The Government seeks an order requiring the divestiture, as a
violation of § 7 of the Clayton Act, by Continental Can
Company (CCC), the second largest producer of metal containers, of
the assets acquired in 1956 of Hazel-Atlas Glass Company (HAG), the
third largest producer of glass containers. CCC, which had a
history of acquiring other companies, produced no glass containers
in 1955, but shipped 33% of all metal containers sold in this
country. HAG, which produced no metal containers, shipped 9.6% of
the glass containers that year. The geographic market was held by
the District Court to be the entire country. The Government had
urged ten product markets, including the can industry, the glass
container industry, and various lines of commerce defined by the
end use of the containers. The District Court found three product
markets, metal containers, glass containers, and metal and glass
beer containers. Although finding inter-industry competition
between metal, glass and plastic containers, the District Court
held them to be separate lines of commerce. Holding that the
Government had failed to prove reasonable probability of lessening
competition in any line of commerce, the District Court dismissed
the complaint at the end of the Government's case.
Held:
1. Inter-industry competition between glass and metal containers
may provide the basis for defining a relevant product market. Pp.
378 U. S.
447-458.
(a) The competition protected by § 7 is not limited to that
between identical products. P.
378 U. S.
452.
(b) Cross-elasticity of demand and interchangeability of use are
used to recognize competition where it exists, not to obscure it.
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 326.
P.
378 U. S.
453.
(c) There has been insistent, continuous, effective and
substantial end-use competition between metal and glass containers;
and though interchangeability of use may not be so complete and
cross-elasticity of demand not so immediate as in the case of some
intra-industry mergers, the long-run results bring the competition
between them within § 7. Pp.
378 U. S.
453-455.
Page 378 U. S. 442
(d) There is a large area of effective competition between metal
and glass containers, which implies one or more other lines of
commerce encompassing both industries. Pp.
378 U. S.
456-457.
(e) If an area of effective competition cuts across industry
lines, the relevant line of commerce must do likewise. P.
378 U. S.
457.
(f) Based on the present record, the inter-industry competition
between glass and metal containers warrants treating the combined
glass and metal container industries and all end uses for which
they compete as a relevant product market. P.
378 U. S.
457.
(g) Complete inter-industry competitive overlap is not required
before § 7 is applicable, and some noncompetitive segments in
a proposed market area do not prevent its identification as a line
of commerce. P.
378 U. S.
457.
(h) That there may be a broader product market, including other
competing containers, does not prevent the existence of a submarket
of cans and glass containers. Pp.
378 U. S.
457-458.
2. On the basis of the evidence so far presented, the merger
between CCC and HAG violates § 7 because it will have a
probable anticompetitive effect within the relevant line of
commerce. Pp.
378 U. S.
458-466.
(a) In determining whether a merger will have probable
anticompetitive effect, it must be looked at functionally in the
context of the market involved, its structure, history, and future.
P.
378 U. S.
458.
(b) Where a merger is of such magnitude as to be inherently
suspect, detailed market analysis and proof of likely lessening of
competition are not required in view of § 7's purpose of
preventing undue concentration. P.
378 U. S.
458.
(c) The product market of the combined metal and glass container
industries was dominated by six companies, of which CCC ranked
second and HAG sixth. P.
378 U. S.
461.
(d) The 25% of the product market held by the merged firms
approaches the percentage found presumptively bad in
United
States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.
S. 321, and nearly the same as that involved in
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.
S. 271, and the addition to CCC's share is larger here
than in
Aluminum Co. P.
378 U. S.
461.
(e) Where there has been a trend toward concentration in an
industry, any further concentration should be stopped. P.
378 U. S.
461.
(f) Where an industry is already highly concentrated, it is
important to prevent even slight increases therein. Pp.
378 U. S.
461-462.
Page 378 U. S. 443
(g) The argument that CCC's and HAG's products were not in
direct competition at the time of the merger, and that therefore
the merger could have no effect on competition, ignores the fact
that the removal of HAG as an independent factor in the glass
container industry and in the combined metal and glass container
market foreclosed its potential competition with CCC, neglects the
further fact that CCC, already a dominant firm in an oligopolistic
market, has increased its power and effectiveness, and fails to
consider the triggering effect that a merger of such large
companies has on the rest of the industry, which seeks to follow
the pattern, with anticompetitive results. Pp.
378 U. S.
462-465.
217 F.
Supp. 761, reversed and remanded.
MR. JUSTICE WHITE delivered the opinion of the Court.
In 1956, Continental Can Company, the Nation's second largest
producer of metal containers, acquired all of the assets, business
and good will of Hazel-Atlas Glass Company, the Nation's third
largest producer of glass containers, in exchange for 999,140
shares of Continental's common stock and the assumption by
Continental of all the liabilities of Hazel-Atlas. The Government
brought this action seeking a judgment that the acquisition
violated § 7 of the Clayton Act [
Footnote 1] and requesting an
Page 378 U. S. 444
appropriate divestiture order. Trying the case without a jury,
the District Court found that the Government had failed to prove
reasonable probability of anticompetitive effect in any line of
commerce, and accordingly dismissed the complaint at the close of
the Government's case.
United States v. Continental Can
Co., 217 F.
Supp. 761 (D.C.S.D.N.Y.). We noted probable jurisdiction to
consider the specialized problems incident to the application of
§ 7 to inter-industry mergers and acquisitions. [
Footnote 2] 375 U.S. 893. We reverse the
decision of the District Court.
I
The industries with which this case is principally concerned
are, as found by the trial court, the metal can industry, the glass
container industry, and the plastic container industry, each
producing one basic type of container made of metal, glass, and
plastic, respectively.
Continental Can is a New York corporation organized in 1913 to
acquire all the assets of three metal container
Page 378 U. S. 445
manufacturers. Since 1913, Continental has acquired 21 domestic
metal container companies, as well as numerous others engaged in
the packaging business, including producers of flexible packaging;
a manufacturer of polyethylene bottles and similar plastic
containers; 14 producers of paper containers and paperboard; four
companies making closures for glass containers; and one --
Hazel-Atlas -- producing glass containers. In 1955, the year prior
to the present merger, Continental, with assets of $382 million,
was the second largest company in the metal container field,
shipping approximately 33% of all such containers sold in the
United States. It and the largest producer, American Can Company,
accounted for approximately 71% of all metal container shipments.
National Can Company, the third largest, shipped approximately 5%,
with the remaining 24% of the market being divided among 75 to 90
other firms. [
Footnote 3]
During 1956, Continental acquired not only the Hazel-Atlas
Company, but also Robert Gair Company, Inc. -- a leading
manufacturer of paper and paperboard products -- and White Cap
Company -- a leading producer of vacuum-type metal closures for
glass food containers -- so that Continental's assets rose from
$382 million in 1955
Page 378 U. S. 446
to more than $633 million in 1956, and its net sales and
operating revenues during that time increased from $666 million to
more than $1 billion.
Hazel-Atlas was a West Virginia corporation which, in 1955, had
net sales in excess of $79 million and assets of more than $37
million. Prior to the absorption of Hazel-Atlas into Continental,
the pattern of dominance among a few firms in the glass container
industry was similar to that which prevailed in the metal container
field. Hazel-Atlas, with approximately 9.6% of the glass container
shipments in 1955, was third. Owens-Illinois Glass Company had
34.2% and Anchor-Hocking Glass Company 11.6%, with the remaining
44.6% being divided among at least 39 other firms. [
Footnote 4]
After an initial attempt to prevent the merger under a 1950
consent decree failed, the terms of the decree being
Page 378 U. S. 447
held inapplicable to the proposed acquisition, the Government
moved for a preliminary injunction against its consummation and
sought a temporary restraining order pending the determination of
its motion. The temporary restraining order was denied, and, on the
same day, the merger was accomplished. The Government then withdrew
its motion for a preliminary injunction and continued the action as
one for divestiture.
