U.S. 910.
Grinnell manufactures plumbing supplies and fire sprinkler
systems. It also owns 76% of the stock of ADT, 89% of the stock of
AFA, and 100% of the stock of Holmes. [
Footnote 3] ADT provides both burglary and fire protection
services; Holmes provides burglary services alone; AFA supplies
only fire protection service. Each offers a central station service
under which hazard-detecting devices installed on the protected
premises automatically
Page 384 U. S. 567
transmit an electric signal to a central station. [
Footnote 4] The central station is manned 24
hours a day. Upon receipt of a signal, the central station, where
appropriate, dispatches guards to the protected premises and
notifies the police or fire department direct. There are other
forms of protective services. But the record shows that subscribers
to accredited central station service (
i.e., that approved
by the insurance underwriters) receive reductions in their
insurance premiums that are substantially greater than the
reduction received by the users of other kinds of protection
service. In 1961, accredited companies in the central station
service business grossed $65,000,000. ADT, Holmes, and AFA are the
three largest companies in the business in terms of revenue: ADT
(with 121 central stations in 115 cities) has 73% of the business;
Holmes (with 12 central stations in three large cities) has 12.5%;
AFA (with three central stations in three large cities) has 2%.
Thus, the three companies that Grinnell controls have over 87% of
the business.
Over the years, ADT purchased the stock or assets of 27
companies engaged in the business of providing burglar or fire
alarm services. Holmes acquired the stock or assets of three
burglar alarm companies in New York City using a central station.
Of these 30, the officials
Page 384 U. S. 568
of seven agreed not to engage in the protective service business
in the area for periods ranging from five years to permanently.
After Grinnell acquired control of the other defendants, the latter
continued in their attempts to acquire central station companies --
offers being made to at least eight companies between the years
1955 and 1961, including four of the five largest nondefendant
companies in the business. When the present suit was filed, each of
those defendants had outstanding an offer to purchase one of the
four largest nondefendant companies.
In 1906, prior to the affiliation of ADT and Holmes, they made a
written agreement whereby ADT transferred to Holmes its burglar
alarm business in a major part of the Middle Atlantic States and
agreed to refrain forever from engaging in that business in that
area, while Holmes transferred to ADT its watch signal business and
agreed to limit its activities to burglar alarm service and night
watch service for financial institutions. While this agreement was
modified several times and terminated in 1947, in 1961, Holmes
still restricted its business to burglar alarm service and operated
only in those areas which had been allocated to it under the 1906
agreement. Similarly, ADT continued to refrain from supplying
burglar alarm service in those areas earlier allocated to
Holmes.
In 1907, Grinnell entered into a series of agreements with the
other defendant companies and with Automatic Fire Protection Co. to
the following effect:
AFA received the exclusive right to provide central station
sprinkler supervisory and waterflow alarm and automatic fire alarm
service in New York City, Boston and Philadelphia, and agreed not
to provide burglar alarm service in those cities or central station
service elsewhere in the United States.
Page 384 U. S. 569
Automatic Fire Protection Co. obtained the exclusive right to
provide central station sprinkler supervisory and waterflow alarm
service everywhere else in the United States except for the three
cities in which AFA received that exclusive right, and agreed not
to engage in burglar alarm service.
ADT received the exclusive right to render burglar alarm and
nightwatch service throughout the United States. (Under ADT's 1906
agreement with Holmes, however, it could not provide burglar alarm
services in the areas for which it had given Holmes the exclusive
right to do so.) It agreed not to furnish sprinkler supervisory and
waterflow alarm service anywhere in the country, and not to furnish
automatic fire alarm service in New York City, Boston or
Philadelphia (the three cities allocated to AFA). ADT agreed to
connect to its central stations the systems installed by AFA and
Automatic.
Grinnell agreed to furnish and install all sprinkler supervisory
and waterflow alarm actuating devices used in systems that AFA and
Automatic would install, and otherwise not to engage in the central
station protection business.
AFA and Automatic received 25% of the revenue produced by the
sprinkler supervisory waterflow alarm service which they provided
in their respective territories; ADT and Grinnell received 50% and
25%, respectively, of the revenue which resulted from such service.
The agreements were to continue until February, 1954.
The agreements remained substantially unchanged until 1949, when
ADT purchased all of Automatic Fire Protection Co.'s rights under
it for $13,500,000. After these 1907 agreements expired in 1954,
AFA continued to honor the prior division of territories, and ADT
and AFA entered into a new contract providing for the continued
sharing of revenues on substantially the same
Page 384 U. S. 570
basis as before. [
Footnote
5] In 1954, Grinnell and ADT renewed an agreement with a Rhode
Island company which received the exclusive right to render central
station service within Rhode Island at prices no lower than those
of ADT and which agreed to use certain equipment supplied by
Grinnell and ADT and to share its revenues with those companies.
ADT had an informal agreement with a competing central station
company in Washington, D.C., "that we would not solicit each
other's accounts."
ADT over the years reduced its minimum basic rates to meet
competition and renewed contracts at substantially increased rates
in cities where it had a monopoly of accredited central station
service. ADT threatened retaliation against firms that contemplated
inaugurating central station service. And the record indicates
that, in contemplating opening a new central station, ADT officials
frequently stressed that such action would deter their competitors
from opening a new station in that area.
The District Court found that the defendant companies had
committed
per se violations of § 1 of the Sherman Act
as well as § 2, and entered a decree.
236 F.
Supp. 244.
I
The offense of monopoly under § 2 of the Sherman Act has
two elements: (1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant
market and (2) the willful acquisition
Page 384 U. S. 571
or maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or
development as a consequence of a superior product, business
acumen, or historic accident. We shall see that this second
ingredient presents no major problem here, as what was done in
building the empire was done plainly and explicitly for a single
purpose. In
United States v. E. I. du Pont De Nemours &
Co., 351 U. S. 377,
351 U. S. 391,
we defined monopoly power as "the power to control prices or
exclude competition." The existence of such power ordinarily may be
inferred from the predominant share of the market. In
American
Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.
