Appellee railroads proposed reduced rates for trailer-on-flatcar
service between certain points also served by coastal water
carriers. The reduced rates, with certain exceptions not relevant
here, equaled or exceeded the railroads' out-of-pocket costs; in
many instances, they equaled or exceeded the railroads' fully
distributed costs; they were substantially on a parity with the
water carriers' rates for the same traffic, but they were below the
level maintained by the railroads for similar traffic between
points not served by the water carriers. The Interstate Commerce
Commission cancelled the reductions on the grounds that the water
carriers could not compete with railroads at equal rates; that the
reductions were an initial step in a general rate-cutting program
which threatened the water carriers' continued existence; and that
the water carriers were essential to national defense and an
integral part of the national transportation system. The District
Court reversed.
Held: The judgment is vacated; the order of the
Commission is set aside to the extent that it disallowed certain
railroad trailer-on-flatcar rates, and the cause is remanded to the
Commission for further proceedings consistent with this opinion.
Pp.
372 U. S.
746-764.
1. In the light of the legislative history of §15a(3),
added to the Interstate Commerce Act by the Transportation Act of
1958, there can be no doubt that its purpose was to permit the
railroads to respond to competition by asserting whatever inherent
advantages of cost and service they possessed, and that Congress
did not consciously or inadvertently defeat this purpose when it
included in §15a(3) a reference to the National Transportation
Policy. Pp.
372 U. S.
753-758.
Page 372 U. S. 745
2. On the present record, the disallowance of the rates in
question was not adequately supported. Pp.
372 U. S.
758-764.
(a) In the light of the legislative history of §15a(3), it
is clear that Congress did not regard the setting of a rate at a
particular level as constituting an unfair or destructive
competitive practice simply because that rate would divert some or
all of the traffic from a competing mode. Pp.
372 U. S.
759-761.
(b) This Court disagrees with the conclusion of the District
Court that the needs of the national defense are not an operative
part of the National Transportation Policy; but this Court
concludes that the Commission's reliance on the factor of "national
defense," and perhaps of "commerce," in disallowing the rates in
question was not supported by adequate findings or substantial
evidence. Pp.
372 U. S.
761-764.
199 F.
Supp. 635, judgment vacated and cause remanded.
Page 372 U. S. 746
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case, involving four consolidated appeals from a
three-judge District Court judgment setting aside an order of the
Interstate Commerce Commission to the extent that it rejected
certain proposed railroad rate decreases, brings before us
important questions relating to the role of the Commission in its
task of overseeing competition among different modes of
transportation. The case is the first in which this Court has
considered the interpretation and application of § 15a(3) of
the Interstate Commerce Act, added by Congress in the
Transportation Act of 1958. [
Footnote 1]
I
The two corporate appellants here, Sea-Land Service, Inc.
(formerly Pan-Atlantic Steamship Corporation), and Seatrain Lines,
Inc., are common carriers by water engaged in the Atlantic-Gulf
coastwise trade; they are the only two companies now performing
this service. Sea-Land, which had operated as a "break-bulk"
[
Footnote 2] carrier for many
years, in 1957 suspended that service and converted
Page 372 U. S. 747
four ships into crane-equipped trailerships, each capable of
holding 226 demountable truck trailers. With these ships, freight
could be moved by highway trailers to the port of origin, the
trailers lifted onto the ships, and the process reversed at the
port of destination. As a result, Sea-Land was able to provide a
motor-water-motor service which afforded door-to-door delivery of
goods from and to all shippers and consignees, even if not situated
on a railroad siding, in containers that would not have to be
opened in transit. Traditionally water rates, including water-rail
and water-motor rates, have been lower than the corresponding
all-rail rates, and when Sea-Land inaugurated its new trailership
service in 1957, it published reduced rates which were generally 5%
to 7 1/2% lower than the corresponding all-rail boxcar rates. Some
700 of these reduced rates were placed under investigation by the
Commission.
In Seatrain's service, freight is transported to the company's
dock in railroad cars, the cars and their contents are then lifted
onto Seatrain's vessels, and at destination the cars are unloaded
and delivered by rail to the consignee. This rail-water-rail
service is similar to railroad boxcar service, in that it permits
carriage from shipper to consignee without breaking bulk when both
shipper and consignee are located on railroad sidings.