At the conclusion of the Government's case, Continental moved
for dismissal of the complaint. After the District Court had
granted the motion under Rule 41(b) of the Federal Rules of Civil
Procedure, but before a formal opinion was filed, this Court handed
down its decision in
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States,
370 U. S. 294;
additional briefs directed to the applicability of
Brown
Shoe were filed. The trial judge held that, under the
guidelines laid down by
Brown Shoe, the Government had not
established its right to relief under § 7 of the Clayton Act.
This appeal followed.
II
We deal first with the relevant market. It is not disputed here,
and the District Court held, that the geographical market is the
entire United States. As for the product market, the court found,
as was conceded by the parties, that the can industry and the glass
container industry were relevant lines of commerce. Beyond these
two product markets, however, the Government urged the recognition
of various other lines of commerce, some of them defined in terms
of the end uses for which tin and glass containers were in
substantial competition. These end-use claims were containers for
the beer industry, containers for the soft drink industry,
containers for the canning industry, containers for the toiletry
and cosmetic industry, containers for the medicine and health
industry, and containers for the household and chemical industry.
217 F. Supp. at 778-779.
Page 378 U. S. 448
The court, in dealing with these claims, recognized that there
was inter-industry competition, and made findings as to its extent
and nature:
"[T]here was substantial and vigorous inter-industry competition
between these three industries and between various of the products
which they manufactured. Metal can, glass container and plastic
container manufacturers were each seeking to enlarge their sales to
the thousands of packers of hundreds of varieties of food,
chemical, toiletry and industrial products, ranging from ripe
olives to fruit juices to tuna fish to smoked tongue; from maple
syrup to pet food to coffee; from embalming fluid to floor wax to
nail polish to aspirin to veterinary supplies, to take examples at
random."
"Each industry and each of the manufacturers within it was
seeking to improve their products so that they would appeal to new
customers or hold old ones."
217 F. Supp. at 780-781. Furthermore the court found that:
"Hazel-Atlas and Continental were part of this overall
industrial pattern, each in a recognized separate industry
producing distinct products but engaged in inter-industry
competition for the favor of various end users of their
products."
Id. at 781. The court, nevertheless, with one exception
-- containers for beer -- rejected the Government's claim that
existing competition between metal and glass containers had
resulted in the end-use product markets urged by the
Government:
"The fact that there is inter-industry or inter-product
competition between metal, glass and plastic containers is not
determinative of the metes and bounds of a relevant product
market."
Ibid. In the trial court's view, the Government failed
to make
"appropriate distinctions . . . between inter-industry or
overall commodity
Page 378 U. S. 449
competition and the type of competition between products with
reasonable interchangeability of use and cross-elasticity of demand
which has Clayton Act significance."
Id. at 781-782. The inter-industry competition,
concededly present, did not remove this merger from the category of
the conglomerate combination,
"in which one company in two separate industries combined with
another in a third industry for the purpose of establishing a
diversified line of products."
Id. at 782.
We cannot accept this conclusion. The District Court's findings
having established the existence of three product markets -- metal
containers, glass containers and metal and glass beer containers --
the disputed issue on which that court erred is whether the
admitted competition between metal and glass containers for uses
other than packaging beer was of the type and quality deserving of
§ 7 protection, and therefore the basis for defining a
relevant product market. In resolving this issue, we are
instructed, on the one hand, that, "[f]or every product,
substitutes exist. But a relevant market cannot meaningfully
encompass that infinite range."
Times-Picayune v. United
States, 345 U. S. 594,
345 U. S. 612,
n. 31. On the other hand, it is improper "to require that products
be fungible to be considered in the relevant market."
United
States v. E. I. du Pont De Nemours & Co., 351 U.
S. 377,
351 U.S.
394. In defining the product market between these terminal
extremes, we must recognize meaningful competition where it is
found to exist. Though the
"outer boundaries of a product market are determined by the
reasonable interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of
demand between the product itself and substitutes for it,"
there may be, "within this broad market, well-defined submarkets
. . . which, in themselves, constitute product markets for
antitrust purposes."
Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v. United
States, 370 U. S. 294,
370 U. S. 325.
Concededly these guidelines offer no precise formula for judgment,
and they necessitate, rather than avoid, careful consideration
based upon the entire record.
Page 378 U. S. 450
It is quite true that glass and metal containers have different
characteristics which may disqualify one or the other, at least in
their present form, from this or that particular use; that the
machinery necessary to pack in glass is different from that
employed when cans are used; that a particular user of cans or
glass may pack in only one or the other container, and does not
shift back and forth from day to day as price and other factors
might make desirable; and that the competition between metal and
glass containers is different from the competition between the can
companies themselves or between the products of the different glass
companies. These are relevant and important considerations, but
they are not sufficient to obscure the competitive relationships
which this record so compellingly reveals.
Baby food was at one time packed entirely in metal cans.
Hazel-Atlas played a significant role in inducing the shift to
glass as the dominant container by designing "what has become the
typical baby food jar." According to Continental's estimate, 80% of
the Nation's baby food now moves in glass containers. Continental
has not been satisfied with this contemporary dominance by glass,
however, and has made intensive efforts to increase its share of
the business at the expense of glass. In 1954, two years before the
merger, the Director of Market Research and Promotion for the Glass
Container Manufacturers Institute concluded, largely on the basis
of Continental's efforts to secure more baby food business, that
"the can industry is beginning to fight back more aggressively in
this field where it is losing ground to glass." In cooperation with
some of the baby food companies, Continental carried out what it
called a Baby Food Depth Survey in New York and Los Angeles to
discover specific reasons for the preference of glass-packed baby
food. Largely in response to this and other in-depth surveys,
advertising campaigns were conducted which were designed
Page 378 U. S. 451
to overcome mothers' prejudices against metal containers.
[
Footnote 5]
In the soft drink business, a field which has been, and is,
predominantly glass territory, the court recognized that the metal
can industry had, "[a]fter considerable initial difficulty . . . ,
developed a can strong enough to resist the pressures generated by
carbonated beverages" and "made strenuous efforts to promote the
use of metal cans for carbonated beverages as against glass
bottles." 217 F. Supp. at 798. Continental has been a major factor
in this rivalry. It studied the results of market tests to
determine the extent to which metal cans could "penetrate this
tremendous market," and its advertising has centered around the
advantages of cans over glass as soft drink containers, emphasizing
such features as convenience in stacking and storing, freedom from
breakage. and lower distribution costs resulting from the lighter
weight of cans.
The District Court found that,
"[a]lthough, at one time, almost all packaged beer was sold in
bottles, in a relatively short period, the beer can made great
headway, and may well have become the dominant beer container."
217 F. Supp. at 795. Regardless of which industry may have the
upper hand at a given moment, however, an
Page 378 U. S. 452
intense competitive battle on behalf of the beer can and the
beer bottle is being waged both by the industry trade associations
and by individual container manufacturers, one of the principal
protagonists being Continental. Technological development has been
an important weapon in this battle. A significant factor in the
growth of the beer can appears to have been its no-return feature.
The glass industry responded with the development of a lighter and
cheaper one-way bottle.
In the food canning, toiletry and cosmetic, medicine and health,
and household and chemical industries, the existence of vigorous
competition was also recognized below. In the case of food, it was
noted that one type of container has supplanted the other in the
packing of some products, and that, in some instances, similar
products are packaged in two or more different types of containers.