S. 781,
328 U. S. 797,
we said that "over two-thirds of the entire domestic field of
cigarettes, and . . . over 80% of the field of comparable
cigarettes" constituted "a substantial monopoly." In
United
States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 429, 90% of
the market constituted monopoly power. In the present case, 87% of
the accredited central station service business leaves no doubt
that the congeries of these defendants have monopoly power -- power
which, as our discussion of the record indicates, they did not
hesitate to wield -- if that business is the relevant market. The
only remaining question therefore is what is the relevant
market?
In case of a product, it may be of such a character that
substitute products must also be considered, as customers may turn
to them if there is a slight increase in the price of the main
product. That is the teaching of the
du Pont case
(
supra, at
351 U. S. 395,
351 U. S.
404),
viz., that commodities reasonably
interchangeable make up that "part" of trade or commerce which
§ 2 protects against monopoly power.
The District Court treated the entire accredited central station
service business as a single market, and we think it was justified
in so doing. Defendants argue that the different central station
services offered are so diverse that they cannot, under
du
Pont, be lumped together to
Page 384 U. S. 572
make up the relevant market. For example, burglar alarm services
are not interchangeable with fire alarm services. They further urge
that
du Pont requires that protective services other than
those of the central station variety be included in the market
definition.
But there is here a single use,
i.e., the protection of
property, through a central station that receives signals. It is
that service, accredited, that is unique, and that competes with
all the other forms of property protection. We see no barrier to
combining in a single market a number of different products or
services where that combination reflects commercial realities. To
repeat, there is here a single basic service -- the protection of
property through use of a central service station -- that must be
compared with all other forms of property protection.
In § 2 cases under the Sherman Act, as in § 7 cases
under the Clayton Act (
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U. S. 294,
370 U. S. 325)
there may be submarkets that are separate economic entities. We do
not pursue that question here. First, we deal with services, not
with products; and second, we conclude that the accredited central
station is a type of service that makes up a relevant market, and
that domination or control of it makes out a monopoly of a "part"
of trade or commerce within the meaning of § 2 of the Sherman
Act. The defendants have not made out a case for fragmentizing the
types of services into lesser units.
Burglar alarm service is, in a sense, different from fire alarm
service, from waterflow alarms, and so on. But it would be
unrealistic on this record to break down the market into the
various kinds of central station protective services that are
available. Central station companies recognize that, to compete
effectively, they must offer all or nearly all types of service.
[
Footnote 6] The different
Page 384 U. S. 573
forms of accredited central station service are provided from a
single office and customers utilize different services in
combination. We held in
United States v. Philadelphia Nat.
Bank, 374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 356,
that "the cluster" of services donoted by the term "commercial
banking" is "a distinct line of commerce." There is, in our view, a
comparable cluster of services here. That bank case arose under
§ 7 of the Clayton Act, where the question was whether the
effect of a merger "in any line of commerce" may be "substantially
to lessen competition." We see no reason to differentiate between
"line" of commerce in the context of the Clayton Act and "part" of
commerce for purposes of the Sherman Act.
See United States v.
First Nat. Bank & Trust Co., 376 U.
S. 665,
376 U. S.
667-668. In the § 7 national bank case just
mentioned, services, not products in the mercantile sense, were
involved. In our view, the lumping together of various kinds of
services makes for the appropriate market here, as it did in the
§ 7 case.
There are, to be sure, substitutes for the accredited central
station service. But none of them appears to operate on the same
level as the central station service so as to meet the
interchangeability test of the
du Pont case. Nonautomatic
and automatic local alarm systems appear on this record to have
marked differences, not the low degree of differentiation required
of substitute services, as well as substitute articles.
Page 384 U. S. 574
Watchman service is far more costly and less reliable. Systems
that set off an audible alarm at the site of a fire or burglary are
cheaper, but often less reliable. They may be inoperable without
anyone's knowing it. Moreover, there is a risk that the local
ringing of an alarm will not attract the needed attention and help.
Proprietary systems that a customer purchases and operates are
available, but they can be used only by a very large business or by
government, and are not realistic alternatives for most concerns.
There are also protective services connected directly to a
municipal police or fire department. But most cities with an
accredited central station do not permit direct connected service
for private businesses. These alternate services and devices
differ, we are told, in utility, efficiency, reliability,
responsiveness, and continuity, and the record sustains that
position. And, as noted, insurance companies generally allow a
greater reduction in premiums for accredited central station
service than for other types of protection.
Defendants earnestly urge that, despite these differences, they
face competition from these other modes of protection. They seem to
us seriously to overstate the degree of competition, but we
recognize that (as the District Court found) they "do not have
unfettered power to control the price of their services . . . due
to the fringe competition of other alarm or watchmen services." 236
F. Supp. at 254. What defendants overlook is that the high degree
of differentiation between central station protection and the other
forms means that, for many customers, only central station
protection will do. Though some customers may be willing to accept
higher insurance rates in favor of cheaper forms of protection,
others will not be willing or able to risk serious interruption to
their businesses, even though covered by insurance, and will thus
be unwilling to consider anything but central station
protection.
Page 384 U. S. 575
The accredited, as distinguished from nonaccredited, service is
a relevant part of commerce. Virtually the only central station
companies in the status of the nonaccredited are those that have
not yet been able to meet the standards of the rating bureau. The
accredited ones are indeed those that have achieved, in the eyes of
underwriters, superiorities that other central stations do not
have. The accredited central station is located in a building of
approved design, provided with an emergency lighting system and two
alternate main power sources, manned constantly by at least a
required minimum of operators, provided with a direct line to fire
headquarters and, where possible, a direct line to a police
station, and equipped with all the devices, circuits, and equipment
meeting the requirements of the underwriters. These standards are
important, as insurance carriers often require accredited central
station service as a condition to writing insurance. There is
indeed evidence that customers consider the unaccredited service as
inferior.
