Under § 8c of the Agricultural Adjustment Act, as amended
and reenacted by the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937,
the Secretary of Agriculture issued orders regulating the marketing
of milk in the New York-New Jersey region. To protect the prices
received by milk producers in that region, he included in the
orders a provision in effect requiring those who buy milk elsewhere
and bring it into the region for sale as fluid milk to pay to the
producers who regularly supply the region a "compensatory payment"
equal to the difference between the minimum price set by the Market
Administrator for fluid milk and the minimum price for surplus milk
in the region.
Held: this requirement is invalid because it conflicts
with § 8c(5)(G) of the Act, which, as shown by its legislative
history, was intended by Congress to prevent the Secretary from
setting up trade barriers to the importation of milk from other
production areas in the United States. Pp.
370 U. S.
77-100.
287 F.2d 726 reversed.
Page 370 U. S. 77
MR. JUSTICE HARLAN delivered the opinion of the Court.
Petitioners, operating milk processing plants in Pennsylvania,
challenge the validity of certain "compensatory payment" provisions
included in milk marketing orders affecting the New York-New Jersey
area, which were promulgated by the Secretary of Agriculture under
the authority granted him by § 8c of the Agricultural
Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 7 U.S.C. § 608c. That section
permits the Secretary to issue regional regulations governing, in
various enumerated respects, the marketing of certain agricultural
commodities, among which is milk. This provision in question
requires those who buy milk elsewhere and bring it into the region
for sale as fluid milk to pay to the farmers who supply the region
a fixed amount as a "compensatory payment." This amount is measured
by the difference between the minimum price set by the Market
Administrator for fluid milk and the minimum price for surplus
milk. The judgment of the Court of Appeals for the Third Circuit,
287 F.2d 726, upholding the validity of the "compensatory payment"
provision here under attack, [
Footnote 1] conflicted with an earlier
Page 370 U. S. 78
decision rendered by the Court of Appeals for the Second
Circuit,
Kass v. Brannan, 196 F.2d 791. To resolve this
conflict, we granted certiorari. 366 U.S. 957.
I
The General Scheme of Milk Regulation
The order around which the present controversy centers, now
titled Milk Marketing Order No. 2, 7 CFR §§ 1002.1
et
seq., [
Footnote 2] though
somewhat more complex than others, is in its general outline
representative of the pattern of regulation established by the
Secretary for the promotion of orderly marketing conditions in the
milk industry and the preservation of minimum prices for farmers.
Pursuant to the authority granted by § 8c(5)(A), [
Footnote 3] the Order classifies milk
that is sold within
Page 370 U. S. 79
the New York-New Jersey marketing area "in accordance with the
form in which or the purpose for which it is used." Milk that
contains 3% to 5% butterfat-the usual proportion in ordinary liquid
milk -- and is sold for fluid consumption is assigned to Class I.
Milk that is used for cream (sweet and sour), half and half, or
milk drinks containing less than 3% or more than 5% butterfat is
classified in Class II. The remainder -- milk that is to be stored
for a substantial period and used for dairy products such as butter
and cheese -- is grouped in Class III. 7 CFR § 1002.37.
This classification reflects the relative prices usually
commanded by the different forms of milk. Thus, highest prices are
paid for milk used for fluid consumption, and the lowest for milk
which is to be processed into butter and cheese. Since the supply
of milk is always greater than the demands of the fluid-milk
market, the excess must be channeled to the less desirable,
lower-priced outlets. It is in order to avoid destructive
competition among milk producers for the premium outlets that the
statute authorizes the Secretary to devise a method whereby uniform
prices are paid by milk handlers to producers for all milk
received, regardless of the form in which
Page 370 U. S. 80
it leaves the plant and its ultimate use. Adjustments are then
made among the handlers so that each eventually pays out-of-pocket
an amount equal to the actual utilization value of the milk he has
bought.
Under the Marketing Order here in question, it is primarily the
handlers whose plants are located within the marketing area and who
regularly supply that area with fluid milk who are regulated. All
handlers who receive or distribute milk within the area are
required to submit monthly reports to the Market Administrator,
listing the quantity of milk they have handled and the use for
which it was sold. But only the handlers operating "pool plants" --
i.e., plants which meet certain standards set out in 7 CFR
§§ 1002.25-1002.29 [
Footnote 4] -- must pay the producers from whom they buy
the uniform price set by the Administrator. This price is
calculated each month on the basis of the reports that are
submitted. After determining the minimum prices for each use
classification pursuant to formulas set out in 7 CFR §
1002.40, the Administrator computes an average price for the "pool"
milk handled during that month. This figure is reached by first
multiplying the "pool" milk disposed of in each class by the
established minimum price for that class, and then adding the
products to the "compensatory payments" made for nonpool milk.
After certain minor adjustments are made, this sum is divided by
the total quantity of "pool" milk sold in the market during the
month. The quotient is a "blend price." With some adjustments to
reflect transportation expenses, this uniform price must be paid to
producers by all handlers maintaining "pool" plants. 7 CFR §
1002.66.
Page 370 U. S. 81
Adjustments among handlers are made by way of a "Producer
Settlement Fund," into which each handler contributes the excess of
his "use value" [
Footnote 5]
over the uniform price paid by him to his producer. Handlers whose
"use value" of the milk they purchase is less than the "blend
price" they are required to pay may withdraw the difference from
the fund. The net effect is that each handler pays for his milk at
the price he would have paid had it been earmarked at the outset
for the use to which it was ultimately put. But the farmer who
produces the milk is protected from the effects of competition for
premium outlets since he is automatically allotted a proportional
share of each of the different "use" markets.
II
The Compensatory Payment Provision
It will thus be seen that this system of regulation contemplates
economic controls only over "pool-handler" plants, since only such
handlers are required to pay the "blend price" to their producers
and to account to the Producer Settlement Fund. If limited to the
provisions recounted above, the regulatory scheme would not affect
milk brought into the New York-New Jersey marketing area by
handlers who are primarily engaged in supplying some other market
and whose producers are not located within the New York-New Jersey
area. Some of the regional orders now in effect do not undertake
any economic regulation of "outside" or "other source" milk.
[
Footnote 6] But it is quite
obvious that, under certain circumstances, some regulation of such
milk may be necessary. Accordingly,
Page 370 U. S. 82
§ 8c(7)(D) of the Act, 7 U.S.C. § 608c(7)(D),
authorizes the Secretary to include in his regulating orders
conditions that are incidental to terms expressly authorized by the
statute, and that are "necessary to effectuate the other provisions
of such order."
A handler who brings outside milk into a marketing area may
disrupt the regulatory scheme in at least two respects:
"(1)
Pool handlers in the marketing area who are
required to pay the minimum class prices for their milk may find
their selling prices undercut by those of nonpool handlers dealing
in outside milk purchased at an unregulated price."
"(2)
Producers in the marketing area, whose 'blend
price' depends on how much of the relatively constant fluid-milk
demand they supply in a given month, may find the outside milk
occupying a portion of the premium market, thus displacing the
'pool' milk and forcing it into the less rewarding surplus uses,
with the ultimate effect of diminishing the 'blend price' payable
to producers."