Railroad "piggy-back," or trailer-on-flatcar (TOFC), service is
like that provided by Sea-Land. A motor carrier trailer is hauled
by road to a railhead, loaded onto a flatcar, and demounted at
destination for delivery by motor carrier to the consignee.
Before 1957, railroad TOFC rates were generally higher than
all-rail boxcar, water, and land-water rates. But in 1957,
primarily in answer to the new improved service and lower rates
offered by Sea-Land, the appellee railroads proposed to establish,
on an experimental basis, reduced rates on 66 commodity movements
between certain
Page 372 U. S. 748
eastern points, on the one hand, and Fort Worth and Dallas,
Texas, on the other. [
Footnote
3] These rates, which were substantially on a parity with
Sea-Land and Seatrain rates on the same traffic, were suspended and
placed under investigation by the Commission. In December, 1960,
the Commission disposed of 43 docket proceedings by issuing a
consolidated report embracing the railroad TOFC rates involved
here, as well as a number of Sea-Land and Seatrain rates not now
before us. 313 I.C.C. 23.
The Commission found that the proposed TOFC rates were
compensatory, that is, they equaled or exceeded out-of-pocket
costs, for all of the listed movements by railroad-leased flatcars
capable of carrying two trailers (TTX cars), and for all but six of
the listed movements by railroad-owned single trailer cars.
[
Footnote 4] The Commission
further found that the proposed rates equaled or exceeded fully
Page 372 U. S. 749
distributed costs [
Footnote
5] for 43 of the 66 movements by TTX cars and 14 of 66
movements by railroad-owned cars.
Having made these findings, the Commission addressed itself to
what it considered the "most important" question -- "whether these
(TOFC) rates constitute destructive competition." 313 I.C.C. at 44.
It noted at the outset that, apart from the question of rates, most
shippers prefer rail service to Sea-Land and Seatrain service, and
that, in order to attract traffic, the latter carriers must
therefore establish rates somewhat below those of the railroads. As
to relative costs, the Commission stated that Sea-Land costs, both
out-of-pocket and fully distributed, were below railroad TOFC costs
for all 66 movements using railroad-owned flatcars and for all but
2 of the 66 movements using TTX cars. But the Commission explicitly
refrained from relying on these findings. Instead, it concluded
that, because of a number of factors:
"[W]e cannot determine on these records where the
inherent
advantages may lie as to any of the rates in issue. We must
recognize, also, that cost is only one of the elements which may
appropriately be considered in passing upon the lawfulness of
rates. In the exceptional circumstances here presented, other
considerations, herein discussed, appear to us determinative of the
issues."
313 I.C.C. at 46. (Emphasis added.)
The Commission acknowledged that the recently enacted §
15a(3) prohibited it from holding rail rates up to a particular
level merely to protect the traffic of another
Page 372 U. S. 750
mode, but emphasized that the prohibition was qualified by the
phrase "giving due consideration to the objectives of the national
transportation policy declared in this Act." [
Footnote 6] In this case, the Commission stated,
the reduced TOFC rates were an initial step in a program of rate
reductions that could "fairly be said to threaten the continued
operation, and thus the continued existence, of the coastwise
water-carrier industry generally." 313 I.C.C. at 47. Since, in the
Commission's view, the coastwise shipping so threatened was
important to the national defense, to the shipping public, and to
the economy of ports and coastal areas, [
Footnote 7] it concluded that the objectives
Page 372 U. S. 751
of the National Transportation Policy required the establishment
and maintenance of a differential between rail rates and those of
Sea-Land and Seatrain which would enable the coastwise carriers to
continue their service. The Commission decided that an appropriate
differential to accomplish this purpose would be 6% over Sea-Land
rates for TOFC service and somewhat less than 6% for boxcar
service. Accordingly, the proposed TOFC rates were ordered to be
canceled, without prejudice to the filing of new schedules in
conformity with the Commission's views. [
Footnote 8]
The appellee railroads then brought this action before a
three-judge District Court seeking to have the Commission's
Page 372 U. S. 752
order set aside to the extent that it required cancellation of
the proposed TOFC rates. In November, 1961, the court handed down
its opinion, setting aside the Commission's order in part and
enjoining the Commission from canceling TOFC rates which return at
least fully distributed costs, except on the basis of certain
specified findings.