We also agree with the District Court that the geographic market
for the accredited central station service is national. The
activities of an individual station are in a sense local as it
serves, ordinarily, only that area which is within a radius of 25
miles. But the record amply supports the conclusion that the
business of providing such a service is operated on a national
level. There is national planning. The agreements we have discussed
covered activities in many States. The inspection, certification
and ratemaking is largely by national insurers. The appellant ADT
has a national schedule of prices, rates, and terms, though the
rates may be varied to meet local conditions. It deals with
multistate businesses on the basis of nationwide contracts. The
manufacturing business of ADT is interstate. The fact that Holmes
is more nearly local than the others does not
Page 384 U. S. 576
save it, for it is part and parcel of the combine presided over
and controlled by Grinnell.
As the District Court found, the relevant market for determining
whether the defendants have monopoly power is not the several local
areas which the individual stations serve, but the broader national
market that reflects the reality of the way in which they built and
conduct their business.
We have said enough about the great hold that the defendants
have on this market. The percentage is so high as to justify the
finding of monopoly. And, as the facts already related indicate,
this monopoly was achieved in large part by unlawful and
exclusionary practices. The restrictive agreements that preempted
for each company a segment of the market where it was free of
competition of the others were one device. Pricing practices that
contained competitors were another. The acquisitions by Grinnell of
ADT, AFA, and Holmes were still another. Grinnell long faced a
problem of competing with ADT. That was one reason it acquired AFA
and Holmes. Prior to settlement of its dispute and controversy with
ADT, Grinnell prepared to go into the central station service
business. By acquiring ADT in 1953, Grinnell eliminated that
alternative. Its control of the three other defendants eliminated
any possibility of an outbreak of competition that might have
occurred when the 1907 agreements terminated. By those
acquisitions, it perfected the monopoly power to exclude
competitors and fix prices. [
Footnote 7]
Page 384 U. S. 577
II
The final decree enjoins the defendants in general terms from
restraining trade or attempting or conspiring to restrain trade in
this particular market, from further monopolizing, and attempting
or conspiring to monopolize. The court ordered the alarm companies
to file with the Department of Justice standard lists of prices and
terms and every quotation to customers that deviated from those
lists, and enjoined the defendants from acquiring stock, assets, or
business of any enterprise in the market. Grinnell was ordered to
file, not later than April 1, 1966, a plan of divestiture of its
stock in each of the other defendant companies. It was given the
option either to sell the stock or distribute it to its
stockholders or combine or vary those methods. [
Footnote 8] The court further enjoined any of the
defendants from employing in any capacity the President and
Chairman of the Board of Grinnell, James D. Fleming. Both the
Government and the defendants challenge aspects of the decree.
We start from the premise that adequate relief in a
monopolization case should put an end to the combination and
deprive the defendants of any of the benefits of the illegal
conduct, and break up or render impotent the monopoly power found
to be in violation of the Act. That is the teaching of our cases,
notably
Schine Chain Theatres v. United States,
334 U. S. 110,
334 U. S.
128-129.
We largely agree with the Government's views on the relief
aspect of the case. We start with ADT, which presently does 73% of
the business done by accredited central stations throughout the
country. It is indeed the keystone of the defendants' monopoly
power. The mere
Page 384 U. S. 578
dissolution of the combination through the divestiture by
Grinnell of its interests in the other companies does not reach the
root of the evil. In 92 of the 115 cities in which ADT operates,
there are no other accredited central stations. Perhaps some cities
could not support more than one. Defendants recognized prior to
trial that at least 13 cities can; the Government urged divestiture
in 48 cities. That there should be some divestiture on the part of
ADT seems clear, but the details of such divestiture must be
determined by the District Court, as the matter cannot be resolved
on this record.
Two of the means by which ADT acquired and maintained its large
share of the market are the requirement that subscribers sign
five-year contracts and the retention by ADT of title to the
protective services equipment installed on a subscriber's premises.
On this record, it appears that these practices constitute
substantial barriers to competition, and that relief against them
is appropriate. The pros and cons are argued with considerable
vehemence here. [
Footnote 9]
Again, we cannot resolve them on this record. The various aspects
of this controversy must be explored by the District Court, and
suitable protective provisions included in the decree that deprive
these two devices of the coercive power that they apparently have
had towards restraining competition and creating a monopoly.
Page 384 U. S. 579
The Government proposed that the defendants be required to sell,
on nondiscriminatory terms, any devices manufactured by them for
use in furnishing central station service. It seems clear that, if
the competitors are to be able to compete effectively for the
existing customers of the defendants when the present service
contracts expire, they must be assured of replacement parts to
maintain those systems. [
Footnote 10]
The Government urges visitation rights -- that is, requiring
reports, examining documents, and interviewing company personnel, a
relief commonly granted for the purpose of determining whether a
defendant has complied with an antitrust decree.
See United
States v. United States Gypsum Co., 340 U. S.
76,
340 U. S. 95.
The District Court gave no explanation for its refusal to grant
this relief. [
Footnote 11]
It is so important and customary a provision that the District
Court should reconsider it.
Defendants urge and the Government concedes that the barring of
Mr. Fleming from the employment of any of the defendants is unduly
harsh, and quite unnecessary on this record. While relief of that
kind may be appropriate where the predatory conduct is conspicuous,
we cannot see that any such case was made out on this record.
The Government objects, as do the defendants, to the broad and
generalized terms of the restraining order. They properly point
out, as we emphasized in
Schine Chain Theatres v. United
States, supra, at
334 U. S.
125-126, that the precise practices found to have
violated the Act should
Page 384 U. S. 580
be specifically enjoined. On remand, we suggest that that course
be taken.
The defendants object to the requirements that Grinnell divest
itself of its holdings in the three alarm company defendants, but
we think that provision is wholly justified. Dissolution of the
combination is essential as indicated by many of our cases,
starting with
Standard Oil Co. of New Jersey v. United
States, 221 U. S. 1,
221 U. S. 78. The
defendants object to that portion of the decree that bars them from
acquiring interests in firms in the accredited central station
business. But, since acquisition was one of the methods by which
the defendants acquired their market power and was the method by
which Grinnell put the combination together, an injunction against
the repetition of the practice seems fully warranted. The
defendants further object to the requirement in the decree that the
alarm company defendants report to the Department of Justice any
deviation they make from their list prices. We make no comment on
that, because, in view of the other extensive changes necessary in
the decree, the District Court might well deem it to be unnecessary
in the fashioning of the new decree. In other words, we leave that
matter open, to rest finally in the discretion of the District
Court.