In an effort to cope with these disruptive economic forces, the
Secretary devised his "compensatory payment" plan. In essence, the
plan imposes special monetary exactions on handlers introducing
"outside" milk for fluid consumption into a marketing area in
months when there is a substantial surplus of milk on the market.
[
Footnote 7]
Of the 68 regional milk orders which establish marketwide pools,
[
Footnote 8] 64 contain
"compensatory payment" provisions
Page 370 U. S. 83
of one kind or another. The Order now before us is typical of 23
of these orders. [
Footnote 9]
The Order provides that a handler who brings "outside" milk into
the New York-New Jersey area and sells it for fluid use must pay to
the pool's producers, through the Producer Settlement Fund, an
amount equal to the difference between the minimum prices for the
highest and for the lowest use classifications prevailing in that
area. In other words, for each hundredweight of non-pool milk sold
for Class I use in the New York-New Jersey area, a payment equal to
the difference between Class I and Class III prices must be made by
the seller to the Producer Settlement Fund.
III
The Purpose and Effect of the Compensatory Payment
After the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit had held that
compensatory payment requirement in the New York-New Jersey Milk
Marketing Order (then Order No. 27) to be a "penalty,"
Kass v.
Brannan, 196 F.2d
Page 370 U. S. 84
791, 795, the Secretary of Agriculture conducted extensive
hearings to determine whether it should be retained. His findings,
which appear at 18 Fed.Reg. 8444-8454, explain this requirement as
the most satisfactory means of imposing
"a suitable charge on such unpriced milk in an amount sufficient
to neutralize, compensate for and eliminate the artificial economic
advantage for non-pool milk which necessarily is created by the
classified pricing and pooling of pool milk under the order."
Id. at 8448. There seems little doubt that an
assessment equal to the Class I-Class III differential would, in
all but rare instances, nullify any competitive advantage that
nonpool milk could have: only if the sum of the purchase price of
the outside milk and the cost of its transportation to market were
less than the Class III price would a handler find it profitable to
bring such milk into the marketing area. But it must be obvious
that this payment is wholly or partially "compensatory" --
i.e., puts pool and nonpool milk "on substantially similar
competitive positions at source" (
ibid.) -- only if the
milk has been purchased at not more than the Class III price. If
the purchase price of the nonpool milk exceeds the Class III price
within the area, the effect of the fixed compensatory payment is to
make it economically unfeasible for a handler to bring such milk
into the marketing area.
The Secretary of Agriculture's determination that the Class
I-Class III differential was the most suitable compensatory figure
rested upon what was, in effect, an irrebuttable presumption that
the nonpool milk was purchased at a rate commensurate with the
value of "surplus" (Class III) milk.
See 18 Fed.Reg. at
8448. [
Footnote 10]
Page 370 U. S. 85
That presumption was based in turn on the supposition that the
nonpool milk could not have been worth more than the Class III
price where purchased, since it could not be shipped elsewhere for
Class I use. But it must
Page 370 U. S. 86
be apparent that it is only if the milk is denied access to
other marketing areas or if a prohibitive payment is assessed on
its use elsewhere that it will depreciate in value to Class III
levels. For if the milk can be freely shipped elsewhere for fluid
use or if it is purchased in an area where prices paid to producers
are regulated, it will command a higher price.
Indeed, the facts of the case now before us demonstrate the
shortcomings of the Secretary's reasoning. One of the petitioners,
Suncrest Farms, Inc., purchases its milk in Pennsylvania under
regulations established by the Pennsylvania Milk Control
Commission. In September, 1957, which was one of the months during
which it sought to sell its milk in the New York-New Jersey
Marketing Area, Suncrest was required to pay $6.40 per cwt. for the
milk it purchased from dairy farmers in Pennsylvania. The Class
I-Class III differential in the New York-New Jersey Marketing Area
during that month was $2.78 per cwt. Thus, if the "compensatory
payment" were assessed, Suncrest would actually be forced to pay
$9.18 per cwt. for fluid milk sold in the area, while the handlers
maintaining pool plants in the area would pay only the Class I
price, which was $6.23 in August 1957. [
Footnote 11]
If competitive parity among handlers of pool and nonpool milk
were the only objective of the Secretary's "compensatory"
regulation, other marketing orders of the Secretary show that this
result has been achieved without imposing unnecessary hardships,
virtually "trade
Page 370 U. S. 87
barriers" as in the instance just given, [
Footnote 12] on the nonpool milk. [
Footnote 13]
It is in considering the effect of the present compensatory
payment provision on the pool producers, however,
Page 370 U. S. 88
that the principal concern of the Secretary becomes quite
apparent. As has been noted (p.
370 U. S. 82
supra), the sale for fluid use of nonpool milk in the
marketing area displaces pool milk that might otherwise be used for
this premium outlet. Since the market area's "blend price" is
computed only with reference to the pool milk, the effect of the
entry of nonpool milk is to drive down the price that
Page 370 U. S. 89
is paid to producers in the area. A close examination of the
workings of the present compensatory payment provision reveals that
its effect is to preserve for the benefit of the area's producers
the blend price that they would receive if all outside milk were
physically excluded and they alone would supply the fluid-milk
needs of the area. For every cwt. of pool milk that is forced into
"surplus" use by the entry of nonpool milk, the handler introducing
the outside milk is required to pay for the benefit of the area's
producers the difference between the value the pool milk would have
had if the nonpool milk had never entered and the value it has once
the nonpool milk is sold for fluid use. [
Footnote 14] In effect, therefore, the nonpool milk
is
Page 370 U. S. 90
forced to subsidize the pool milk and insulate the pool milk
from the competitive impact caused by the entry of outside milk.
This was recognized by the Court of Appeals, which held that such a
compensatory payment
Page 370 U. S. 91
was "designed to compensate the pool for the loss of the Class I
fluid milk utilization and . . . protect the uniform blend price in
the marketing area." 287 F.2d at 730. It is only if the Secretary
has been authorized by the statute to impose such economic trade
barriers on the entry of milk into an area so as to protect the
prices received by the pool producers that the present compensatory
payment plan can be sustained as "necessary to effectuate" the
expressly authorized provisions of this Order.
IV
.
Section 8c(5)(G)
Section 8c(5)(G) of the Act, however, taken in light of its
legislative history, indicates that the regulation here imposed by
the Secretary was of the sort that Congress intended to forbid.
Section 8c(5)(G) provides:
"No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its
products in any marketing area shall prohibit or in any manner
limit, in the case of the products of milk, the marketing in that
area of any milk or product thereof produced in any production area
in the United States."
This provision was first enacted into law as part of the
Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1935, 49 Stat. 750, amending the
Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933, 48 Stat. 31. It was reenacted
as part of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 50
Stat. 246, which reaffirmed the marketing order provisions of the
1935 Act after the processing tax had been struck down as
unconstitutional in
United States v. Butler, 297 U. S.
1.