In the other industries,
"glass container, plastic container, and metal container
manufacturers are each seeking to promote their lines of containers
at the expense of other lines; . . . all are attempting to improve
their products or to develop new ones so as to have a wider
customer appeal,"
217 F. Supp. at 804, the result being that "manufacturers from
time to time may shift a product from one type of container to
another."
Id. at 805.
In the light of this record and these findings, we think the
District Court employed an unduly narrow construction of the
"competition" protected by § 7 and of "reasonable
interchangeability of use or the cross-elasticity of demand" in
judging the facts of this case. We reject the opinion below insofar
as it holds that these terms, as used in the statute or in
Brown Shoe, were intended to limit the competition
protected by § 7 to competition between identical products, to
the kind of competition which exists, for example, between the
metal containers of one company and those of another, or between
the several manufacturers of glass containers. Certainly, that
Page 378 U. S. 453
the competition here involved may be called "inter-industry
competition" and is between products with distinctive
characteristics does not automatically remove it from the reach of
§ 7.
Interchangeability of use and cross-elasticity of demand are not
to be used to obscure competition, but to "recognize competition
where, in fact, competition exists."
Brown Shoe Co. v. United
States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 326.
In our view, there is and has been a rather general confrontation
between metal and glass containers, and competition between them
for the same end uses which is insistent, continuous, effective
and, quantity-wise, very substantial. Metal has replaced glass, and
glass has replaced metal, as the leading container for some
important uses; both are used for other purposes; each is trying to
expand its share of the market at the expense of the other;
[
Footnote 6] and each is
attempting to preempt for itself every use for which its product is
physically suitable, even though some such uses have traditionally
been regarded as the exclusive domain of the competing industry.
[
Footnote 7] In differing
degrees
Page 378 U. S. 454
for different end uses, manufacturers in each industry take into
consideration the price of the containers of the opposing industry
in formulating their own pricing
Page 378 U. S. 455
policy. [
Footnote 8] Thus,
though the interchangeability of use may not be so complete and the
cross-elasticity of demand not so immediate as in the case of most
intra-industry mergers, there is, over the long run, the kind of
customer response to innovation and other competitive stimuli that
brings the competition between these two industries within §
7's competition-preserving proscriptions.
Moreover, price is only one factor in a user's choice between
one container or the other. That there are price differentials
between the two products, or that the demand for one is not
particularly or immediately responsive to changes in the price of
the other, are relevant matters, but not determinative of the
product market issue. Whether a packager will use glass or cans may
depend not only on the price of the package, but also upon other
equally important considerations. The consumer, for example, may
begin to prefer one type of container over the other, and the
manufacturer of baby food cans may therefore find that his problem
is the housewife, rather
Page 378 U. S. 456
than the packer or the price of his cans. [
Footnote 9] This may not be price competition, but
it is nevertheless meaningful competition between interchangeable
containers.
We therefore conclude that the area of effective competition
between the metal and glass container industry is far broader than
that of containers for beer. It is true that the record in this
case does not identify with particularity all end uses for which
competition exists and all those for which competition may be
nonexistent, too remote, or too ephemeral to warrant § 7
application. Nor does the record furnish the exact quantitative
share of the relevant market which is enjoyed by the individual
participating can and glass companies. But
"[t]he 'market,' as most concepts in law or economics, cannot be
measured by metes and bounds. . . . Obviously no magic inheres in
numbers."
Times-Picayune v. United States, 345 U.
S. 594,
345 U. S.
611-612. "Industrial activities cannot be confined to
trim categories."
United States v. E. I. du Pont De Nemours
& Co., 351 U. S. 377,
351 U. S. 395.
The claimed deficiencies in the record cannot sweep aside the
existence of a large area of effective competition between the
makers of cans and the makers of glass containers. We know enough
to conclude that the rivalry between cans and glass containers is
pervasive, and that the area of competitive overlap between these
two product markets is broad enough to make the position of the
individual companies within their own industries very relevant to
the merger's impact within the broader competitive area that
embraces both of the merging firms' respective industries.
Glass and metal containers were recognized to be two separate
lines of commerce. But, given the area of effective
Page 378 U. S. 457
competition between these lines, there is necessarily implied
one or more other lines of commerce embracing both industries.
Since the purpose of delineating a line of commerce is to provide
an adequate basis for measuring the effects of a given acquisition,
its contours must, as nearly as possible, conform to competitive
reality. Where the area of effective competition cuts across
industry lines, so must the relevant line of commerce; otherwise,
an adequate determination of the merger's true impact cannot be
made.
Based on the evidence thus far revealed by this record, we hold
that the inter-industry competition between glass and metal
containers is sufficient to warrant treating as a relevant product
market the combined glass and metal container industries and all
end uses for which they compete. There may be some end uses for
which glass and metal do not and could not compete, but complete
inter-industry competitive overlap need not be shown. We would not
be true to the purpose of the Clayton Act's line of commerce
concept as a framework within which to measure the effect of
mergers on competition were we to hold that the existence of
noncompetitive segments within a proposed market area precludes its
being treated as a line of commerce.
This line of commerce was not pressed upon the District Court.
However, since it is coextensive with the two industries, which
were held to be lines of commerce, and since it is composed
largely, if not entirely, of the more particularized end-use lines
urged in the District Court by the Government, we see nothing to
preclude us from reaching the question of its
prima facie
existence at this stage of the case.
Nor are we concerned by the suggestion that, if the product
market is to be defined in these terms, it must include plastic,
paper, foil and any other materials competing for the same
business. That there may be a
Page 378 U. S. 458
broader product market made up of metal, glass and other
competing containers does not necessarily negative the existence of
submarkets of cans, glass, plastic or cans and glass together, for,
"within this broad market, well defined submarkets may exist which,
in themselves, constitute product markets for antitrust purposes."
Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v. United States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S.
325.
III
We approach the ultimate judgment under § 7 having in mind
the teachings of
Brown Shoe, supplemented by their
application and elaboration in
United States v. Philadelphia
National Bank, 374 U. S. 321; and
United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., 376 U.
S. 651. The issue is whether the merger between
Continental and Hazel-Atlas will have probable anticompetitive
effect within the relevant line of commerce. Market shares are the
primary indicia of market power, but a judgment under § 7 is
not to be made by any single qualitative or quantitative test. The
merger must be viewed functionally in the context of the particular
market involved, its structure, history, and probable future. Where
a merger is of such a size as to be inherently suspect, elaborate
proof of market structure, market behavior, and probable
anticompetitive effects may be dispensed with in view of § 7's
design to prevent undue concentration. Moreover, the competition
with which § 7 deals includes not only existing competition,
but that which is sufficiently probable and imminent.
See
United States v. El Paso Natural Gas Co., supra.
Continental occupied a dominant position in the metal can
industry. It shipped 33% of the metal cans shipped by the industry,
and, together with American, shipped about 71% of the industry
total. Continental's share amounted to 13 billion metal containers
out of a total of 40 billion, and its $433 million gross sales of
metal containers
Page 378 U. S. 459
amounted to 31.4% of the industry's total gross of
$1,380,000,000. Continental's total assets were $382 million, its
net sales and operating revenues $666 million.
In addition to demonstrating the dominant position of
Continental in a highly concentrated industry, the District Court's
findings clearly revealed Continental's vigorous efforts all across
the competitive front between metal and glass containers.