III
The defendants contend that Judge Wyzanski, who tried the case,
was personally biased and prejudiced and should have been
disqualified from sitting in the case, and that he denied them a
fair trial. We think this point is without merit.
The complaint was filed in April, 1961, the answers in July,
1961. Shortly thereafter, extensive taking of depositions began.
The District Court, in January, 1963, directed that no depositions
be taken after September 1, 1963. In response to an inquiry from
the court, both sides suggested that the trial be set no earlier
than January, 1964.
Page 384 U. S. 581
At a pretrial conference in December, 1963, government counsel
told the court that the parties had been trying to reach agreement
on a consent decree, but were far apart, and asked how the court
would like to handle the presentation of the evidence in the event
a settlement was not reached. Grinnell's lawyer suggested that the
next appropriate procedure would be a pretrial on the question of
relief -- a suggestion that the District Court construed as an
invitation to the court to discuss the relief apart from the
merits. The Government objected. The court then asked for a brief
from each side setting forth its views on relief if the Government
prevailed on the merits. In response to the court's statement
that,
"as I understand it, you want to find out what kind of relief I
would be likely to allow if the government's case stood virtually
uncontradicted,"
Grinnell's counsel replied: "That is what I had in mind, your
Honor, yes."
Thereupon the court set a day for such a hearing. At the next
pretrial conference, Grinnell's counsel stated that "if your Honor
would indicate the relief that might be appropriate in this case,
that would help both sides to come to a better understanding."
Then the following colloquy occurred:
"THE COURT. I don't think it would help very much."
"MR. MCINERNEY. Well, your Honor, I think it would help both the
plaintiff and the defendants to know what is really at stake here
in this trial."
"THE COURT. I assure you that you would not be helped by
anything I would say. You would do better to get together with the
government, rather than run the risk of what I would say, from what
I have seen. Let me just assure you of that. . . ."
The case was then set for trial on June 15, 1964. When
Grinnell's counsel sought to argue further, the court stated:
"There is no use in discussing it with me. I have
Page 384 U. S. 582
read enough to know that if I have to decide this case on what I
have seen from the government, you will not be in a position at
this stage to agree to it."
On June 3, 1964, defendants argued for a postponement of the
trial, saying they needed more time. The court denied the motion.
Then they argued that the relief issues to be tried be limited to
those raised by the pleadings, so as to eliminate what they
considered to be extraneous issues raised by the Government. To
that, the court replied:
"I can't understand, frankly, why you don't realize that you
have forced me to look at the documents in this case, which I
dislike doing in advance of trial. You have invited me, therefore,
into what I regard as, from your point of view, a rather
undesirable situation. I think I made that clear at the beginning.
I have told you that, forced by you to look, my views are more
extreme than those of the government, and I have also made you
realize that if I am required to make findings and reach
conclusions I am opening up third-party suits that will make, in
view of the size of the industry, the percentage of people involved
higher than in the electrical cases."
Shortly thereafter, defendants filed a motion [
Footnote 12] for the disqualification of
Judge Wyzanski on the grounds of personal bias and prejudice.
[
Footnote 13]
Page 384 U. S. 583
The alleged bias and prejudice to be disqualifying must stem
from an extrajudicial source and result in an opinion on the merits
on some basis other than what the judge learned from his
participation in the case.
Berger v. United States,
255 U. S. 22,
255 U. S. 31.
Any adverse attitudes that Judge Wyzanski evinced toward the
defendants were based on his study of the depositions and briefs
which the parties had requested him to make. What he said reflected
no more than his view that, if the facts were as the Government
alleged, stringent relief was called for.
During the trial, he repeatedly stated that he had not made up
his mind on the merits. During the trial, he ruled certain evidence
to be irrelevant to the issues, and when the lawyer persisted in
offering it, Judge Wyzanski said, "Maybe you will persuade somebody
else. And if you think so, all right. I just assure you it is a
great ceremonial act as far as I am concerned." We do not read this
statement as manifesting a closed mind on the merits of the case,
but consider it merely a terse way of repeating the previously
stated ruling that this particular evidence was irrelevant.
We have examined all the other claims of the defendants made
against Judge Wyzanski, and find that the claim of bias and
prejudice is not made out. Our discussion of the relief which he
granted shows indeed that he was, in several critical respects, too
lenient with those who now charge him with bias and prejudice.
The judgment below is affirmed except as to the decree. We
remand for further hearings on the nature of the relief consistent
with the views expressed herein.
It is so ordered.
|384 U.S.
384 U. S.
563ast|
* Together with No. 74,
Grinnell Corp. v. United
States, No. 75,
American District Telegraph Co. v. United
States, No. 76,
Holmes Electric Protective Co. v. United
States, and No. 77,
Automatic Fire Alarm Co. of Delaware
v. United States, also on appeal from the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
26 Stat. 209, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 2 (1964 ed.).
[
Footnote 2]
Expediting Act § 2, 32 Stat. 823, as amended, 15 U.S.C.
§ 29 (1964 ed.);
United States v. Loew's, Inc.,
371 U. S. 38.
[
Footnote 3]
These are the record figures. Since the time of the trial,
Grinnell's holdings have increased. Counsel for Grinnell has
advised this Court that Grinnell now holds 80% of ADT's stock and
90% of the stock of AFA.
[
Footnote 4]
Among the various central station services offered are the
following:
(1)
automatic burglar alarms;
(2)
automatic fire alarms;
(3)
sprinkler supervisory service (any malfunctions in
the fire sprinkler system --
e.g., changes in water
pressure, dangerously low water temperatures, etc. -- are reported
to the central station); and
(4)
watch signal service (night watchmen, by operating
a key-triggered device on the protected premises, indicate to the
central station that they are making their rounds and that all is
well; the failure of a watchman to make his electrical report
alerts the central station that something may be amiss).