199 F.
Supp. 635. The court held that "at least on this record,"
§ 15a(3) prohibited the imposition of a rate differential to
protect the water carriers. The reference to the National
Transportation Policy in § 15a(3), the court said, was
intended to qualify the prohibition of mandatory differentials
". . . only when factors other than the normal incidents of fair
competition intervened, such as a practice which would destroy a
competing mode of transportation by setting rates so low as to be
hurtful to the proponent as well as his competitor or so low as to
deprive the competitor of the 'inherent advantage' of being the
low-cost carrier."
199 F. Supp. at 642. The court went on to discuss in some detail
its understanding of the way in which costs of service for the
different transportation modes were determined, the possible
reasons why the Commission had been reluctant to accept relative
costs as critical, and the precise circumstances under which the
Commission could properly require cancellation of certain TOFC
rates. Finally, in rejecting the argument that a differential was
required in the interests of the national defense, the court stated
that the reference to the national defense in the National
Transportation Policy was merely a "hoped-for end," not an
operative policy, and that, in any event, the Commission's
conclusion with respect to the national defense was not supported
by adequate evidence.
Page 372 U. S. 753
We noted probable jurisdiction, 371 U.S. 808, because of the
importance of the questions presented in effectuating the
congressional design embodied in the Interstate Commerce Act.
[
Footnote 9]
II
The significance of § 15a(3) to the determination of these
appeals can best be understood after consideration of the
legislative history of this provision.
Section 15a(3) was the result of several years of congressional
consideration of the problems of the transportation industry as a
whole and of the railroads in particular. Concerned with their
declining share in an expanding market, and with what they regarded
as improper administrative interference with their efforts to
compete, the railroads vigorously supported legislation introduced
in 1955 on the basis of a proposal by the Secretary of Commerce.
H.R. 6141, 84th Cong., 1st Sess. This bill, which became known as
"the three shall-nots," would have amended § 15a(1) of the Act
to provide that, in determining whether a rate is less than a
reasonable minimum, the Commission
". . . shall not consider the effect of such charge on the
traffic of any other mode of transportation; or
Page 372 U. S. 754
the relation of such charge to the charge of any other mode of
transportation; or whether such charge is lower than necessary to
meet the competition of any other mode of transportation. . .
."
This bill was strongly opposed by the Commission and by other
carriers, and died in committee. A substantially similar bill,
however, was introduced in the next Congress, H.R. 5523, 85th
Cong., 1st Sess., and the Commission renewed its opposition. When,
after hearings, a Senate subcommittee recommended a bill to its
parent committee, it explicitly rejected the three "shall-nots."
But, at the same time, it expressed its concern with
"over-regulation," and emphasized that its own proposal to add a
new § 15a(3) was designed to encourage competition among the
difference modes and to permit each mode to assert its inherent
advantages. S.Rep.No. 1647, 85th Cong., 2d Sess. 10, 18-19. The
bill at this stage provided that, in a proceeding involving
competition with another mode,
". . . the Commission in determining whether a rail rate is
lower than a reasonable minimum rate, shall consider the facts and
circumstances attending the movement of the traffic by railroad
and not by such other mode."
Id. at 18. (Emphasis added.) At hearings before the
full Senate Commerce Committee, the Commission opposed the bill as
drafted not because it disagreed with the principles set out in the
subcommittee report, but because it feared that the language used,
particularly the italicized portion, was inconsistent with those
principles, and was substantially equivalent to the three "shall
nots." Hearings on S. 3778 before the Senate Committee on
Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 85th Cong., 2d Sess. 165-185. In
particular Commissioner (then Chairman) Freas expressed concern
that if the Commission were foreclosed from considering the
effect
Page 372 U. S. 755
of a rate on a competing mode, it would be powerless to reject a
railroad rate which covered the railroad's out-of-pocket costs,
even if that rate had the effect of destroying the inherent
advantages of a lower-cost carrier. He stated:
"Whenever conditions permit, given transportation should return
the full cost of performing carrier service. . . . In many
instances, however, the full cost of the low-cost form of
transportation exceeds the out-of-pocket cost of another. If, then,
we are required to accept the rates of the high cost carrier merely
because they exceed its out-of-pocket costs, we see no way of
preserving the inherent advantages of the low cost carrier."