Continental obviously pushed metal containers wherever metal
containers could be pushed. Its share of the beer can market ran
from 43% in 1955 to 46% in 1957. Its share of both beer can and
beer bottle shipments, disregarding the returnable bottle factor,
ran from 36% in 1955 to 38% in 1957. Although metal cans have so
far occupied a relatively small percentage of the soft drink
container field, Continental's share of this can market ranged from
36% in 1955 to 26% in 1957, and its portion of the total shipments
of glass and metal soft drink and beverage containers, disregarding
the returnable bottle factor, was 7.2% in 1955, approximately 5.4%
in 1956, and approximately 6.2% in 1957 (for 1956 and 1957, these
figures include Hazel-Atlas' share). In the category covering all
nonfood products, Continental's share was approximately 30% of the
total shipments of metal containers for such uses.
Continental's major position in the relevant product market --
the combined metal and glass container industries -- prior to the
merger is undeniable. Of the 59 billion containers shipped in 1955
by the metal (39 3/4 billion) and glass (19 1/3 billion)
industries, Continental shipped 21.9%, to a great extent dispersed
among all of the end uses for which glass and metal compete.
[
Footnote 10] Of the six
largest firms in the product market, it ranked second.
Page 378 U. S. 460
When Continental acquired Hazel-Atlas, it added significantly to
its position in the relevant line of commerce. Hazel-Atlas was the
third largest glass container manufacturer in an industry in which
the three top companies controlled 55.4% of the total shipments of
glass containers. Hazel-Atlas' share was 9.6%, which amounted to
1,857,000,000 glass containers out of a total of 19 1/3 billion
industrial total. Its annual sales amounted to $79 million, its
assets exceeded $37 million, and it had 13 plants variously located
in the United States. In terms of total containers shipped,
Hazel-Atlas ranked sixth in the relevant line of commerce, its
almost 2 billion containers being 3.1% of the product market
total.
Page 378 U. S. 461
The evidence so far presented leads us to conclude that the
merger between Continental and Hazel-Atlas is in violation of
§ 7. The product market embracing the combined metal and glass
container industries was dominated by six firms having a total of
70.1% of the business. [
Footnote
11] Continental, with 21.9% of the shipments, ranked second
within this product market, and Hazel-Atlas, with 3.1%, ranked
sixth. Thus, of this vast market -- amounting at the time of the
merger to almost $3 billion in annual sales -- a large percentage
already belonged to Continental before the merger. By the
acquisition of Hazel-Atlas stock, Continental not only increased
its own share more than 14%, from 21.9% to 25%, but also reduced
from five to four the most significant competitors who might have
threatened its dominant position. The resulting percentage of the
combined firms approaches that held presumptively bad in
United
States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.
S. 321, and is almost the same as that involved in
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 377 U.
S. 271. The incremental addition to the acquiring firm's
share is considerably larger than in
Aluminum Co. The case
falls squarely within the principle that, where there has been a
"history of tendency toward concentration in the industry,"
tendencies toward further concentration "are to be curbed in their
incipiency."
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S.
345-346. Where
"concentration is already great, the importance of
preventing
Page 378 U. S. 462
even slight increases in concentration, and so preserving the
possibility of eventual deconcentration is correspondingly
great."
United States v. Philadelphia National Bank,
374 U. S. 321,
374 U. S. 365;
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, supra.
Continental insists, however, that whatever the nature of
inter-industry competition in general, the types of containers
produced by Continental and Hazel-Atlas at the time of the merger
were, for the most part, not in competition with each other, and
hence the merger could have no effect on competition. This argument
ignores several important matters.
First: the District Court found that both Continental and
Hazel-Atlas were engaged in inter-industry competition
characteristic of the glass and metal can industries. While the
position of Hazel-Atlas in the beer and soft drink industries was
negligible in 1955, its position was quite different in other
fields. Hazel-Atlas made both wide-mouthed glass jars and
narrow-necked containers, but more of the former than the latter.
Both are used in packing food, medicine and health supplies,
household and industrial products and toiletries and cosmetics,
among others, and Hazel-Atlas' position in supplying the packaging
needs of these industries was indeed important. In 1955, it shipped
about 8% of the narrow-necked bottles and about 14% of the
widemouthed glass containers for food; about 10% of the
narrow-necked and 40% of the wide-mouthed glass containers for the
household and chemical industry; about 9% of the narrow-necked and
28% of the wide-mouthed glass containers for the toiletries and
cosmetics industry; and about 6% of the narrow-necked and 25% of
the wide-mouthed glass containers for the medicine and health
industry. Continental, as we have said, in 1955 shipped 30% of the
containers used for these same nonfood purposes. In these
industries, the District Court found that the glass container and
metal
Page 378 U. S. 463
container manufacturers were each seeking to promote their lines
of containers at the expense of the other lines, and that all were
attempting to improve their products or to develop new ones so as
to have a wider customer appeal. We think it quite clear that
Continental and Hazel-Atlas were set off directly against one
another in this process, and that the merger therefore carries with
it the probability of foreclosing actual and potential competition
between these two concerns. Hazel-Atlas has been removed as an
independent factor in the glass industry and in the line of
commerce which includes both metal cans and glass containers.
We think the District Court erred in placing heavy reliance on
Continental's management of its Hazel-Atlas division after the
merger, while Continental was under some pressure because of the
pending government antitrust suit. Continental acquired by the
merger the power to guide the development of Hazel-Atlas
consistently with Continental's interest in metal containers;
contrariwise, it may find itself unwilling to push metal containers
to the exclusion of glass for those end uses where Hazel-Atlas is
strong. It has at the same time acquired the ability, know-how and
the capacity to satisfy its customers' demands whether they want
metal or glass containers. Continental need no longer lose
customers to glass companies solely because consumer preference,
perhaps triggered by competitive efforts by the glass container
industry, forces the packer to turn from cans to glass. And no
longer does a Hazel-Atlas customer who has normally packed in glass
have to look elsewhere for metal containers if he discovers that
the can, rather than the jar, will answer some of his pressing
problems.
Second: Continental would view these developments as
representing an acceptable effort by it to diversify its product
lines and to gain the resulting competitive advantages, thereby
strengthening competition which it
Page 378 U. S. 464
declared the antitrust laws are designed to promote. But we
think the answer is otherwise when a dominant firm in a line of
commerce in which market power is already concentrated among a few
firms makes an acquisition which enhances its market power and the
vigor and effectiveness of its own competitive efforts.
Third: a merger between the second and sixth largest competitors
in a gigantic line of commerce is significant not only for its
intrinsic effect on competition, but also for its tendency to
endanger a much broader anticompetitive effect by triggering other
mergers by companies seeking the same competitive advantages sought
by Continental in this case. As the Court said in
Brown
Shoe,
"[i]f a merger achieving 5% control were now approved, we might
be required to approve future merger efforts by Brown's competitors
seeking similar market shares."
370 U.S. at
370 U. S.
343-344.
Fourth: it is not at all self-evident that the lack of current
competition between Continental and Hazel-Atlas for some important
end uses of metal and glass containers significantly diminished the
adverse effect of the merger on competition. Continental might have
concluded that it could effectively insulate itself from
competition by acquiring a major firm not presently directing its
market acquisition efforts toward the same end uses as Continental,
but possessing the potential to do so. Two examples will illustrate
. Both soft drinks and baby food are currently packed predominantly
in glass, but Continental has engaged in vigorous and imaginative
promotional activities attempting to overcome consumer preferences
for glass and secure a larger share of these two markets for its
tin cans. Hazel-Atlas was not, at the time of the merger, a
significant producer of either of these containers, but, with
comparatively little difficulty, if it were an independent firm
making independent business judgments,
Page 378 U. S. 465
it could have developed its soft drink and baby food capacity.