[
Footnote 5]
In 1959, ADT complained that AFA's share of the revenues was
excessive. AFA replied, in a letter to the president of Grinnell
(which by that time controlled both ADT and AFA), that its share
was just compensation for its continued observance of the service
and territorial restrictions:
"
[T]he geographic restrictions placed upon us plus the
requirement that we confine our activities to sprinkler and fire
alarm services exclusively, since 1907 and presumably into the
future, has definitely retarded our expansion in the past to the
benefit of ADT growth. . . . [AFA's] contribution must also include
the many things that helped make ADT big."
(Emphasis added.)
[
Footnote 6]
Thus, of the 38 nondefendant firms operating a central service
station protective service in the United States in 1961, 24 offered
all of the following services: automatic fire alarm; waterflow
alarm and sprinkler supervision; watchman's reporting and manual
fire alarm; and burglar alarm. Of the other firms, 11 provided no
watchman's reporting and manual fire alarm service; six provided no
automatic fire alarm service; and two offered no sprinkler
supervisory and waterflow alarm service. Moreover, of the 14 firms
not providing the full panoply of services, 10 lacked only one of
the above-described services. Appellant ADT's assertion that "very
few accredited central stations furnish the full variety of
services" is flatly contradicted by the record.
[
Footnote 7]
Since the record clearly shows that this monopoly power was
consciously acquired, we have no reason to reach the further
position of the District Court that, once monopoly power is shown
to exist, the burden is on the defendants to show that their
dominance is due to skill, acumen, and the like.
[
Footnote 8]
Although the Government originally urged that the decree was
inadequate as to divestiture in that it permitted Grinnell to
distribute the stock of the other companies to Grinnell's
shareholders, it has abandoned that point in this Court.
[
Footnote 9]
Specifically, the areas of disagreement are: (1) Defendants urge
that barring them from offering five-year contracts would put them
at a competitive disadvantage
vis-a-vis nondefendant
firms; the Government responds that, since they violated the law,
they may properly be subjected to restrictions not borne by others.
See United States v. Bausch & Lomb Optical Co.,
321 U. S. 707,
321 U. S.
723-724. (2) Some customers of defendants may wish to
have long-term contracts; the Government responds that this may be
explored on remand. (3) There is some dispute as to whether, if the
central station company cannot retain title to the equipment it
installs, the insurance companies will accredit the system. This,
too, is a proper subject for inquiry on remand.
[
Footnote 10]
Prior to trial, the defendants agreed that this would be an
appropriate provision in a decree were the Government to prevail in
all its claims of antitrust violations. Although defendants now
maintain that this pretrial discussion was "settlement talk," that
earlier concession is a relevant factor that the District Judge can
properly take into account on remand.
[
Footnote 11]
This provision, too, gained pretrial acceptance.
See
n 10,
supra.
[
Footnote 12]
28 U.S.C. § 144 (1964 ed.) provides in relevant part:
"Whenever a party to any proceeding in a district court makes
and files a timely and sufficient affidavit that the judge before
whom the matter is pending has a personal bias or prejudice either
against him or in favor of any adverse party, such judge shall
proceed no further therein, but another judge shall be assigned to
hear such proceeding."
[
Footnote 13]
Judge Wyzanski referred the question of his disqualification to
Chief Judge Woodbury of the Court of Appeals for the First Circuit
who after hearing oral argument held that no case of bias and
prejudice had been made out under § 144.
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN, dissenting in Nos. 73-77.
I cannot agree with the Court that the relevant market has been
adequately proved. I do not dispute that a
Page 384 U. S. 584
national market may be found even though immediate competition
takes place only within individual communities, some of which are
themselves natural monopolies. For a national monopoly of such
local enterprises may still have serious long-term impact on
competition and be vulnerable on its own plane to the antitrust
laws. In the product market also, the Court seems to me to make out
a good enough case for lumping together the different kinds of
central station protective service (CSPS). But I cannot agree that
the facts so far developed warrant restricting the product market
to accredited CSPS.
Because the ultimate issue is the effective power to control
price and competition, this Court has always recognized that the
market must include products or services "reasonably
interchangeable" with those of the alleged monopolist.
United
States v. E. I. du Pont De Nemours & Co., 351 U.
S. 377,
351 U. S. 395.
In this instance, there is no doubt that the accredited CSPS
business does compete in some measure with many other forms of
hazard protection: watchmen, local alarms, proprietary systems,
telephone-connected services, unaccredited CSPS, direct-connected
(to police and fire stations) systems, and so forth. The critical
question, then, is the extent of competition from these rivals.
The Government and the majority have stressed that differences
in cost, reliability and insurance discounts may disqualify a
competing form of protection for a particular customer. For
example, it is said that proprietary systems are too expensive for
any but large companies, and local alarms may go unanswered in some
neighborhoods. But if, in general, a CSPS customer has a feasible
alternative to CSPS, it does not much matter that other ones are
foreclosed to him, nor that other CSPS customers have different
second choices. From this record, it may well be that other forms
of protection are each competitive enough with segments of the
CSPS
Page 384 U. S. 585
market so that in sum CSPS rarely has a monopoly position.
From the defense standpoint, there is substantial evidence
showing that the defendants do feel themselves under pressure from
other forms of protection, that they do compete for customers, and
that they do lower prices even in areas where no CSPS competition
is present. This concrete evidence of market behavior seems to me
to rank higher than the kind of inference proof heavily relied on
by the Government -- physical differences between competing forms
of protection, self-advertising claims of CSPS companies that they
represent a superior service and varying insurance discounts. Given
that the burden of proof rests upon the Government, the record
leaves me with such misgivings as to the validity of the District
Court's findings on this score that I am not prepared to agree that
the Government has made the showing of market domination that the
law demands before a business is sundered.
At the same time, the case must be recognized as a close one,
and I am not ready to say at this stage that the findings and
conclusions of the District Court might not be supportable. All
things considered, I join with my Brothers Fortas and Stewart to
the extent of voting to remand the case for further proceedings so
that new findings can be made as to the relevant product market.