Id. at 168. Commissioner Freas made it clear that the
Commission believed the railroads should be permitted to assert
their inherent advantages too,
id. at 172, and suggested
that any proposal specifically authorize the Commission to give
"due consideration to the inherent cost and service advantages of
the respective carriers,"
id. at 169. In further
discussion, it was indicated that it would be inconsistent with the
National Transportation Policy to permit destruction of the
inherent advantages of any mode of transportation,
id. at
170-171, 177, and when Senator Potter suggested the deletion of the
phrase "and not by such other mode" and the addition of a reference
to the National Transportation Policy, Chairman Freas answered: "We
will buy Senator Potter's suggestion."
Id. at 177-178.
Senator Potter's suggestion was adopted in the final version of the
bill.
Other testimony of particular interest here is that of John L.
Weller, President of Seatrain, who testified on behalf of Seatrain
and Pan-Atlantic (now Sea-Land). In opposing the bill recommended
by the subcommittee, Mr. Weller emphasized that he did not seek any
more than
Page 372 U. S. 756
to make it possible for the Commission to preserve the inherent
advantages of the water carriers he represented:
"As I explained, our kind of operation can only exist with a
differential under the railroad rates; that is No. 1.
We are
not entitled to have such a differential, nor do I urge one, except
in the case where cost is lower than the railroad cost. We
have no right to ask for anything more than that."
Id. at 30. (Emphasis added.)
The proposal reported out by the Senate Commerce Committee was
in the form ultimately adopted by Congress and contained the key
provision that rates
"shall not be held up to a particular level to protect the
traffic of any other mode of transportation, giving due
consideration to the objectives of the national transportation
policy declared in this Act."
The Committee, quoting with approval the subcommittee's report,
made it clear that the purpose of the proposal was to permit each
mode of transportation to assert its "inherent advantages, whether
they be of service of cost." S.Rep.No. 1647, 85th Cong., 2d Sess.
3. The new subsection, the Committee stated, was designed to
reaffirm the intent of the 1940 Act, an intent that had been
correctly construed by the Commission in 1945 in
New
Automobiles in Interstate Commerce, 259 I.C.C. 475, but which,
in the Committee's view, had not been consistently followed.
[
Footnote 10] The particular
passage in
Page 372 U. S. 757
the
New Automobiles decision which the Committee
endorsed contained the statement:
"[T]here appears no warrant for believing that rail rates, for
example, should be help up to a particular level to preserve a
motor-rate structure, or vice versa."
259 I.C.C. at 538.
This theme -- that Congress was firmly opposed to rates
maintained by the Commission at an artificially high level merely
to protect competing modes -- was repeated in the House Commerce
Committee report, H.R.Rep. No. 1922, 85th Cong., 2d Sess., and in
the debates on the floor of both Houses. 104 Cong.Rec. 10822,
10841-10843, 10858-10859, 12524, 12531, 15528. As stated by
Representative Harris, Chairman of the House Commerce Committee, if
a carrier could provide a rate that was "fully compensatory," the
Commission could not force it up to a higher level "just because it
is necessary to keep another mode of transportation in business."
Id. at 12531. The mood of Congress was perhaps best
summarized by Senator Smathers when he said:
"[W]e are going to eliminate some of the paternalism which has
heretofore existed in the minds of the Interstate Commerce
Commission. I think we will breathe into our whole system of
transportation some new competition, which, of course, is needed,
because the public and the consumer will benefit therefrom."
Id. at 15528.
This revealing legislative history fills out the contours of
§ 15a(3). There can be no doubt that the purpose of this
provision was to permit the railroads to respond to competition by
asserting whatever inherent advantages of cost and service they
possessed. The Commission, in the view of the proponents of the
bill, had thwarted effective competition by insisting that each
form of transportation
Page 372 U. S. 758
subject to its jurisdiction must remain viable at all costs, and
must therefore receive a significant share of the traffic. It had,
in the words of one Congressman, become a "giant handicapper."
[
Footnote 11]
Moreover, it is clear that Congress did not consciously or
inadvertently defeat this purpose when it included in § 15a(3)
a reference to the National Transportation Policy. The principal
reason for this reference, as the hearings show, was to emphasize
the power of the Commission to prevent the railroads from
destroying or impairing the inherent advantages of other modes. And
the precise example given to the Senate Committee, which led to the
language adopted, was a case in which the railroads, by
establishing on a part of their operations a compensatory rate
below their fully distributed cost, forced a smaller competing
lower cost mode to go below its own fully distributed cost
and thus perhaps to go out of business.