The acquisition of Hazel-Atlas by a company engaged in such intense
efforts to effect a diversion of business from glass to metal in
both of these lines cannot help but diminish the likelihood of
Hazel-Atlas' realizing its potential as a significant competitor in
either line. Our view of the record compels us to disagree with the
District Court's conclusion that Continental, as a result of the
merger, was not "likely to cease being an innovator in either [the
glass or metal container] line." 217 F. Supp. at 790. It would make
little sense for one entity within the Continental empire to be
busily engaged in persuading the public of metal's superiority over
glass for a given and use, while the other is making plans to
increase the Nation's total glass container output for that same
end use. Thus, the fact that Continental and Hazel-Atlas were not
substantial competitors of each other for certain end uses at the
time of the merger may actually enhance the long-run tendency of
the merger to lessen competition.
We think our holding is consonant with the purpose of § 7
to arrest anticompetitive arrangements in their incipiency. Some
product lines are offered in both metal and glass containers by the
same packer. In such areas, the interchangeability of use and
immediate inter-industry sensitivity to price changes would
approach that which exists between products of the same industry.
In other lines, as where one packer's products move in one type
container while his competitor's move in another, there are
inherent deterrents to customer diversion of the same type that
might occur between brands of cans or bottles. But the possibility
of such transfers over the long run acts as a deterrent against
attempts by the dominant members of either industry to reap the
possible benefits of their position by raising prices above the
competitive
Page 378 U. S. 466
level or engaging in other comparable practices. And even though
certain lines are today regarded as safely within the domain of one
or the other of these industries, this pattern may be altered, as
it has been in the past. From the point of view not only of the
static competitive situation, but also the dynamic long-run
potential, we think that the Government has discharged its burden
of proving
prima facie anticompetitive effect. Accordingly
the judgment is reversed and the case remanded for further
proceedings consistent with this opinion.
Reversed.
[
Footnote 1]
1. Section 7 of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 731, as amended by the
Celler-Kefauver Antimerger Act, 64 Stat. 1125, 15 U.S.C. § 18,
provides in relevant part:
"No corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the
Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the
assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in
any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of
such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to
tend to create a monopoly."
[
Footnote 2]
Both parties and the District Court refer to this as an
inter-industry merger. The word "industry" is susceptible of more
than one meaning. It might be defined in terms of end uses for
which various products compete; so defined, it would be roughly
equivalent to the concept of a "line of commerce." According to
this interpretation, the glass and metal container businesses, to
the extent they compete, are in the same industry. On the other
hand, "industry" might also denote an aggregate of enterprises
employing similar production and marketing facilities and producing
products having markedly similar characteristics. In many
instances, the segments of economic endeavor embraced by these two
concepts of "industry" will be substantially coextensive, since
those who employ the same types of machinery to turn out the same
general product often compete in the same market. Since this is not
such a case, it will be helpful to use the word "industry" as
referring to similarity of production facilities and products. So
viewed, "inter-industry competition" becomes a meaningful
concept.
[
Footnote 3]
The District Court found that the basic raw material used in the
manufacture of cans, and the major cost factor bearing on their
price is tin-coated steel (tin plate). In some instances, uncoated
steel (blackplate) or aluminum is used instead of tin plate. Other
raw materials include soldering compounds, paints, varnishes,
lithographic inks, paper and cartons for packaging. Cans are rigid
and unbreakable, can be hermetically sealed, and are impermeable to
gases. They are lighter than glass containers, can be
heat-processed faster, and are not chemically inert.
Forty-nine members of the metal can industry are organized in a
trade association known as the Can Manufacturers Institute, which
maintains a professional staff of three. Acting largely through
committees, it deals with various technical problems of the
industry and carries out some promotional activities emphasizing
the advantages of the metal can.
[
Footnote 4]
According to the findings of the District Court, glass
containers are made principally from sand, lime, and soda ash, and
the major factor in determining their price is the cost of labor.
Glass containers are rigid, breakable, and chemically inert. They
can be hermetically sealed and, unlike many cans, can be easily
resealed after they have been opened. The industry recognizes two
basic types of containers, the wide mouth and the narrow neck.
Members of this industry also have a trade association, the Glass
Container Manufacturers Institute, which, through its 45 employees
and its standing committees, carries on such activities as market
research and promotion, technical research, package design and
specifications, the development of standard testing and quality
control procedures, problems of freight rates, labor relations, and
liaison work with government. In recent decades, the expansion of
the glass container industry has been more rapid than, and often
realized at the expense of, the metal can industry. During World
War II, for example, substantial increments in the market served by
glass container manufacturers were made possible by the short
supply of tin plate.
The third industry found by the District Court to be involved in
this multi-industry competitive picture was the plastic container
industry, which, though a relative newcomer, has enjoyed impressive
growth since making its debut in the mid-1940's. Its dollar sales
volume is small compared with that of its metal and glass
counterparts, but its growth has been and continues to be steady
and rapid.
[
Footnote 5]
In 1952, Continental ran a series of advertisements emphasizing
the following "5 reasons why cans are an ideal container for baby
foods:"
"1. ECONOMICAL. Baby food in cans is usually priced as low or
lower than baby food packed in other containers."
"2. STERILE. Processing sterilizes the inside, and light, dust
and germs can't get into a hermetically sealed can."
"3. EXTRA SAFETY. Cans are sealed to stay sealed until the
consumer opens them."
"4. SHATTERPROOF. Steel and tin won't break, shatter or
chip."
"5. SAFE FOR LEFT-OVERS. Food can be safely left in the can,
just keep it covered and under refrigeration."
[
Footnote 6]
Consumer preferences for glass or metal are often regional, and
traceable to factors other than the intrinsic superiority of the
preferred container. For example, the one-way beer bottle was
highly successful in Baltimore -- due in part to the efforts of "a
highly motivated leading brewer" -- but failed to make headway in
Detroit. And though glass appears to have about 80% of the Nation's
baby food business, as of the time of the merger, cans had over 60%
of the business west of the Mississippi. According to one opinion
in the record, all Canadian baby food moves in cans. And an
official of the Glass Container Manufacturers Institute reported to
that body that pickles, preserves, and jams are packed in tin cans
in Canada.
[
Footnote 7]
Ford Sammis & Company, a firm of market economists,
conducted for the Glass Container Manufacturers Institute market
surveys of 28 different product classifications. On the basis of
over 3 1/4 million individual answers to questions asked in more
than 12,000 personal interviews, Ford Sammis concluded the
following:
"Every consumer product tends to standardize on a single type of
container. Glass has become the standard, traditional container for
a host of products, including catsup, salad dressings, salad oil,
instant coffee, prune juice, mayonnaise, peanut butter, jams and
syrup. Other products have standardized on tin cans -- regular
coffee, evaporated milk, dog food, and most fruits, vegetables and
juices."
"However, no traditional market is ever secure for any type of
container. Marketers are apt to try out new containers at any time,
in their constant search for ways to increase sales."
"When this happens, the result is a period of container
competition, which may run through one or more of three separate
stages."
1. Stage 1, according to the Sammis report, occurs when a new
type of container is first introduced by a secondary brand.
Thus,
"[a] new container can become a potent sales force for a brand
if strong consumer preference exists (or is promoted) for that type
of container. Recognizing this, secondary brands are constantly
trying out new types of containers as sales incentive. While
leading brands are ordinarily satisfied to maintain the
status
quo, secondary brands are willing to gamble to improve their
positions."
2. The second stage comes about in this manner:
"If a secondary brand increases its sales during the period when
it is introducing a new type of container, the sales increase is
usually attributed to the new container by marketer and competitors
alike. Advertising, product changes or other factors may actually
be more important than the new container, but circumstantial
evidence points to the container."
"Leading brands are not prone to sit idly by while competitors
cut into their share of the market. They tend to cover competitors'
bets by offering both traditional and new types of containers to
their customers. This creates Stage 2 of container
competition."
3.