This course seems to me the more appropriate in light of the fact
that, because of the Expediting Act, 15 U.S.C. § 29 (1964
ed.), we have not had the benefit of any intermediate appellate
sifting of this record. In view of the disposition I propose, I do
not consider any of the other questions in the case.
MR. JUSTICE FORTAS, with whom MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins,
dissenting in Nos. 73 and 77.
I agree that the judgment below should be remanded, but I do not
agree that the remand should be limited to
Page 384 U. S. 586
reshaping the decree. Because I believe that the definition of
the relevant market here cannot be sustained, I would reverse and
remand for a new determination of this basic issue, subject to
proper standards.
We have here a case under both § 1 and § 2 of the
Sherman Act, which proscribe combinations in restraint of trade,
and monopolies and attempts to monopolize. The judicial task is not
difficult to state: does the record show a combination in restraint
of trade or a monopoly or attempt to monopolize? If so, what are
its characteristics, scope and effect? And, finally, what is the
appropriate remedy for a court of equity to decree?
Each of these inquires depends upon two basic referents:
definition of the geographical area of trade or commerce restrained
or monopolized, and of the products or services involved. In §
1 cases, this problem ordinarily presents little difficulty,
because the combination in restraint of trade itself delineates the
"market" with sufficient clarity to support the usual injunctive
form of relief in those cases.
See, e.g., United States v.
Griffith, 334 U. S. 100. In
the present case, however, the essence of the offense is
monopolization, achieved or attempted, and the major relief is
divestiture. For these purposes, "market" definition is of the
essence, just as, in § 7 cases, [
Footnote 2/1] the kindred definition of the "line of
commerce" is fundamental. We must define the area of commerce that
is allegedly engrossed before we can determine its engrossment, and
we must define it before a decree can be shaped to deal with the
consequences of the monopoly and to restore or produce competition.
See United States v. E. I. du Pont De Nemours & Co.
(the
Cellophane Case),
351 U. S. 377,
Page 384 U. S. 587
351 U. S.
389-396;
United States v. Aluminum Co. of
America, 148 F.2d 416 (C.A.2d Cir. 1945).
In § 2 cases, the search for "the relevant market" must be
undertaken and pursued with relentless clarity. It is, in essence,
an economic task put to the uses of the law. Unless this task is
well done, the results will be distorted in terms of the conclusion
as to whether the law has been violated and what the decree should
contain.
In this case, the relevant geographical and product markets have
not been defined on the basis of the economic facts of the industry
concerned. They have been tailored precisely to fit defendants'
business. The Government proposed, and the trial court concluded,
that the relevant market is not the business of fire protection, or
burglary protection, or protection against waterflow, etc., or all
of these together. It is not even the business of furnishing these
from a central location. It is the business, viewed nationally, of
supplying "insurance accredited central station protection
services" (CSPS) -- that is, fire, burglary and other kinds of
protection furnished from a central station which is accredited by
insurance companies. The business of defendants fits neatly into
the product and geographic market so defined. In fact, it comes
close to filling the market so defined. [
Footnote 2/2] This Court has now approved this
Procrustean definition.
The geographical market is defined as nationwide. But the need
and the service are intensely local -- more local by far, for
example, than the market which this Court found to be local in
United States v. Philadelphia Nat. Bank, 374 U.
S. 321,
374 U. S.
357-362. [
Footnote 2/3]
The premises protected
Page 384 U. S. 588
do not travel. They are fixed locations. They must be protected
where they are. Protection must be provided on the spot. It must be
furnished by local personnel able to bring help to the scene within
minutes. Even the central stations can provide service only within
a 25-mile radius. Where the tenants of the premises turn to central
stations for this service, they must make their contracts locally
with the central station and purchase their services from it on the
basis of local conditions.
But because these defendants, the trial court found, are
connected by stock ownership, interlocking management, and some
degree of national corporate direction, and because there is some
national participation in selling, as well as national financing,
advertising, purchasing of equipment, and the like, [
Footnote 2/4] the court concluded that the
competitive area to be considered is national. This Court now
affirms that conclusion.
This is a
non sequitur. It is not permissible to seize
upon the nationwide scope of defendants' operation and to bootstrap
a geographical definition of the market from this. The purpose of
the search for the relevant geographical market is to find the area
or areas to which a potential buyer may rationally look for the
goods or services that he seeks. The test, as this Court said in
United States v. Philadelphia Nat. Bank, is "the
geographic structure of supplier-customer relations,"
374 U. S. 374 U.S.
321,
374 U. S. 357,
quoting Kaysen & Turner, Antitrust Policy 102 (1959). And, as
Mr. Justice Clark put it in
Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville
Coal Co., 365 U. S. 320,
365 U. S. 327,
the definition of the relevant market requires
Page 384 U. S. 589
"careful selection of the market area in which the seller
operates, and to which the purchaser can practicably turn for
supplies." [
Footnote 2/5] The
central issue is where does a potential buyer look for potential
suppliers of the service -- what is the geographical area in which
the buyer has, or, in the absence of monopoly, would have, a real
choice as to price and alternative facilities? This depends upon
the facts of the market place, taking into account such economic
factors as the distance over which supplies and services may be
feasibly furnished, consistently with cost and functional
efficiency.
The incidental aspects of defendants' business which the court
uses cannot control the outcome of this inquiry. They do not
measure the market area in which buyer and sellers meet. They have
little impact upon the ascertainment of the geographical areas in
which the economic and legal questions must be answered: have
defendants "monopolized" or "restrained" trade; have they
eliminated or can they eliminate competitors or prevent or obstruct
new entries into the business; have they controlled or can they
control price for the services? These are the issues, and, in
defendants' business, a finding that the "relevant market" is
national is nothing less than a studied failure to assess the
effect of defendants' position and practices in the light of the
competition which exists, or could exist, in economically defined
areas-in the real world.