III
We agree with the District Court that, "at least on this
record," the Commission's rejection of the TOFC rates here at issue
and the requirement of a differential over the rates of the
coastwise carriers were not consistent with the mandate of §
15a(3). In light of the findings and conclusions underlying the
Commission's decision, and more particularly its putting aside the
question of "inherent advantages," its insistence that TOFC rates,
in the words of the prohibition in § 15a(3), "be held up to a
particular level to protect the traffic" of the coastwise carriers
cannot be justified on the basis of the objectives of the National
Transportation Policy. Since the Commission appears to have relied
principally on two aspects of that policy -- (i) the prohibition of
"unfair or destructive
Page 372 U. S. 759
competitive practices," and (ii) the objective of preserving a
transportation system "adequate to meet the needs of the commerce
of the United States . . . and of the national defense" (
note 6 supra) -- we shall
consider each of these aspects separately.
1.
Unfair or Destructive Competitive Practices. -- If
there is one fact that stands out in bold relief in the legislative
history of § 15a(3), it is that Congress did not regard the
setting of a rate at a particular level as constituting an unfair
or destructive competitive practice simply because that rate would
divert some or all of the traffic from a competing mode. Moreover,
neither the Commission representative nor the witness who testified
on behalf of the appellant carriers (
supra, pp.
372 U. S.
754-756) took this position, since they too recognized
that such an interpretation would be inconsistent with the mandate
of the National Transportation Policy to "preserve the inherent
advantages of each" mode of transportation. If a carrier is
prohibited from establishing a reduced rate that is not detrimental
to its own revenue requirements merely because the rate will divert
traffic from others, then the carrier is thwarted from asserting
its own inherent advantages of cost and service. Nor should the
selective character of such a rate reduction, made in response to a
particular competitive situation, be permitted, without more, to
furnish a basis for rejecting the rate. Section 15a(3), in other
words, made it clear that something more than even hard competition
must be shown before a particular rate can be deemed unfair or
destructive. The principal purpose of the reference to the National
Transportation Policy, as we have seen, was to prevent a carrier
from setting a rate which would impair or destroy the inherent
advantages of a competing carrier, for example, by setting a rate,
below its own fully distributed costs, which would force a
competitor with a cost advantage on particular transportation to
establish an unprofitable rate in order to attract traffic.
Page 372 U. S. 760
It is true that, in the present case, the Commission found that
with respect to virtually all of the TOFC movements involved,
Sea-Land's out-of-pocket and fully distributed costs were below
those of the railroads. But the Commission at the same time
explicitly stated that "we cannot determine on these records where
the inherent advantages may lie as to
any of the rates in
issue." 313 I.C.C. at 46. (Emphasis added.) It is not for us to
make this determination at this stage, or to decide in advance
precisely how either carrier's inherent advantages should be
measured or protected. [
Footnote
12] It may be, for example, that neither a comparison of
"out-of-pocket" nor a comparison of "fully distributed" costs, as
those terms are defined by the Commission, is the appropriate
method of deciding which of two competing modes has the cost
advantage on a given movement. [
Footnote 13] And even if the cost advantage on each
movement were determined to lie with the coastwise carriers, it may
be that some or all of the TOFC rates at issue here should be
allowed to stand because they
Page 372 U. S. 761
would not unduly impair that advantage. [
Footnote 14] These and other similar questions
should be left for initial resolution to the Commission's informed
judgment.
The court below set out at some length its understanding of the
Commission's methods of arriving at carrier costs, its analysis of
the role of "value of service" concepts in ratemaking, and its
views of the precise circumstances under which the Commission could
lawfully disallow the TOFC rates at issue. We find it unnecessary
to consider that discussion in this instance, since we hold only
that, on the present record, the disallowance of the rates in
question was not adequately supported.
Cf. Securities &
Exchange Comm. v. Chenery Corp., 318 U. S.
80,
318 U. S.
87.
2.