"When leading brands are available in a choice of containers,
consumers' container preference is no longer in conflict with their
brand preferences. They can have the brand they want in the
container the want. Sales of leading brands under these
circumstances seek the level of consumer preference for each type
of container."
"If preference for one type of container greatly exceeds
preference for the other type, the products then tends
[
sic] eventually to standardize once again on a single
type of container -- the container most consumers prefer. This
process is subject to promotion of container by brand marketers or
container manufacturers. The alternate outcome can be favorable to
either the new or the traditional container."
[
Footnote 8]
The chairman of the board of Owens-Illinois Glass Co. testified
that he takes into account the price of metal containers in pricing
glass containers for beer, soft drinks, and household and chemical
products, and, to a lesser degree, for toiletries and cosmetics. In
assessing the likelihood that it could "penetrate [the] tremendous
market" for soft drink containers, Continental concluded:
"[a]ssuming that the merchandising factors are favorable, and
that the product quality is well received, the upper limit on
market acceptance will then be determined by price."
Continental also stated in an inter-company memorandum that, in
the fight between the beer can and the one-way bottle, "[t]he key
factor, in our estimation, is pricing," and concluded that a
reduction in the price of one-way beer bottles was to "be regarded
as a further attempt on the part of the glass manufacturers to
maintain their position in the one-way package field."
[
Footnote 9]
An official of the Glass Container Manufacturers Institute
described that organization's advertising program as three-pronged,
directed at the packer, the retailer, and the ultimate
consumer.
[
Footnote 10]
Determination of market shares is made somewhat more difficult
in this case than in the ordinary intra-industry merger because the
indices of total production of the two industries are expressed
differently, the metal container industry reporting to the Census
Bureau in terms of tinplate consumed in manufacture, and the glass
container industry in terms of units of containers. On the basis of
figures and data supplied by the Census Bureau and the Can
Manufacturers Institute, the Government has derived a conversion
factor showing the relationship between tinplate consumption and
total containers manufactured, thereby permitting a comparison of
the relative positions of the firms competing within the glass and
metal container line of commerce. It would appear that the District
Court relied on figures disclosed by application of this factor,
since it found that American and Continental shipped approximately
38% and 33%, respectively, of the metal cans sold in the United
States. 217 F. Supp. at 773.
Continental objects to the use of this conversion scheme,
however, arguing that it ignores such considerations as size of
cans and the returnable feature of some types of bottles. We are
not persuaded. Since different systems of statistical notation are
employed by these industries, a common referential standard is an
absolute prerequisite to a comparison of market shares. Consistent
with this Court's declarations in other cases concerning the high
degree of relevance of market shares to the effect of mergers on
competition, we believe that slight variations one way or the other
which may inhere in the use of a conversion formula should not
blind us to the broad significance of the resulting percentages. In
the compilation of statistics, "precision in detail is less
important than the accuracy of the broad picture presented."
Brown Shoe Co. v. United States, 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 342,
n. 69.
[
Footnote 11]
The six largest firms, and their respective percentages of the
relevant market as of the year prior to the merger are:
American Can Co. 26.8%
Continental Can Co. 21.9%
Owens-Illinois Glass Co. 11.2%
Anchor-Hocking Glass Co. 3.8%
National Can Co. 3.3%
Hazel-Atlas Glass Co. 3.1%
------
Total 70.1%
MR. JUSTICE GOLDBERG, concurring.
I fully agree with the Court that,
"[s]ince the purpose of delineating a line of commerce is to
provide an adequate basis for measuring the effects of a given
acquisition, its contours must, as nearly as possible, conform to
competitive reality."
Ante at p.
378 U. S. 457.
I also agree that, "on the evidence thus far revealed by this
record," there has been a
prima facie showing
"that the inter-industry competition between glass and metal
containers . . . [warrants] treating as a relevant product market
the combined glass and metal container industries and all end uses
for which they compete."
Ibid. I wish to make it clear, however, that, as I read
the opinion of the Court, the Court does not purport finally to
decide the determinative line of commerce. Since the District Court
"dismissed the complaint at the close of the Government's case,"
ante at p.
378 U. S. 444,
upon remand, it will be open to the defendants not only to rebut
the
prima facie inference that metal and glass containers
may be considered together as a line of commerce, but also to prove
that plastic or other containers in fact compete with metal and
glass to such an extent that, as a matter of "competitive reality,"
they must be considered as part of the determinative line of
commerce.
Page 378 U. S. 467
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN, whom MR. JUSTICE STEWART joins,
dissenting.
Measured by any antitrust yardsticks with which I am familiar,
the Court's conclusions are, to say the least, remarkable. Before
the merger which is the subject of this case, Continental Can
manufactured metal containers and Hazel-Atlas manufactured glass
containers. [
Footnote 2/1] The
District Court found, with ample support in the record, that the
Government had wholly failed to prove that the merger of these two
companies would adversely affect competition in the metal container
industry, in the glass container industry, or between the metal
container industry and the glass container industry. Yet this Court
manages to strike down the merger under § 7 of the Clayton Act
because, in the Court's view, it is anticompetitive. [
Footnote 2/2] With all respect, the Court's
conclusion is based on erroneous analysis, which makes an abrupt
and unwise departure from established antitrust law.
I agree fully with the Court that "we must recognize meaningful
competition where it is found,"
ante, p.
378 U. S. 449,
and that "inter-industry" competition, such as that involved in
this case, no less than "intra-industry" competition, is protected
by § 7 from anticompetitive mergers. As
Page 378 U. S. 468
this Court has, in effect, recognized in past cases, the concept
of an "industry," or "line of commerce" is not susceptible of
reduction to a precise formula.
See Brown Shoe Co., Inc. v.
United States, 370 U. S. 294,
370 U. S. 325;
United States v. E. I. du Pont de Nemours & Co.,
351 U. S. 377,
351 U.S. 394-396;
Times-Picayune Publishing Co. v. United States,
345 U. S. 594,
345 U. S. 611.
It would, therefore, be artificial and inconsistent with the broad
protective purpose of § 7,
see Brown Shoe, supra, at
370 U. S.
311-323, to attempt to differentiate between permitted
and prohibited mergers merely by asking whether a probable
reduction in competition, if it is found, will be within a single
"industry" or between two or more "industries."
Recognition that the purpose of § 7 is not to be thwarted
by limiting its protection to intramural competition within
strictly defined "industries" does not mean, however, that the
concept of a "line of commerce" is no longer serviceable. More
precisely, it does not, as the majority seems to think, entail the
conclusion that, wherever "meaningful competition" exists, a "line
of commerce" is to be found. The Court declares the initial
question of this case to be
"whether the admitted competition between metal and glass
containers for uses other than packaging beer was of the type and
quality deserving of § 7 protection and
therefore the
basis for defining a relevant product market."
Ante, p.
378 U. S. 449.
(Emphasis added.) And the Court's answer is similarly phrased:
". . . [W]e hold that
the inter-industry competition
between glass and metal containers
is sufficient to warrant
treating as a relevant product market the combined glass and
metal container industries and all end uses for which they
compete."
Ante, p.
378 U. S. 457.
(Emphasis added.) Quite obviously, such a conclusion simply reads
the "line of commerce" element out of § 7, and destroys its
usefulness as an aid to analysis.
The distortions to which this approach leads are evidenced by
the Court's application of it in this case.
Page 378 U. S. 469
Having found that there is "inter-industry competition between
glass and metal containers," the Court concludes that "the combined
glass and metal container industries" is the relevant line of
commerce or "product market" in which anticompetitive effects must
be measured.
Ante, p.
378 U. S. 457.
Applying that premise, the Court then notes Continental's "dominant
position" in the
metal can industry, ante, p.