Along with enumerating the powers granted to the Secretary of
Agriculture so as to avoid the "delegation" problems brought to
light by the then recent decision in
Schechter Poultry Corp. v.
United States, 295 U. S. 495, the
Congress
Page 370 U. S. 92
sought in 1935 to limit the Secretary's powers so as to prevent
him from establishing "trade barriers." Midwestern legislators were
particularly concerned over this possibility. When the reported
bill which contained no provision like the present § 8c(5)(G)
came to the floor of the House of Representatives, Representative
Andresen of Minnesota suggested that the Secretary might use his
powers to "stop the free flow in commerce . . . of dairy products."
He received an assurance from Representative Jones, the Chairman of
the House Committee on Agriculture, that the Secretary was not
authorized to require anything more of milk coming into a marketing
area than that it "comply with the same conditions which the
farmers and distributors comply with in that region." 79 Cong.Rec.
9462. [
Footnote 15] An
amendment to the bill clarifying this position was then offered by
Representative
Page 370 U. S. 93
Sauthoff of Wisconsin, 79 Cong.Rec. 9493, [
Footnote 16] but no action was taken on that
proposal.
On the next day, Representative Andresen proposed from the floor
of the House the forerunner to the present § 8c(5)(G). 79
Cong.Rec. 9572. His amendment took the following form:
"(g) No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its
products in any marketing area shall prohibit the marketing in that
area of any milk or product thereof produced in any production area
in the United States."
There was no objection to the addition of this language,
Representative Jones remarking that "[i]t is simply clarifying."
Ibid. But when Representative Sauthoff sought to change
the amendment by substituting the words "limit or tend to limit"
for "prohibit," Representative Jones objected on the ground that
necessary milk classification and minimum pricing for the
protection of outside milk producers regularly supplying their own
marketing area would "tend to limit" the introduction of their milk
into other areas. [
Footnote
17]
Ibid.
Page 370 U. S. 94
The House bill, with the language added by Representative
Andresen's amendment, went to the Senate. Accompanying the bill to
the floor was S.Rep.No. 1011, 74th Cong., 1st Sess., which stated
at p. 11:
"To prevent assaults upon the price structure by the sporadic
importation of milk from new producing areas, while permitting the
orderly and natural expansion of the area supplying any market by
the introduction of new producers or new producing areas, orders
may provide that for the first 3 months
Page 370 U. S. 95
of regular delivery, payments shall be made to producers not
theretofore selling milk in the area covered by the order at the
price fixed for the lowest use classification.
This is the only
limitation upon the entry of new producers -- wherever located --
into a market, and it can remain effective only for the specified
3-month period."
(Emphasis added.) [
Footnote
18]
In the Senate, § 8c(5)(G) was amended, without objection,
79 Cong.Rec. 11655, to read:
"(G) No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its
products in any marketing area shall prohibit or in any manner
limit, except as provided for milk only in subsection (d), the
marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof produced in
any production area in the United States. [
Footnote 19]"
Section 8c(5)(G) emerged from conference in its present form.
The conference report explained how the differences between the
House and Senate versions were resolved (H.R.Rep.No. 1757, 74th
Cong., 1st Sess. 21):
". . . The conference agreement retains the House provision with
respect to prohibitions on marketing of both milk and products of
milk. The conference agreement also denies the authority to limit
in any manner the marketing in any area of milk products (butter,
cheese, cream, etc.) produced anywhere in the United States. The
language adopted by the conference agreement does not refer to
milk, and so does not negative the applicability to milk, for use
in fluid form or for manufacturing purposes, of the provisions
Page 370 U. S. 96
of the bill relating to milk, such as the provisions on
price-fixing, price adjustment, payments for milk, etc."
When the conference agreement came to the floor of the House,
Representative Jones again explained what § 8c(5)(G), when
taken together with § 8c(5)(D), meant (79 Cong.Rec.
13022):
"Mr. SNELL. . . . I do not understand exactly what this means,
'No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its
products,' and so forth."
"Mr. JONES. That simply applies to fluid milk. You cannot make
any limitation at all on the amount of butter or cheese or milk
products that are shipped from any one area to another,
and the
limitation that may be applied on milk is only such limitation as
puts each area on an equality with the other areas after a certain
period of about 2 1/2 months."
"Mr. SNELL. How does that change the situation from the present
law?"
"Mr. JONES. The provisions of this particular bill would enable
that area to be protected from being swamped with fluid milk from
the outside, bought at any old price. For instance, if you do not
have the protection of this bill, they would run into the same
trouble they ran into in the New York milk cases, where they went
into New Hampshire and bought milk at a lower price and came in and
broke down your milk agreements. Under the provisions of this bill
if a price were fixed in this particular area in New York, then, if
anyone bought milk from an outside area and brought it in, he would
be compelled to
pay the producer the same price that was being
paid the producers within the area and comply with
Page 370 U. S. 97
all regulations and requirements of that area. For the first 2
months he would be required to take the manufacturer's price."
(Emphasis added.)
This history discloses that, rather than being confined, as
Judge Learned Hand suggested in
Kass v. Brannan, 196 F.2d
at 800, to practices aimed at the exclusion of cheese and other
milk products from eastern markets, § 8c(5)(G) was
compendiously intended to prevent the Secretary from setting up,
under the guise of price-fixing regulation, any kind of economic
trade barriers, whether relating to milk or its products. Whenever
there was an attempt to broaden the language of subsection (G) to
encompass "limitations," as well as "prohibitions," those opposing
it pointed only to the fact that "limit" might be read as including
the type of price-fixing covered by subsection (D) --
i.e., allowing new pool producers only manufacturing use
prices for a limited period -- or other attempts to put outside
milk on an equal footing with pool milk. Although the words of
§ 8c(5)(G), "in any manner limit," must be taken, in the
context of their legislative history, as referring only to milk
products, that history likewise makes it clear that as regards milk
the word "prohibit" refers not merely to absolute or quota physical
restrictions, but also encompasses economic trade barriers of the
kind effected by the subsidies called for by this "compensatory
payment" provision.
V
The Invalidity of the Present Compensatory Payment
Provision.
In light of the legislative history of § 8c(5)(G), we
conclude that the compensatory payment provision of the New
York-New Jersey Milk Marketing Order must fall as inconsistent with
the policy expressed by Congress in
Page 370 U. S. 98
that section. [
Footnote
20] Because it conflicts with § 8c(5)(G), the payment
provision cannot be justified under the general terms of §
8c(7)(D), which prevents the inclusion of conditions that are
inconsistent with express statutory provisions. Nor is the
compensatory payment clause saved by the circumstance that, in some
instances, it may also fortuitously operate to put the handlers of
pool and nonpool milk on a competitive par. As has been pointed out
(
note 13 supra),
there are other means available to the Secretary for achieving this
result, while affording protection to pool producers, without
imposing almost insuperable trade restrictions on the entry of
nonpool milk into a marketing area.