The Needs of the Commerce of the United States and of the
National Defense. -- The Commission gave considerable weight
to the factor of "national defense" and perhaps of "commerce" in
arriving at its decision. But the District Court discounted these
factors, concluding that the reference in the National
Transportation Policy to the national defense (and presumably to
commerce as well) represented merely a "hoped-for end," not an
operative policy. We disagree with this conclusion, but hold that
the Commission's reliance on these
Page 372 U. S. 762
factors was not supported by adequate findings or substantial
evidence.
The primary reason for the reference to the National
Transportation Policy in § 15a(3) was to confirm the
Commission's power to protect the inherent advantages of all
carriers from destructive competition. But we cannot conclude that
this was the only reason, especially in view of the choice not to
accept the Commission's proposal, which would have expressed the
qualification in terms of the inherent advantage element alone.
See p.
372 U. S. 755,
supra. Nor can we conclude that the statutory references
to such vital considerations as national defense are mere window
dressing, without any practical significance in terms of the
Commission's function.
"Congress unequivocally reserved to the Commission power to
regulate reasonableness of interstate rates in the light of the
needs of national defense."
United States v. Capital Transit Co., 325 U.
S. 357,
325 U. S.
362.
On the other hand, by recognizing the relevance of such
considerations as national defense, we do not imply that these
broad policy factors may be applied so freely as to nullify either
the more particularized mandates of the National Transportation
Policy or the clear congressional design embodied in § 15a(3).
Normally, it is these more specific considerations that should
govern the lawfulness of proposed rates in a case involving
intermodal competition. Only under extraordinary circumstances may
the Commission properly permit them to be outweighed. To justify
such a result, we believe it must be demonstrated that the proposed
rates, in themselves, genuinely threaten the continued existence of
a transportation service that is uniquely capable of filling a
transcendent national defense or other public need.
Measured against this standard, the Commission's conclusions
cannot be sustained. The Commission did state that the proposed
rates were an "initial step" in a program
Page 372 U. S. 763
of rate reductions that "can fairly be said to threaten" the
existence of the coastwise carriers, but it made no findings, and
referred to no supporting evidence, to the effect that these
particular TOFC rates would drive the corresponding water carrier
rates below a profitable level or otherwise endanger the carriers'
survival.
Cf. Burlington Truck Lines, Inc. v. United
States, 371 U. S. 156,
371 U. S.
167-168;
Gilbertville Trucking Co. v. United
States, 371 U. S. 115,
371 U. S.
130-131. It is not enough to rely on the possible effect
of other rate reductions not here in issue, a situation with which
the Commission has ample power to deal if occasion arises.
Nor did the Commission present an adequate basis for concluding
that either the national defense or any significant segment of the
country's commerce depends upon the operation of Sea-Land or
Seatrain. [
Footnote 15] We
need not consider the question whether reliance on other additional
sources might have been sufficient, [
Footnote 16] for we believe that the question is one for
initial determination by the Commission, and that all parties
should have an opportunity to adduce relevant evidence, including
any evidence tending to indicate that disallowance of the proposed
TOFC rates might adversely affect the commerce
Page 372 U. S. 764
or the national defense of the country. Once raised, these
considerations (like the factor of inherent advantage) do not exist
solely for the benefit of protesting carriers.
In conclusion: we agree with the District Court that the
Commission's order, insofar as it related to the TOFC rates at
issue, must be set aside. We disagree, however, with that court's
determination that the needs of the national defense are not an
operative part of the National Transportation Policy, and we deem
it inappropriate to approve or disapprove of other aspects of the
court's opinion. Accordingly, we decide that the judgment below
should be vacated, the order of the Commission set aside to the
extent that it related to certain railroad TOFC rates described
herein, and the cause remanded to the Commission for further
proceedings consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
* Together with No. 109,
Sea-Land Service, Inc. v. New York,
New Haven & Hartford Railroad Co. et al.; No. 110,
Seatrain Lines, Inc. v. New York, New Haven & Hartford
Railroad Co. et al.; and No. 125,
United States v. New
York, New Haven & Hartford Railroad Co. et al., on appeals
from the same Court.
[
Footnote 1]
Section 15a(3) of the Interstate Commerce Act, 72 Stat. 572, 49
U.S.C. § 15a(3), provides:
"In a proceeding involving competition between carriers of
different modes of transportation subject to this Act, the
Commission, in determining whether a rate is lower than a
reasonable minimum rate, shall consider the facts and circumstances
attending the movement of the traffic by the carrier or carriers to
which the rate is applicable. Rates of a carrier shall not be held
up to a particular level to protect the traffic of any other mode
of transportation, giving due consideration to the objectives of
the national transportation policy declared in this Act."