378 U. S. 458,
and finds that Continental has a "major position" in the "relevant
product market --
the combined metal and glass container
industries,"
ante, p.
378 U. S. 459.
(Emphasis added.) Hazel-Atlas, being the third largest producer of
glass containers, is found to rank sixth in the relevant
product market -- again, the combined metal and glass container
industries.
Ante, p.
378 U. S. 460.
This "evidence," coupled with the market shares of Continental and
Hazel-Atlas in the combined product market, [
Footnote 2/3] leads the Court to conclude that the
merger violates § 7.
"The resulting percentage of the combined firms," the Court
says, "approaches that held presumptively bad in
United States
v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.
S. 321."
Ante, p.
378 U. S. 461.
The
Philadelphia Bank case, which involved the merger of
two banks plainly engaged in the same line of commerce, [
Footnote 2/4] is, however, entirely
distinct from the present situation, which involves two separate
industries. The bizarre result of the Court's approach
Page 378 U. S. 470
is that market percentages of a nonexistent market enable the
Court to dispense with "elaborate proof of market structure, market
behavior and probable anticompetitive effects,"
ante, p.
378 U. S. 458.
As I shall show, the Court has "dispensed with" proof which, given
heed, shows how completely fanciful its market share analysis
is.
In fairness to the District Court, it should be said that it did
not err in failing to consider the "line of commerce" on which this
Court now relies. For the Government did not even suggest that such
a line of commerce existed until it got to this Court. [
Footnote 2/5] And it does not seriously
suggest even now that such a line of commerce exists. [
Footnote 2/6] The truth
Page 378 U. S. 471
is that "glass and metal containers" form a distinct line of
commerce only in the mind of this Court.
The District Court found, and this Court accepts the finding,
that this case "deals with three separate and distinct industries
manufacturing separate and distinct types of products:" metal,
glass, and plastic containers. 217 F. Supp. at 780.
"Concededly there was substantial and vigorous inter-industry
competition between these three industries and between various of
the products which they manufactured. Metal can, glass container
and plastic container manufacturers were each seeking to enlarge
their sales to the thousands of packers of hundreds of varieties of
food, chemical, toiletry and industrial products, ranging from ripe
olives to fruit juices to tuna fish to smoked tongue; from maple
syrup to pet food to coffee; from embalming fluid to floor wax to
nail polish to aspirin to veterinary supplies, to take examples at
random."
"Each industry and each of the manufacturers within it was
seeking to improve their products so that they would appeal to new
customers or hold old ones. Hazel-Atlas and Continental were part
of this overall industrial pattern, each in a recognized separate
industry producing distinct products but engaged in inter-industry
competition for the favor of various end users of their
products."
217 F. Supp. at 780-781.
Page 378 U. S. 472
Only this Court will not be "concerned,"
ante, p.
378 U. S. 457,
that, without support in reason or fact, it dips into this network
of competition and establishes metal and glass containers as a
separate "line of commerce," leaving entirely out of account all
other kinds of containers: "plastic, paper, foil and any other
materials competing for the same business,"
ibid.
[
Footnote 2/7]
Brown Shoe,
supra, on which the Court relies for this travesty of
economics,
ante, p.
378 U. S. 458,
spoke of "
well defined submarkets" within a broader
market, and said that "[t]he boundaries of such a submarket" were
to be determined by "
practical indicia," 370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 325.
[
Footnote 2/8] (Emphasis added.)
Since the Court here provides its own definition of a market,
unrelated to any market reality whatsoever,
Brown Shoe
must, in this case, be regarded as a bootstrap.
The Court is quite wrong when it says that the District Court
"employed an unduly narrow construction of the "competition"
protected by § 7," and that it held that "the competition
protected by § 7 [is limited] to competition between identical
products,"
ante, p.
378 U. S. 452.
Quite to the contrary, the District Court expressly stated that
Page 378 U. S. 473
"Section 7 is applicable to conglomerate mergers where the facts
warrant," 217 F. Supp. at 783 (footnote omitted). [
Footnote 2/9] The difference between the District
Court and this Court lies rather in the District Court's next
sentence: "But there must be evidence that the facts warrant such
application."
Ibid.
If attention is paid to the conclusions of the court below, it
is obvious that this Court's analysis has led it to substitute a
meaningless figure -- the merged companies' share of a nonexistent
"market" -- for the sound, careful factual findings of the District
Court.
The District Court found: [
Footnote 2/10]
(1) With respect to the merger's effect on competition within
the metal container industry, that, "[p]rior to its acquisition,
Hazel-Atlas did not manufacture or sell metal cans. . . ." 217 F.
Supp. at 770.
(2) With respect to the merger's effect on competition within
the glass container industry, that "Continental did not, directly
or through subsidiaries, manufacture or sell glass containers. . .
."
Ibid.
Page 378 U. S. 474
(3) With respect to the merger's effect on the metal container
industry's efforts to compete with the glass container
industry,
"The Government fared no better on its claim that as a result of
the merger Continental was likely to lose the incentive to push can
sales at the expense of glass. The Government introduced no
evidence showing either that there had been or was likely to be any
slackening of effort to push can sales. On the contrary, as has
been pointed out, the object of the merger was diversification, and
Continental was actively promoting intra-company competition
between its various product lines. Since by far the largest
proportion of Continental's business was in metal cans, it scarcely
seemed likely that cans would suffer at the expense of glass."
"Moreover, subsequent to the merger Continental actively engaged
in a vigorous research and promotion program in both its metal and
glass container lines.
In the light of the record and of the
competitive realities, the notion that it was likely to cease being
an innovator in either line is patently absurd."
217 F. Supp. at 790 (footnote omitted). (Emphasis added.)
(4) With respect to the merger's effect on the glass container
industry's efforts to compete with the metal container
industry,
"In addition the Government advanced the converse of the
proposition which it urged with respect to the metal can line --
that, as a result of the merger, Continental was likely to lose the
incentive to push glass container sales at the expense of cans. In
view of what has been said concerning the purpose of Continental's
diversification program and the course it pursued after the merger,
it is no more likely that Continental would slacken its efforts to
promote glass
Page 378 U. S. 475
than that it would slacken its efforts to promote cans. Indeed,
if it had planned to do so, there would have been little, if any,
point to acquiring Hazel-Atlas, a major glass container
producer."
217 F. Supp. at 793.
It is clear from the foregoing that the District Court fully
considered the possibility that a merger of leading producers in
two industries between which there was competition would dampen the
inter-industry rivalry. The basis of the decision below was not,
therefore, an erroneous belief that § 7 did not reach such
competition, but a careful study of the Government's proof, which
led to the conclusion that,
"in the light of the record and of the competitive realities,
the motion that . . . [the merged company] was likely to cease
being an innovator in either line is patently absurd."
Surely this failure of the Court's mock statistical analysis to
reflect the facts as found on the record demonstrates what the
Government concedes, [
Footnote
2/11] and what one would, in any event, have thought to be
obvious: when a merger is attacked on the ground that competition
between two distinct industries, or lines of commerce, will be
effected, the shortcut "market share" approach developed in the
Philadelphia Bank case, see 374 U.S. at
374 U. S.
362-365;
ante, p.
378 U. S. 458,
has no place. In such a case, the legality of the merger must
surely depend, as it did below, on an inquiry into competitive
effects in the actual lines of commerce which are involved. In this
case, the result depends -- or should depend -- on the impact of
the merger in the two lines of commerce here involved: the metal
container industry and the glass container industry. [
Footnote 2/12] As the findings
Page 378 U. S. 476
of the District Court which are quoted above make plain,
reference to these two actual lines of commerce does not preclude
protection of inter-industry competition. Indeed, by placing the
merged company in the setting of other companies in each of the
respective lines of commerce which are also engaged in
inter-industry competition, this approach is far more likely than
the Court's to give § 7 full, but not artificial, scope.