Here, there can be no doubt that the correct geographic market
is local. The services at issue are intensely local: they can be
furnished only locally. The business as it is done is local -- not
nationwide. If, as might well be the case on this record,
defendants were found to have violated the Sherman Act in a number
of these local areas, a proper decree, directed to those markets,
as well as to
Page 384 U. S. 590
general corporate features relevant to the condemned practices,
could be fashioned. On the other hand, a gross definition of the
market as nationwide leads to a gross nationwide decree which does
not address itself to the realities of the market place. That is
what happened here: the District Court's finding that the market
was
nationwide logically led it to a decree which operated
on the only
national aspect of the situation -- the parent
company nexus -- instead of on the economically realistic areas --
the local situations. This Court now directs the trial court to
require "some [unspecified] divestiture" locally by the alarm
companies. This is a recognition of the economic reality that the
relevant competitive areas are local. In plain terms, the Court's
direction to the trial court means a "market by market" analysis
for the purpose of breaking up defendants' monopoly position and
creating competitors and competition wherever feasible in
particular cities. In my view, however, by so directing, the Court
implies that which it does not command: that the case should be
reconsidered at the trial court level because of the improper
standard it used to define the relevant geographic markets.
The trial court's definition of the "product" market even more
dramatically demonstrates that its action has been Procrustean --
that it has tailored the market to the dimensions of the
defendants. It recognizes that a person seeking protective services
has many alternative sources. It lists
"watchmen, watchdogs, automatic proprietary systems confined to
one site (often, but not always), alarm systems connected with some
local police or fire station, often unaccredited CSPS (central
station protective services), and often accredited CSPS."
The court finds that, even in the same city, a single customer
seeking protection for several premises may "exercise its option"
differently for different locations. It may choose
Page 384 U. S. 591
accredited CSPS for one of its locations, and a different type
of service for another.
But the court isolates from all of these alternatives only those
services in which defendants engage. It eliminates all of the
alternative sources, despite its conscientious enumeration of them.
Its definition of the "relevant market" is not merely confined to
"central station" protective services, but to those central station
protective services which are "accredited" by insurance
companies.
There is no pretense that these furnish peculiar services for
which there is no alternative in the market place, on either a
price or a functional basis. The court relies solely upon its
finding that the services offered by accredited central stations
are of better quality, and upon its conclusion that the insurance
companies tend to give "noticeably larger" discounts to
policyholders who use accredited central station protective
services. This Court now approves this strange red-haired, bearded,
one-eyed "man with a limp" classification.
The unreality of the trial court's market definition may best be
illustrated by an example. Consider the situation of a retail
merchant in Pittsburgh who wishes to protect his store against
burglary. The Holmes Electric Protective Company, a subsidiary of
Grinnell, operates an accredited central station service in
Pittsburgh. It provides only burglary protection.
The gerrymandered market definition approved today totally
excludes from the market consideration of the availability in
Pittsburgh of cheaper but somewhat less reliable local alarm
systems, or of more expensive (although the expense is reduced by
greater insurance discounts) watchman service, or even of
unaccredited central station service which virtually duplicates the
Holmes service.
Instead, and in the name of "commercial realities," we are
instructed that the "relevant market" -- which totally
Page 384 U. S. 592
excludes these locally available alternatives -- requires us to
look only to accredited central station service, and that we are to
include in the "market" central stations which do not furnish
burglary protection, and even those which serve such places as
Boston and Honolulu. [
Footnote
2/6]
Moreover, we are told that the "relevant market" must assume
this strange and curious configuration despite evidence in the
record and a finding of the trial court that "fringe competition"
from such locally available alternatives as watchmen, local alarm
systems, proprietary systems, and unaccredited central stations
has, in at least 20 cities, forced the defendants to operate at a
"loss" even though defendants have a total monopoly in these cities
of the "market" -- namely, the "accredited central station
protective services." And we are led to this odd result even though
there is in the record abundant evidence that customers switch from
one form of property protection to another, and not always in the
direction of accredited central station service.
I believe this approach has no justification in economics,
reason, or law. It might be supportable if it were found that the
accredited central stations offer services which are unique in the
sense that potential buyers -- or at least a substantial,
identifiable part of the trade -- look only to them for the
services in question, and that neither cost, type, quality of
service nor other factors bring competing services into the market.
The findings here and the record do not permit this conclusion.
The Government's market definition, accepted by the trial court,
is a distortion which inevitably leads to a superficial and
distorted results even in the hands of a highly skilled judge. As
this Court held in
Brown Shoe, supra, the "reasonable
interchangeability of use or the
Page 384 U. S. 593
cross-elasticity of demand," determines the boundaries of a
product market. 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 325.
See also the
Cellophane Case, 351 U.S. at
351 U. S. 380.
In plain language, this means that the court should have defined
the relevant market here to include all services which, in light of
geographic availability, price, and use characteristics, are in
realistic rivalry for all or some part of the business of
furnishing protective services to premises. In the present
situation, however, the court's own findings show that practical
alternatives are available to potential users -- although they vary
from market to market and possibly from user to user. These have
been arbitrarily excluded from the court's definition.
I do not suggest that wide disparities in quality, price and
customer appeal could never affect the definition of the market.
But this follows only where the disparities are so great that they
create separate and distinct categories of buyers and sellers. The
record here and the findings do not approach this standard. They
fall far short of justifying the narrowing of the market as
practiced here. I need refer only to the exclusion of nonaccredited
central stations, which the court seeks to justify by reference to
differentials in insurance discounts. These differentials may
indeed affect the relative cost to the consumer of the competing
modes of protection. But, in the absence of proof that they result
in eliminating the competing services from the category of those to
which the purchaser "can practicably turn" for supplies, [
Footnote 2/7] they do not justify such
total exclusion. This sort of exclusion of the supposedly not quite
so attractive service from the basic definition of the kinds of
business and service against which defendants' activity will be
measured is entirely unjustified on this record. [
Footnote 2/8]
Page 384 U. S. 594
The importance of this kind of truncated market definition
vividly appears if we are to say, as the trial court here held,
that if defendant has so large a fraction of the market as to
constitute a "predominant" share, a rebuttable presumption of
monopolization follows. The fraction depends upon the denominator
(the "market") as well as the numerator (the defendants' volume).