The Government contends that the effect of § 8c(5)(G) may
not be considered by this Court, since that provision was not cited
by the petitioners in the administrative proceeding in the
Department of Agriculture. But even on the Government's premise
that an unauthorized regulation should be upheld by this Court
merely because the provision prohibiting it was not cited in the
administrative proceeding in which it was attacked, this case
presents no such instance. The administrative petition filed with
the Department of Agriculture alleged that the effect of the
compensatory payment clause amounted "to establishing tariffs or
barriers interfering with the free flow of milk across state
lines," an obvious reference to the prohibition of §
8c(5)(G).
In addition, the Government contends that the petitioners had
the choice of joining the marketwide pool, in which case they would
not have been subject to the compensatory payment provisions. Their
election to stay
Page 370 U. S. 99
out of the pool, it is argued, bars any attack on the
consequences of their choice. However, such an "election" is surely
illusory. The consequences of joining the pool would have been that
petitioners would have been forced to pay the "blend price" to all
their producers wherever located and account to the Producer
Settlement Fund for all milk wherever sold. In these circumstances,
the election was not voluntary, as in
Booth Fisheries Co. v.
Industrial Comm'n, 271 U. S. 208,
271 U. S. 211.
It was coercive and, indeed, no election at all.
Whether full regulation of the petitioners would be permissible
under the Act is a question which we need not reach in this case.
If the Secretary chooses to impose such regulation as a consequence
of a handler's introducing any milk into a marketing area, the
validity of such a provision would involve considerations different
from those now before us. With respect to these petitioners,
however, and with regard to the regulation here in issue, we
conclude that the action of the Secretary of Agriculture exceeded
the powers entrusted to him by Congress.
The Secretary of course remains free to protect, in any manner
consistent with the provisions of the statute, the "blend price" in
this or any other marketing area against economic consequences
resulting from the introduction of outside milk. We do not now
decide whether or not any new regulation directed to that end could
be made to apply retrospectively, or whether, if it could be
validly so applied, the presently impounded funds could be resorted
to
pro tanto in its effectuation.
Cf. United States v.
Morgan, 307 U. S. 183.
"What further proceedings the Secretary may see fit to take in
the light of our decision, or what determinations may be made by
the District Court in relation to any such proceedings, are not
matters which we should attempt to forecast or hypothetically to
decide."
Morgan v. United States, 304 U. S.
1,
304 U. S. 23,
304 U. S. 26.
Page 370 U. S. 100
The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed, and the case
is remanded to the District Court for further proceedings
consistent with this opinion.
It is so ordered.
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER took no part in the decision of this
case.
MR. JUSTICE WHITE took no part in the consideration or decision
of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
The petitioners instituted this action challenging the validity
of the compensatory payment provision by filing administrative
petitions with the Secretary of Agriculture pursuant to §
8c(15)(A) of the Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937, 7
U.S.C. § 608c(15)(A). The Hearing Examiner sustained the
petitioners' contentions on the authority of
Kass v.
Brannan, 196 F.2d 791, but the Judicial Officer, acting on
behalf of the Secretary of Agriculture, dismissed the
petitions.
Petitioners then sought review of the Secretary's ruling in the
District Court under § 8c(15)(B) of the Act. The review
proceedings were consolidated with enforcement actions brought by
the Government pursuant to § 8a(6) of the Act. The District
Court, relying on
Kass v. Brannan, supra, held that the
payment provision was invalid. 183 F. Supp. 80. It was this
decision that was reversed by the Court of Appeals. 287 F.2d
726.
[
Footnote 2]
A general reorganization of Chapter IX of Title 7 of the Code of
Federal Regulations during the past year has resulted in
redesignation of most of the milk marketing orders. The New
York-New Jersey Order had previously been designated as Milk
Marketing Order No. 27, and had been found at 7 CFR § 927. The
section references and the contents of the regulations as quoted
throughout this opinion are as they were in effect on January 1,
1962.
[
Footnote 3]
Section 8c(5)(A) provides:
"(5)
Milk and its products; terms and conditions of
orders."
"In the case of milk and its products, orders issued pursuant to
this section shall contain one or more of the following terms and
conditions, and (except as provided in subsection (7) of this
section) no others:"
"(A) Classifying milk in accordance with the form in which or
the purpose for which it is used, and fixing, or providing a method
for fixing, minimum prices for each such use classification which
all handlers shall pay, and the time when payments shall be made
for milk purchased from producers or associations of producers.
Such prices shall be uniform as to all handlers, subject only to
adjustments for (1) volume, market, and production differentials
customarily applied by the handlers subject to such order, (2) the
grade or quality of the milk purchased, and (3) the locations at
which delivery of such milk, or any use classification thereof, is
made to such handlers."
7 U.S.C. § 608c(5)(A).
[
Footnote 4]
These provisions establish certain performance requirements
aimed at insuring that the plant continues to provide fluid milk to
the marketing area even in periods of short supply. Thus, it is
primarily the handlers whose main concern is the marketing area who
qualify for the "pool."
[
Footnote 5]
"Use value" is the price the handler would have had to pay at
prevailing minimum rates had he purchased his milk at a price
reflecting its ultimate disposition.
[
Footnote 6]
See 7 CFR §§ 1034 (Dayton-Springfield), 1037
(North Central Ohio), 1038 (Rockford-Freeport), 1074 (Southwest
Kansas).
[
Footnote 7]
The payment provision of 7 CFR § 1002.83 applies only in
those months when the volume of milk sold for Class III use exceeds
15% of the total pool milk reported in the marketing area.
[
Footnote 8]
The Act authorizes the establishment of either marketwide pools
or individual handler pools. Since the latter require only that
each handler pay uniform prices to all the producers from which he
buys, but does not impose a uniformity requirement among the
various handlers, there is no need for adjustments among handlers.
Consequently, no compensatory payment provision is included in
orders establishing individual handler pools.
See 7 CFR
§§ 1004 (Philadelphia), 1005 (Tri-State), 1010
(Wilmington), 1039 (Milwaukee), 1041 (Toledo), 1044 (Michigan Upper
Peninsula), 1078 (North Central Iowa), 1096 (Northern Louisiana),
1097 (Memphis), 1102 (Fort Smith), 1129 (Austin-Waco), 1130 (Corpus
Christi), 1134 (Western Colorado).
[
Footnote 9]
Compare 7 CFR §§ 1001.65 (Greater Boston),
1003.62 (Washington, D.C.), 1006.65 (Springfield, Mass.), 1007.65
(Worcester), 1008.54 (Wheeling), 1009.54 (Clarksburg, W. Va.),
1011.62 (Appalachian), 1014.46 (Southeastern New England), 1015.46
(Connecticut), 1016.62 (Upper Chesapeake Bay), 1030.61 (Chicago),
1031.70(b) (South Bend-LaPorte-Elkhart), 1036.84(b) (Northeastern
Ohio), 1048.54 (Greater Youngstown-Warren), 1061.54 (St. Joseph),
1068.70(b) (Minneapolis-St. Paul), 1071.62(b) (Neosho Valley),
1072.55 (Sioux Falls-Mitchell), 1106.55 (Oklahoma), 1125.70 (Puget
Sound), 1126.70(d) (North Texas), 1133.70(b) (Inland Empire).