The Court's spurious market share analysis should not obscure
the fact that the Court is, in effect, laying down a "
per
se" rule that mergers between two large companies in related
industries are presumptively unlawful under § 7. Had the Court
based this new rule on a conclusion that such mergers are
inherently likely to dampen inter-industry competition or that so
few mergers of this kind would fail to have that effect that a
"
per se" rule is justified, I could at least understand
the thought process which lay behind its decision. It would, of
course, be inappropriate to prescribe
per se rules in the
first case to present a problem,
cf. White Motor Co. v. United
States, 372 U. S. 253, let
alone a case in which the facts suggest that a
per se rule
is unsound. And to lay down a rule on either of the bases suggested
would require a much more careful look at the nature of competition
between industries than the Court's casual glance in that
direction.
In any event, the Court does not take this tack. It chooses
instead to invent a line of commerce the existence of which no one,
not even the Government, has imagined; for which businessmen and
economists will look in vain; a line of commerce which sprang into
existence only when the merger took place, and will cease to exist
when the
Page 378 U. S. 477
merger is undone. I have no idea where § 7 goes from here,
nor will businessmen or the antitrust bar. Hitherto, it has been
thought that the validity of a merger was to be tested by examining
its effect in identifiable, "well defined" (
Brown Shoe,
supra, at
370 U. S. 325)
markets. Hereafter, however slight (or even nonexistent) the
competitive impact of a merger on any actual market, businessmen
must rest uneasy lest the Court create some "market," in which the
merger presumptively dampens competition, out of bits and pieces of
real ones. No one could say that such a fear is unfounded, since
the Court's creative powers in this respect are declared to be as
extensive as the competitive relationships between industries. This
is said to be recognizing "meaningful competition where it is found
to exist." It is, in fact, imagining effects on competition where
none has been shown.
I would affirm the judgment of the District Court.
[
Footnote 2/1]
Both companies manufactured other related products which, for
present purposes, may be disregarded.
See the description
of the two companies in the opinion of the District Court,
217 F.
Supp. 761, 769-770.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Section 7 of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Act of December
29, 1950, 64 Stat. 1125, 15 U.S.C. § 18, provides in pertinent
part:
"No corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, directly or
indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share
capital and no corporation subject to the jurisdiction of the
Federal Trade Commission shall acquire the whole or any part of the
assets of another corporation engaged also in commerce, where in
any line of commerce in any section of the country, the effect of
such acquisition may be substantially to lessen competition, or to
tend to create a monopoly."
[
Footnote 2/3]
The Court confesses to some difficulty in determining market
shares.
See ante, pp.
378 U. S.
459-460,
n
10.
[
Footnote 2/4]
"We have no difficulty in determining the 'line of commerce'
(relevant product or services market) . . . in which to appraise
the probable competitive effects of appellees' proposed merger. We
agree with the District Court that the cluster of products (various
kinds of credit) and services (such as checking accounts and trust
administration) denoted by the term 'commercial banking' . . .
composes a distinct line of commerce. . . . In sum, it is clear
that commercial banking is a market 'sufficiently inclusive to be
meaningful in terms of trade realities.'
Crown Zellerbach Corp.
v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 296 F.2d 800, 811 (C.A.9th Cir.
1961)."
374 U.S. at
374 U. S.
356-357.
[
Footnote 2/5]
In the District Court, the Government relied on 10 "lines of
commerce." In addition to "the packaging industry," "the can
industry," "the glass container industry," and "metal closures"
(not relevant here), the Government argued that there were six
"lines of commerce" which were defined by the end product for which
the containers were used,
e.g., "containers for the beer
industry."
See 217 F. Supp. at 778-779.
[
Footnote 2/6]
Although the Government makes the suggestion, which the Court
now accepts, that wherever there is competition, there is a "line
of commerce," so that
"the 'line of commerce' within which the merger's effect on
competition should be appraised is the production and sale of
containers used for all purposes for which metal or glass
containers may be used . . ."
(Brief, p. 18), it concedes the artificiality of this approach,
and, in so doing, itself rejects the market share analysis adopted
by the Court. The Government states that its suggested test of
illegality of a merger involving inter-industry competition
"omits analysis of statistics regarding market share simply
because those traditional yardsticks are generally unavailable to
measure the full consequences which an inter-industry merger would
have on competition."
(Brief, p. 22.)
The test which the Government advocates is that it
"can satisfy its burden of showing that the merger may have the
effect of substantially lessening competition by proving (a) the
existence of substantial competition between two industries; (b) a
high degree of concentration in either or both of the competing
industries; and (c) the dominant positions of each of the merging
companies in its respective industry."
(Brief, p. 22.) This approach, which has at least the virtue of
facing up to its own logic, frankly disavows attention to a "line
of commerce." The effect of the Court's approach is not markedly
different from that of the Government's test,
see infra,
p.
378 U. S. 476,
and there is some suggestion in the last few pages of the Court's
opinion that the Court appreciates this. As discussed hereafter,
however, there is nothing in the Court's opinion to support
adoption of the Government's "
per se" approach, and the
facts developed in the District Court demonstrate that, so far as
one can tell from this case at least, a
per se approach to
the problem of inter-industry competition is wholly
inappropriate.
[
Footnote 2/7]
If the competition between metal and glass containers is
sufficient to constitute them collectively a "line of commerce,"
why does their competition with plastic containers and "other
materials competing for the same business" not require that all
such containers be included in the same line of commerce? The Court
apparently concedes that the competition is multilateral.
[
Footnote 2/8]
The "practical indicia" specified by the Court were:
"industry or public recognition of the submarket as a separate
economic entity, the product's peculiar characteristics and uses,
unique production facilities, distinct customers, distinct prices,
sensitivity to price changes, and specialized vendors."
370 U.S. at
370 U. S. 325
(footnote omitted). While many of these factors weigh against the
Court's conclusion that metal and glass containers should be
combined in a single line of commerce, not one of them speaks for
the Court's conclusion that they should be segregated from all
other kinds of containers and together form a separate line of
commerce.
[
Footnote 2/9]
The District Court observed also that "relevant markets are
neither economic abstractions nor artificial conceptions." 217 F.
Supp. at 768. In this respect, in view of the majority's present
opinion, the district judge must, I suppose, be deemed to have
erred.
[
Footnote 2/10]
This summary of the District Court's findings includes only so
much as is relevant to the majority's opinion. The District Court
gave detailed attention to each of the Government's contentions, in
an opinion of 48 pages. Its conclusions were summarized in the
following statement:
"Viewing the evidence as a whole, quite apart from theory, there
was a total failure by the Government to establish the essential
elements of a violation of Section 7. As will be apparent from a
discussion of the proof relating to each specific line of commerce,
the Government did not lay either the statistical or testimonial
foundations required to establish its case. It was this failure of
proof which required the dismissal of the complaint and entry of
judgment for the defendants."
217 F. Supp. at 787.
[
Footnote 2/11]
See 378
U.S. 441fn2/6|>note 6,
supra.
[
Footnote 2/12]
The Government urged other lines of commerce below,
see
378
U.S. 441fn2/5|>note 5,
supra, but has abandoned all
of them here except "containers for the canning industry," a line
of commerce defined by end use and including "all metal cans and
glass containers for the end uses of
canning' food." 217 F.
Supp. at 799. The District Court gave detailed reasons, which the
record fully supports, for rejecting the Government's contention
that this was a distinct line of commerce. See 217 F.
Supp. at 799-802.