Clearly, this "presumption" is unwarranted unless the "market" is
defined to include all competitors. The contrary is not supported
by this Court's decisions in either the
Cellophane Case,
supra, or
United States v. E. I. du Pont De Nemours &
Co. (General Motors), 353 U. S. 586. The
latter case defined the market in terms of the
total
products which could be used for the defined purposes: automobile
fabrics and finishes. This embraces the total range of options for
customers seeking these products. On the contrary, as the record
here shows and as the findings, candidly read, imply, substantial
options exist for services other than through accredited central
stations providing protective services. Those options, whether for
all or a part of the services in issue, must be included in the
assessment of the market.
In the opinion which this Court hands down today, there is
considerable discussion of defendants' argument that the market
should be "broken down" by different
Page 384 U. S. 595
type of service:
e.g., Burglar protection, fire
protection, etc. The Court rejects this on the ground that it is
appropriate to evaluate a "cluster" of services as such. It points
to
Philadelphia Nat. Bank, supra, for support for its
approach. In that case, Mr. Justice Brennan's opinion for the Court
carefully set out the distinctive characteristics of banking
services: that some of these services (
e.g., checking
accounts) are virtually free of competition from other types of
institutions, and that other services are distinctive in cost or
other characteristics. 374 U.S. at
374 U. S.
356-357.
See also United States v. First Nat.
Bank, 376 U. S. 665,
376 U. S. 668
(per Douglas, J.). Similarly, in
United States v. Paramount
Pictures, 334 U. S. 131, and
International Boxing Club v. United States, 358 U.
S. 242,
358 U. S.
249-252, "first-run" moving pictures and championship
boxing matches were held sufficiently distinctive in terms of
demand in the market place to warrant consideration as separate
markets.
But no such distinctiveness exists here. As I have discussed,
neither this record nor the trial court's findings show either a
distinctive demand or a separable market for "insurance accredited
central station protective services." The contrary is evident. None
of the services furnished by accredited central stations is unique,
as I have discussed. Nor is there even a common or predominant
"cluster" of services offered by the central stations. One of the
defendants, Holmes, is engaged only in the burglary alarm business.
Another, AFA, furnishes only fire and waterflow service. Only ADT
among the defendants makes available to its customers the full
"cluster."
I do not mean to suggest that the Government must prove its
case, service by service. But, in defining the market, individual
services, even if furnished in isolation, ought to be specified and
here, as distinguished from the conclusion impelled by the
circumstances in
Page 384 U. S. 596
Philadelphia Nat. Bank, supra, competitors for
individual services ought to be taken into account.
I do not intend by any of the foregoing to suggest that, on this
record, the relief granted by the trial court and the substantially
more drastic relief ordered by this Court would necessarily be
unjustified. It is entirely possible that monopoly or attempt to
monopolize may be found -- and perhaps found with greater force --
in local situations. Relief on a pervasive, system-wide, national
basis might follow, as decreed by the trial court, as well as
divestiture in appropriate local situations, as directed by this
Court. It is impossible, I submit, to make these judgments on the
findings before us because of the distortion due to an incorrect
and unreal definition of the "relevant market." Now, because of
this Court's mandate, the market-by-market inquiry must begin for
purposes of the decree. But this should have been the foundation of
judgment, not its superimposed conclusion. This inquiry should --
in my opinion, it must -- take into account the
total
economic situation -- all of the options available to one seeking
protection services. It should not be limited to central stations,
and certainly not to "insurance accredited central station
protective services" which this Court sanctions as the relevant
market. Since I am of the opinion that defendants and the courts
are entitled to a reappraisal of the liability consequences as well
as the appropriate provisions of the decree on the basis of a sound
definition of the market, I would reverse and remand for these
purposes.
[
Footnote 2/1]
United States v. Continental Can Co., 378 U.
S. 441,
378 U. S.
447-458;
United States v. Alcoa, 377 U.
S. 271,
377 U. S.
273-277;
United States v. Philadelphia Nat.
Bank, 374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 356;
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.
S. 294,
370 U. S.
324.
[
Footnote 2/2]
The defendants constitute 87% of the market as defined. One of
the defendants alone, ADT, has 73%.
[
Footnote 2/3]
See also United States v. First Nat. Bank, 376 U.
S. 665,
376 U. S. 668
(per Douglas, J.);
American Crystal Sugar Co. v. Cuban-American
Sugar Co., 152 F.
Supp. 387, 398 (D.C.S.D.N.Y.1957),
aff'd, 259 F.2d 524
(C.A.2d Cir. 1958).
[
Footnote 2/4]
There is a danger that this Court's opinion,
ante at
384 U. S.
575-576, will be read as somewhat overstating the case.
There is neither finding nor record to support the implication that
rates are to any substantial extent fixed on a nationwide basis, or
that there are nationwide contracts with multi-state businesses in
any significant degree, or that insurers inspect or certify central
stations on a nationwide basis.
[
Footnote 2/5]
See also Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.
S. 294,
370 U. S.
336-337.
[
Footnote 2/6]
None of the stations operated by defendant Automatic Fire Alarm
Company offers burglary protection, just as none of Holmes'
stations protects against the risk of fire.
[
Footnote 2/7]
Tampa Electric Co. v. Nashville Coal Co., 365 U.S. at
365 U. S.
327.
[
Footnote 2/8]
The example used by the court in its findings is illuminating
and disturbing. In explanation of its narrow market definition, the
court says that the diference between the accredited central
station protective services and all others "could be compared" to
the difference between a compact six-cylinder car and a
chauffeur-driven sedan. It is probably true that the degree of
direct competition between luxury automobiles and compacts is
slight, but it is by no means as clear-cut as the trial court seems
to suggest. The question would require careful analysis in light of
the total facts and issues. For example, if the antitrust problem
at hand involved an acquisition of the business of a manufacturer
of compacts by a maker of luxury cars, it is by no means
inconceivable that sufficient competitive overlap would be found to
place both products in the "relevant market."