[
Footnote 2]
This break-bulk service involved the physical unloading of
freight from rail car or truck and the loading of the cargo into
the ships, with the operation reversed at the port of
destination.
[
Footnote 3]
Since the establishment of these reduced rates would leave
higher rates in effect to and from certain intermediate points
involving shorter hauls, thus violating the long- and short-haul
provisions of § 4(1) of the Act, 49 U.S.C. § 4(1), the
railroads also applied to the Commission for the relief from these
provisions which § 4(1) permits the Commission to grant. This
fourth-section application was denied by the Commission because,
for reasons summarized in the text of this opinion, the Commission
found the proposed TOFC rates not shown to be just and reasonable.
With respect to the fourth-section application itself, the
Commission noted that "[n]o shippers or receivers located at the
intermediate points oppose the granting of fourth-section relief."
313 I.C.C. at 33. Indeed, no individual shippers came forward to
urge that the selective character of the reduced TOFC rates here
involved in any way discriminated against them, and, in this Court,
the National Industrial Traffic League, a nationwide organization
of shippers, has filed a brief as
amicus curiae urging
affirmance of the decision below.
[
Footnote 4]
The rates for these six movements were withdrawn, and are not at
issue. (The Commission had stated that it had no way of knowing the
percentages of TOFC traffic that would move in TTX cars and the
percentage that would move in railroad-owned cars, and had thus
concluded that the rates for the six movements in question had not
been shown to be compensatory.)
[
Footnote 5]
The Commission has stated, in discussing railroad costs,
that:
"Fully distributed costs based on the out-of-pocket costs plus a
revenue-ton and revenue ton-mile distribution of the constant
costs, including deficits, indicate the revenue necessary to a fair
return on the traffic, disregarding ability to pay."
New Automobiles in Interstate Commerce, 259 I.C.C. 475,
513 (1945).
[
Footnote 6]
The National Transportation Policy, 54 Stat. 899, 49 U.S.C.
preceding § 1, was added to the Interstate Commerce Act in
1940. It provides:
"It is hereby declared to be the national transportation policy
of the Congress to provide for fair and impartial regulation of all
modes of transportation subject to the provisions of this Act, so
administered as to recognize and preserve the inherent advantages
of each; to promote safe, adequate, economical, and efficient
service and foster sound economic conditions in transportation and
among the several carriers; to encourage the establishment and
maintenance of reasonable charges for transportation services,
without unjust discriminations, undue preferences or advantages, or
unfair or destructive competitive practices; to cooperate with the
several States and the duly authorized officials thereof; and to
encourage fair wages and equitable working conditions -- all to the
end of developing, coordinating, and preserving a national
transportation system by water, highway and rail, as well as other
means, adequate to meet the needs of the commerce of the United
States, of the Postal Service, and of the national defense. All of
the provisions of this Act shall be administered and enforced with
a view to carrying out the above declaration of policy."
[
Footnote 7]
In support of these conclusions, the Commission quoted with
approval passages from a 1955 report of the United States Maritime
Administration, "A Review of the Coastwise and Intercoastal
Shipping Trades," which emphasized the national defense importance
of break-bulk cargo ships; from a 1950 congressional report,
S.Rep.No.2494, 81st Cong., 2d Sess. 17, which referred to "the
importance to national defense of having domestic tonnage readily
available"; and from a 1945 Commission decision, War Shipping
Admin. T. A. Application, 260 I.C.C. 589, 591, which spoke of the
"dependency of ports and coastal areas upon the existence of water
transportation."
[
Footnote 8]
Five of the 10 Commissioners then in office joined in the entire
report. A sixth, Commissioner Hutchinson, concurred, stating that
he was "in general agreement with the majority report," 313 I.C.C.
at 50, adding his own view that
"the ultimate effect of approval of the (TOFC) schedules would
be to allow rates of the high-cost carrier (TOFC) to gravitate to a
level whereby the low-cost carrier (sea-land) will be forced to go
below its full costs in order to participate in the traffic."