[
Footnote 10]
"As stated earlier herein, all milk which is established to be
primarily associated with the New York milk marketing area under
the standards prescribed by the order is included in the New York
pool. Conversely, the non-pool milk which enters the marketing area
for fluid use originates from plans which are not sufficiently
associated with the New York market to have their milk in the pool.
Such plants have their primary interests in other fluid markets or
specialized manufacturing uses, and frequently have more milk than
is required for these primary purposes. It is this surplus milk at
non-pool plants which can be 'dumped' into the New York market for
fluid use, provided only that the plant and the milk [have]
marketing area health approval. The operator of such a non-pool
plant has a choice of using the excess milk for surplus uses
(ordinarily in the manufacture of various milk products) or of
sending it to the New York marketing area for fluid uses. In making
this decision he will compare the respective net returns to him for
this surplus milk and will naturally select the fluid alternative,
for it will yield the greater return. In the absence of classified
pricing, his cost at source for the excess milk remains exactly the
same whether he uses it for surplus disposition or for fluid use.
The pool plant operator, on the other hand, has no such advantage,
for he pays a higher classified price at source if he sells the
milk in the market area for fluid use (Class I-A or II) than if he
disposes of it for surplus manufacturing uses (Class III)."
"If this artificial advantage in favor of surplus non-pool milk
at the plant of origin is to be effectively removed, as it must be,
the milk must be treated and evaluated for what it actually is,
namely surplus milk in the milkshed. If New York marketing area
disposition were not available for this surplus, the non-pool
handler could derive from it only its surplus value. This surplus
value is its true value or 'opportunity cost,' and such surplus
value should be used as the subtrahend in the formula for
compensation payments on non-pool milk from plants not subject to a
Federal order."
"The Class III price under the New York order is the class price
which is payable at source, for pool milk under the New York order
when used for most surplus uses. It is expressly designed to fix a
proper classified value at source, for surplus milk. The Class III
price closely approximates the amount paid in the Northeast to
farmers not under the New York order for so much of their milk as
is used for general manufacture."
"It is therefore a dependable indicator of the value of surplus
milk at source. If a non-pool handler, for his own reasons, choses
to pay more than its true market value at source, for surplus milk
which he sends to the New York area, the pool should not underwrite
this unnecessary cost, particularly since the premium can be used
to outbid pool handlers for milk, as previously shown."
[
Footnote 11]
The fact that petitioners were paying more for their milk than
the Class I price in the New York-New Jersey Marketing Area leaves
no room for any suggestion that they will be receiving a "windfall"
if it is ultimately adjudged that they are entitled to have
returned the full amount of their compensatory payments.
[
Footnote 12]
The total amount of the compensatory payments involved in this
litigation, embracing a period of approximately four years, was
some $617,000 as to Lehigh Valley and $108,000 as to Suncrest.
[
Footnote 13]
Several of the marketing orders make the compensatory payment
equal the difference between the Class I price in the marketing
area and the actual cost of the nonpool milk.
See 7 CFR
§§ 1042.60 (Muskegon), 1128.62(b) (Central West Texas).
In some marketing areas, the handler who deals in nonpool milk is
permitted to elect each month between paying the fluid milk-surplus
use differential and paying the difference between his actual cost
and the minimum regional price for Class I milk.
See 7 CFR
§§ 1013.62 (Southeastern Florida), 1033.61 (Greater
Cincinnati), 1035.63 (Columbus, Ohio), 1040.66 (Southern Michigan),
1043.84 (Upstate Michigan), 1045.83 (Northeastern Wisconsin),
1047.62 (Fort Wayne), 1064.61 (Greater Kansas City), 1065.62
(Nebraska-Western Iowa), 1067.61 (Ozarks), 1069.62
(Duluth-Superior), 1073.62 (Wichita), 1094.62 (New Orleans),
1098.92 (Nashville), 1103.62 (Central Mississippi), 1105.62
(Mississippi Delta), 1107.61 (Mississippi Gulf Coast), 1131.62
(Central Arizona), 1135.62 (Colorado Springs-Pueblo), 1136.62
(Great Basin), 1137.62 (Eastern Colorado).
Other marketing orders, applicable in some areas, assess a
compensatory payment equal to the difference between the "blend
price" paid in the area for pool milk and the Class I price, thus
treating the handler of nonpool milk as if he were a member of the
pool with respect to such milk as he introduced into the marketing
area.
Where this differential is accepted as the measure of the
compensatory payment, it is done only in those months when the
surplus is lowest. In the spring and summer months, the fluid milk
surplus use differential is exacted.
See 7 CFR
§§ 1032.55(b) (Suburban St. Louis, August-February),
1046.55(b) (Ohio Valley, August-March), 1049.55(b) (Indianapolis,
August-March), 1062.55(b) (St. Louis August-February), 1063.63(b)
(Quad Cities-Dubuque, July-November), 1066.57(a) (Sioux City,
August-February), 1070.63(b) (Cedar Rapids-Iowa City,
July-November), 1075.63(b) (Black Hills, July-March), 1076.63(b)
(Eastern South Dakota, July-February), 1079.63(b) (Des Moines,
July-March), 1090.54(b) (Chattanooga, August-February),
1095.70(e)(2) (Louisville-Lexington, October-December), 1099.62(a)
(Paducah, August-March), 1101.93(b) (Knoxville, August-February),
1104.53(b) (Red River Valley, August-January), 1108.54(b), (Central
Arkansas, August-February), 1127.65(b) (San Antonio, January and
August), 1132.63(b) (Texas Panhandle, July-February).
The latter method treats the handler of nonpool milk who buys at
a price in excess of the blend price as if he were a member of the
pool, since a handler in the pool may, if he chooses, pay his
producer more than the "blend price" set by the Market
Administrator,
see Stark v. Wickard, 321 U.
S. 288,
321 U. S. 291,
but must still account to the Producer Settlement Fund as if he had
paid only the "blend price." By treating nonpool milk in the same
manner, the Secretary might be able to justify a compensatory
payment equal to the difference between the nonpool milk's "use
value" and the "blend price," though we do not decide the question.
See generally Hutt, Restrictions on the Free Movement of
Fluid Milk Under Federal Milk Marketing Orders, 37 U.Det.L.J. 525,
564-577 (1960).
The suggestion that a nonpool handler would be given a
competitive advantage under either of these methods because, in the
words of the Judicial Officer, he does not have "to equalize his
utilization" as do pool handlers is demonstrably unsound. Insofar
as the handlers' sale of milk is concerned, neither pool nor
non-pool handlers are required to share or "equalize" their
proceeds with others. To the extent that this contention relates to
the handlers' purchase of milk and is meant to suggest that nonpool
handlers will find it easier to buy milk because they will be able
to pay higher prices to their producers, the exaction of a Class I
blend price payment would effectively discourage purchases in
excess of the blend price (which is what the pool's producers are
paid). And the assertion that the pool "carries the surplus burden
for outside handlers" is based on the same mistaken reasoning as
underlies the Secretary's determination to retain the Class I-Class
III payment after
Kass v. Brannan, supra. See pp.