Id. at 51. He also expressed some doubt as to whether a 6%
differential was warranted. Commissioner McPherson, concurring in
part, would have approved all compensatory rates but would have
imposed no differential. Three Commissioners (Commissioner Freas,
joined by Chairman Winchell and Commissioner Webb) dissented on the
ground that the Act neither required nor permitted "blanket
protection" for water carriers or for any mode of transportation.
Id. at 51-52.
In view of our disposition of this case, it is not necessary to
consider whether, in light of Commissioner Hutchinson's
concurrence, the "majority report" in fact represented the views of
a majority of the Commission and, if not, whether the Commission's
decision could be sustained in the absence of any rationale
commanding the support of a majority of the agency.
Cf.
Securities & Exchange Comm. v. Chenery Corp., 318 U. S.
80.
[
Footnote 9]
There is some question as to precisely what rates are in issue
here; the United States and the Commission suggest that these
appeals relate only to the TOFC rates which are equal to or exceed
fully distributed costs, since the court below did not enjoin the
Commission from canceling compensatory TOFC rates under that level.
As we read the opinion and judgment below, however, the
Commission's order was set aside insofar as it canceled all of the
proposed TOFC before the court, and thus any order entered by the
Commission in the future with respect to those rates would be
subject to full judicial review. Accordingly, we reject as too
narrow the position that the relevance of the present appeals is
limited to TOFC rates that return at least the fully distributed
costs of carriage.
[
Footnote 10]
During the hearings, Senator Smathers had referred to several
Commission decisions,
e.g., Petroleum Products in Ill.
Territory, 280 I.C.C. 681, 691 (1951);
Petroleum Products
from Los Angeles to Arizona and New Mexico, 280 I.C.C. 509
(1951), which were believed to have substantially departed from the
principles laid down in
New Automobiles. Hearings on S.
3778 before the Senate Committee on Interstate and Foreign
Commerce, 85th Cong., 2d Sess. 174-175.
[
Footnote 11]
Hearings,
supra, note 10 at 82.
[
Footnote 12]
It was argued below, and at least intimated here, that the
railroads had failed to sustain the burden of proving that they had
the relative cost advantage. But we agree with the court below that
if a carrier shows a proposed rate to be just and reasonable from
the standpoint of its own revenue requirements, it is for a
protesting carrier who relies on a claim of inherent cost advantage
to bear the burden of persuading the Commission of the existence of
that advantage. Of course, when such an issue is raised, each
carrier should bring forward the data relating to its own costs
that are required for resolution of the issue.
See Various
Commodities from or to Ark. & Tex., 314 I.C.C. 215.
[
Footnote 13]
The utility of the concepts of fully distributed and
out-of-pocket costs may be limited to the area in which they have
traditionally been used -- that of determining the reasonableness
of a rate from the standpoint of a carrier's own revenue
requirements. If so, some different measure may be preferred for
comparing the costs of two or more modes of transportation.
[
Footnote 14]
Even though carrier A may have lower costs than carrier B, the
overall advantage may rest with B, for example, if the difference
in cost is very slight but the service of B is so superior as to
out-weigh any such marginal cost difference. In this event, a rate
established by B may be lawful even if it has the effect of
diverting some or all of A's traffic.
Conversely, the cost advantage of A over B may be so great that
even if B were to reduce its rate to the level of its out-of-pocket
costs, A might be able to continue to compete effectively and still
charge a profitable rate. In this event, B's reduced rate would not
appear to impair A's inherent cost advantage.
[
Footnote 15]
The materials relied upon by the Commission are referred to in
note 7 supra. These
materials were general in nature, and the most recent dated back to
1955. Further, they were not sufficiently related to the specific
service rendered by Sea-Land and Seatrain, which, we were informed
by Sea-Land's counsel at oral argument, have a combined total of
only eight ships currently in operation.
[
Footnote 16]
The Commission in its brief has cited the 1960 testimony of Vice
Admiral Wilson and of the Mayor of Savannah, Georgia, in Decline of
Coastwise and Intercoastal Shipping Industry, Hearings before the
Merchant Marine and Fisheries Subcommittee of the Senate Committee
on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, 86th Cong., 2d Sess. 83-86,
105-106, and has also cited a 1961 letter from Vice Admiral
Sylvester to Senator Butler, reproduced at 107 Cong.Rec.
7299-7302.