370 U. S. 84-86
supra.
[
Footnote 14]
A highly simplified illustration serves to clarify this effect:
If the Class I price on a given date is $6 per cwt. and the Class
III price is $3 per cwt., and if 2,000 cwt. are consumed as fluid
milk and another 2,000 cwt. are produced by the dairy farmers in
the area and utilized for surplus uses, the computation of the
blend price would be as follows:
Table A
Class I . . . . . 2,000 x 6.00 equals 12,000
Class III . . . . 2,000 x 3.00 equals 6,000
------
Totals. . . . . 4,000 at 18,000
Blend Price . . . . . . . . $4.50
If 500 cwt. are then brought in from the outside as nonpool milk
and sold for Class I use, 500 cwt. of the pool milk will drop into
Class III (since the fluid milk demand remains relatively
constant):
Table B
Class I . . . . . 1,500 x 6.00 equals 9,000
Class III . . . . 2,500 x 3.00 equals 7,500
------
Totals 4,000 at 16,500
Blend Price . . . . . . . . $4.125
The producers in the pool would thereby be receiving $.375 less
per cwt. than had the nonpool milk stayed out altogether. By
distributing to them (through the exaction made of nonpool
handlers) the difference between Class I and Class III prices
multiplied by the amount of nonpool milk sold in the area as Class
I, that deficit is restored. Thus,
Table C
(Nonpool milk sold as Class I) x (Class minus
ClassIII)
equals
(Loss to pool by displacement of Class I outlet)
or
500 x 3.00 equals 1,500
1,500 divided by 4,000 cwt. equals .375 per cwt.
The Secretary's formula, therefore, precisely accomplishes the
restoring to the pool's producers whatever they have lost by reason
of the occupation of their Class I outlet by the nonpool milk.
It should be noted that the actual computation of the blend
price, as set out in 7 CFR § 1002.66, achieves this same
result in an indirect fashion. Instead of computing the blend price
without reference to any nonpool milk, the Secretary's formula
includes the compensatory payments within the list of minimum-price
obligations that are added in determining the total proceeds for
milk sold within the area. 7 CFR § 1002.66(c). But the blend
price is then computed by dividing this sum by the amount of "milk
delivered by producers,"
i.e., pool milk. Consequently,
the actual computation of the uniform price under the above
illustration would be as follows:
Table D
Class I . . . . . 1,500 x 6.00 equals 9,000
Class III . . . . 2,500 x 3.00 equals 7,500
Compensatory pay-
ments (nonpool
milk) . . . . . 500 x 3.00 equals 1,500
------
Totals
(pool milk) 4,000 at 18,000
Blend Price . . . . . . . . $4.50
The funds paid into the Producer Settlement Fund by the handlers
dealing in nonpool milk are then available to the pool handlers,
whose credits from the Fund will be larger to the extent that they
have been forced to pay a higher blend price.
[
Footnote 15]
"Mr. ANDRESEN. Is there anything in the milk section of the bill
which gives the Secretary authority to set up trade barriers and
stop the free flow in commerce throughout the United States of
dairy products?"
"Mr. JONES. No. There is nothing in the bill that would
authorize that. The Secretary may require that, in crossing from
one region to another, that they comply with the same conditions
which the farmers and distributors comply with in that region."
"Mr. ANDRESEN. That is, sanitary regulations?"
"Mr. JONES. Sanitary and other uniform regulations;
but he
cannot set up any trade barriers which would keep them
out."
"Mr. ANDRESEN. A great many Members have inquired about that
feature, and I just wanted the gentleman to bring that out."
"Mr. JONES. The amendments require a uniform price and uniform
set of conditions and fair distribution. In the first place, I do
not believe we could give authority to set up these barriers. In
the second place, the bill does not do that. It simply enables them
to have a program in one of these regions, and in developing these
orders which the Secretary issues, the word 'region' wherever
possible. Those on the outside must come into that."
(Emphasis added.)
[
Footnote 16]
The proposed amendment read:
"Sec. ___ (b) No marketing agreement, order, or regulation shall
contain any term or provision which will tend to result in
preventing or hindering any agricultural commodity or product
thereof produced in any region or area of the United States from
being brought into or sold in any other such region or area, or
shall have the effect of subsidizing the production or sale of any
agricultural commodity or product thereof in any such region or
area, in such a manner that such commodity or product thereof will
tend to be sold in such other region or area at prices which will
tend to depress prices therein of such commodity or product
thereof."
[
Footnote 17]
"Mr. JONES. Mr. Chairman, the adoption of the amendment of the
gentleman from Wisconsin would absolutely wreck the whole milk
program. In order to get away from the terrific conditions that
have prevailed in the milk industry, there is provided in the bill
authority to fix a minimum price to producers. That. at least in a
measure, would limit or tend to limit shipment, and yet the
gentleman, I am sure, does not want to interfere with the price to
producers. Then it is a universal custom in the marketing of milk
to classify milk. This, in a way, is a limitation. . . ."
"Mr. BOILEAU. . . . Mr. Chairman, I should like to ask the
distinguished chairman of the committee if in his opinion there is
anything in this bill that gives to the Secretary of Agriculture or
to anyone else any power to restrict the free flow of milk or any
other commodity between the various States?"
"Mr. JONES. No; there is nothing in it that will do that. The
only tendency is to make all sections comply with the same
rules."
"Mr. HULL. . . . Mr. Chairman, if there is nothing in this bill
which would authorize the Secretary of Agriculture or any
subordinate so to limit transportation or shipment of dairy
products from one State into another, then the amendment of the
gentleman from Minnesota as amended by the amendment of the
gentleman from Wisconsin (Mr. Sauthoff) can do no harm."
"The three States of Minnesota, Iowa, and Wisconsin produce
about 45 percent of the butter made in this country, and we are
interested in this matter of the shipment of dairy products to
other States."
"Mr. JONES. Mr. Chairman, will the gentleman yield?"
"Mr. HULL. I yield."
"Mr. JONES. Would the gentleman object to the requirement that
Chicago dealers pay the Wisconsin producer a minimum price?"
"Mr. HULL. Not at all."
"Mr. JONES. That certainly would tend to limit."
[
Footnote 18]
The "3-month period" provision here referred to is the present
§ 8c(5)(D), which authorizes the Secretary to set the surplus
use price as the price to be paid to any new producer who enters
the pool. In the final version of the Act, the introductory period
was reduced to two months.
[
Footnote 19]
"Subsection (d)" is § 8c(5)(D).
See note 18 supra.
[
Footnote 20]
While we need not reach the point, we would have difficulty in
concluding, as did the Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit in
Kass v. Brannan, supra, that the provisions of §
8c(5)(A) precluded, in themselves, the promulgation of the present
compensatory payment provision.
MR. JUSTICE BLACK, dissenting.
I find it impossible to agree with the Court's holding or
opinion. In 1936, in
United States v. Butler, [
Footnote 2/1] this Court temporarily
paralyzed the national farm recovery program by holding important
parts of the Agricultural Adjustment Act of 1933 unconstitutional
and by casting grave doubts upon the remainder of that Act, which
had been passed at the bottom of the Great Depression for the
express purpose of alleviating the desperate economic plight of the
American farmer. Following that decision, Congress, in 1937, with
unusual promptness, adopted another national farm program
reaffirming the broad and comprehensive powers it had previously
given the Secretary of Agriculture to develop agricultural
marketing plans for the purpose of raising the income of farmers.
[
Footnote 2/2] The philosophy of
this later Act was not competition, as in the Sherman Act, but
governmental price-fixing, as in the original 1933 Agricultural
Adjustment Act, the National Industrial Recovery Act, and a host of
other contemporaneous Acts, all of which were designed to raise the
income and purchasing power of workers and farmers. Today, some 26
years after the
Butler decision, this Court
Page 370 U. S. 101
again projects itself across the path of the national farm
program by reading Congress' 1937 reenactment as designed to
encourage competition, rather than to help farmers by governmental
price-fixing, and, on this basis, strikes down a vital element of
many of the milk marketing orders set up under the 1937 Act while
raising clouds of confusion and uncertainty as to the validity of
many others. Although the blow to the present farm program is not
so devastating as the one inflicted on the original Act by the
Butler decision, I think that in ultimate effect the
harmful consequences of the two decisions will differ only in
degree. It is my belief that the order of the Secretary which the
Court strikes down was set up in faithful adherence to the Act's
purpose to raise the prices that farmers receive for their
products, and that the Court's action will tend to have precisely
the opposite effect of depressing those prices. I have no doubt but
that the Court's decision will enable some handlers to reap greater
profits, but I regret to say that this is bound to be at the
expense of the farmers themselves -- for whose benefit the national
program was primarily passed. Certainly this is true of the more
than $700,000 which the Court's decision today will allow the two
handlers here to be paid, which, of necessity, must come out of the
pockets of the dairy farmers where this milk was sold.
The basic features of the Act under which the Secretary
promulgated the regulation which the Court today strikes down were
first enacted in 1935, [
Footnote
2/3] when the dairy industry was near the bottom of its
depression and dairy farmers in many parts of the country were not
even receiving the actual cost of producing the milk they sold.
These 1935 provisions were themselves amendments to the original
1933 Agricultural Adjustment Act, and were designed to spell out
more clearly, and, to some extent, add
Page 370 U. S. 102
to, the broad powers which the original 1933 Act had given the
Secretary to correct the "severe and increasing disparity between
the prices of agricultural and other commodities" by raising "the
purchasing power of farmers" and stabilizing the value of the
"agricultural assets supporting the national credit structure."
[
Footnote 2/4]
The causes of the low prices to dairy farmers which led Congress
to grant these broad powers were, like the details of the operation
of the milk business itself, incredibly complex. In the main,
however, these low prices were widely attributed to a vicious and
destructive competition among dairy farmers for fluid milk sales
which brought farmers higher prices than did sales as surplus milk
for manufacturing butter, cheese and other milk products. [
Footnote 2/5] In order to bring an end to
this competition, which was pushing farmers to the wall, the 1935
Act gave the Secretary specific power to set up regional marketing
areas within which he could, for the Government, fix minimum prices
handlers would have to pay to farmers for the various uses of milk,
require that those minimum prices be paid to a pool for the area
and distribute the proceeds of the pool so that each farmer selling
milk through the pool would ultimately be paid at the same uniform
rate or "blend price" regardless of the use to which his particular
milk was put. [
Footnote 2/6] In the
original 1935 Act, the Secretary was directed to fix prices at
"parity" -- a level designed by Congress to insure that farmers
generally would receive a higher price for their products than they
could get in an open, competitive market. [
Footnote 2/7] The 1937 reenactment went beyond even
this, however, and gave the Secretary power to fix prices above
this parity level in order to
Page 370 U. S. 103
insure that dairy farmers in particular would receive a high
enough price for their products. [
Footnote 2/8] In order to make sure that the Secretary
had enough power to raise prices above the competitive level, the
Secretary was also authorized to issue orders "Incidental . . . and
necessary to effectuate" the specific price-fixing and other powers
given to him. [
Footnote 2/9] Thus,
it can be seen that the general scheme of the Act was to raise
prices to farmers by governmental fixing of minimum prices for
dairy products within specific regional areas, thereby abandoning
to that extent the system of price-fixing by competition.
In accordance with this general plan and under the authority of
the Act, the Secretary has proceeded after full hearings within the
various regions to set up a number of regional milk marketing
pools, one of which is the New York-Northern New Jersey pool whose
operation is jeopardized by the Court's decision today. [
Footnote 2/10] The Secretary has also
chosen to leave a number of areas unregulated. Obviously, in a
system including both large unregulated areas and regulated
regional pools in which prices may be fixed at different levels,
there will be significant and complicated problems involved in milk
sales and purchases that do not take place wholly within a single
pool. Among the most serious of these problems
Page 370 U. S. 104
is that handlers from outside a pool can, if left unregulated,
get the advantages of selling milk in that pool area without
bearing any of the burdens that members of that pool have to bear.
And, as shown by the record in this case, such sales can reduce the
net price received by the farmers within the pool area. In an
obvious effort to prevent any such harmful effects on the prices
received by farmers in the New York-Northern New Jersey pool, the
Secretary, properly, I think, acting under his authority to issue
orders "Incidental . . . and necessary to effectuate" his specific
price-fixing powers, provided that non-pool handlers who sold fluid
milk in that pool area at times when there was surplus fluid milk
in the pool should make a payment to compensate pool farmers for
the displacement of fluid sales they otherwise would have made,
compensate for the reduction of the regional pool fund which this
would cause and to compensate for the consequent diminution of the
blend price that would be paid to pool farmers. It is this key
regulatory feature which the Court strikes down as a "trade
barrier" prohibited by § 8c(5)(G) of the Act because it limits
the ability of outside handlers to sell milk within the pool area
at a profit.
It is no doubt true that the Secretary's requirement that
nonpool handlers make compensatory payments in order to sell fluid
milk within the New York-Northern New Jersey pool area does limit
to some extent the ability to handlers whose major business is
outside the pool to dump their surplus milk into the pool at highly
profitable fluid milk prices, and, if this is a trade barrier, the
Secretary's regulation can properly be called a "trade barrier."
But § 8c(5)(G) says nothing at all about prohibiting "trade
barriers" or guaranteeing high profits to handlers, and if it had,
it would have been at cross-purposes with the basic aim of the Act
to have government, rather than competition,
Page 370 U. S. 105
fix the minimum prices that farmers in designated regional areas
must be paid for their milk. It says only:
"No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its
products in any marketing area shall prohibit or
in any manner
limit, in the case of the products of milk, the marketing in
that area of any milk or product thereof produced in any production
area in the United States. [
Footnote
2/11]"
This language contains no words or arrangement of words of any
kind that would prohibit the Secretary from limiting the marketing
of milk in any regional area where necessary to protect the prices
fixed for that regional area. The Court, however, goes to great
lengths to try to show on the basis of legislative history that
Congress really meant the no-limitation clause to apply to milk, as
well as to milk products. In other words the Court wants to read
the statute as if Congress had said "No order shall prohibit or
limit the marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof."
But Congress simply did not say that. And the whole legislative
history persuades me that Congress knew exactly what it was saying,
and that, while it intended to forbid the Secretary from making
blanket prohibitions against outside milk, it also meant to leave
the Secretary free to establish whatever regulations were necessary
to guarantee that farmers in a price-fixing region received the
regional prices he was authorized to fix even though those
regulations might limit sales by outside handlers by making them
unprofitable. [
Footnote 2/12]
Outside the language of § 8c(5)(G) itself, the clearest
indication that this is the proper interpretation of the
legislative
Page 370 U. S. 106
history of the Act is that an amendment which would have made
the no-limitation clause applicable to milk, as well as milk
products, was defeated on the floor of the House, and that an
amendment to the same effect which passed the Senate was deleted in
Conference. [
Footnote 2/13] The
arguments of the Chairman of the House Committee on Agriculture,
one of the principal architects of the program,
Page 370 U. S. 107
against the amendment in the House show, almost conclusively, a
general understanding that regional price-fixing necessarily
required sales from out of the region to be limited if the
price-fixing were to be successful:
"Mr. JONES. Mr. Chairman,
the adoption of the amendment of
the gentleman from Wisconsin would absolutely wreck the whole milk
program. In order to get away from the terrific conditions that
have prevailed in the milk industry, there is provided in the bill
authority to fix a minimum price to producers. That, at least in a
measure, would limit or tend to limit shipment, and yet the
gentleman, I am sure, does not want to interfere with the price to
producers. Then it is a universal custom in the marketing of milk
to classify milk. This, in a way, is a limitation."
"I am perfectly willing to adopt the first amendment suggested
[the present § 8c(5)(G)], because that simply treats all areas
alike, for you could not prohibit someone from an outside area
coming in so long as he complied with the conditions prescribed for
that area;
but if you said that no restrictions or limitations
could be required, it would wreck the program, it would destroy
every vestige of a program we have for milk. [
Footnote 2/14]"
After the Senate amendment had been rejected by the Conference,
and while the Conference Report was being considered in the House
of Representatives, a discussion took place on the floor between
Representative Hope, a member of the House Committee on Agriculture
and one of the conferees, and the Chairman of the Committee, who
was also a conferee. This discussion shows the same understanding
that the Secretary was to be left free to
Page 370 U. S. 108
impose whatever limitations were necessary to protect the
regional prices he was authorized to fix:
"Mr. JONES. But the original amendments did not permit any
orders governing the price to the producers?"
"Mr. HOPE. No; but otherwise, the Secretary could make orders
which would regulate the bringing in of milk from the outside into
any particular milkshed, but under the amendments we are now
considering, the Secretary's power is limited. He cannot prohibit
milk from coming in?"
"Mr. JONES. That is correct."
"Mr. HOPE.
But he can prescribe some limitations?"
"Mr. JONES.
Yes; and he cannot prohibit the products of milk
being brought into any area."
"Mr. HOPE.
No; but he can prescribe limitations on the
importation of fluid milk."
"Mr. SNELL.
Then, as far as fluid milk is concerned, it is
protected in certain markets, but, as far as the other
products are concerned, they are not protected."
"Mr. JONES. That is correct. [
Footnote 2/15]"
These were the last comments made on the floor of the House
concerning milk before the Conference Report was finally
adopted.
In the light of this legislative history and the Act's language
itself, I cannot possibly read § 8c(5)(G) or any other part of
the Act to insure profitable operations to outside handlers who
desire to dump surplus milk into a regional price-fixing area or to
say that the Secretary lacks the power to protect by appropriate
regulations the integrity of the regional prices which Congress
authorized him to fix. I simply cannot believe that Congress
intended to
Page 370 U. S. 109
take away with one hand the high fixed price for milk which it
gave with the other.
The net result of the Court's action is to leave the farmers in
the New York-Northern New Jersey pool, and those in 22 other pools
containing the provisions which the Court strikes down today,
[
Footnote 2/16] completely
defenseless against an onslaught of outside milk that is highly
discriminatory because the outside milk bears none of the burdens
of pool milk. I say completely defenseless despite the fact that
the Court intimates that the Secretary might possibly devise some
alternative compensatory payment plan that would satisfy the
exacting standards which it lays down today. My first reason for
saying this is that I do not see how any formula that the Secretary
could devise under the Court's expanded interpretation of the word
"prohibit" in § 8c(5)(G) would protect pool members from
unfair competition by outside handlers who are, by the Court's
decision, given the advantages, but not required to bear the
burdens of the pool. [
Footnote
2/17]
Page 370 U. S. 110
Secondly, even if such a formula were possible, I doubt that a
single member of this Court has the technical knowledge about the
complicated workings of the milk industry to formulate a sound
substitute for the compensatory payment plan which the Court
strikes down -- a regulatory plan which represents more than a
quarter century of daily practical experience in administering the
congressional farm plan. Thirdly, in any event, the Court's vague
intimations that some compensatory payment plan might be valid are
hardly sufficient to furnish the Secretary with any guidance at all
as to what formula, if any, the Court would permit him to use to
protect the farmers in this pool from the effects of being
compelled to compete with outside "free riders."
I think that, if the Court really does believe that the
Secretary has any power at all to prevent pool farmers from being
subjected to discriminatory competition from outside "free riders,"
it should state in clear and precise
Page 370 U. S. 111
terms what those powers are and inform the Secretary how he can
meet this Court's requirements. The Court should than remand this
case to allow the Secretary to take the action which it will
approve, permit him to determine the amount that he could properly
under its standards have required these handlers to pay, and direct
that the District Court pay over that amount to the Secretary out
of the funds now in its possession. This plan would at least offer
the farmers in this pool some protection against having to pay out
all of the more than $700,000 in compensatory payments which has
already been collected from these handlers. Such a plan was
followed in
United States v. Morgan, [
Footnote 2/18] and there is every reason in equity
and good conscience why it should be followed here. In that case,
the District Court enjoined an order of the Secretary, but required
the party challenging the order to pay into court sufficient funds
to effect compliance with the order if it should ultimately be
found valid. This Court found the order defective, but nevertheless
ordered the District Court not to return the fund, which then
contained over a half million dollars. On the contrary, over strong
dissents urging that the Secretary only had power to issue a new
order for the future, this Court commanded that the fund be
retained until the Secretary could make new findings and enter a
new order so that the fund could be disposed of under a proper
determination of the Secretary, stating that:
"Due regard for the discharge of the court's own responsibility
to the litigants and to the public and the appropriate exercise of
its discretion in such manner as to effectuate the policy of the
Act and facilitate administration of the system which it has set up
require retention of the fund by the district court
Page 370 U. S. 112
until such time as the Secretary, proceeding with due
expedition, shall have entered a final order in the proceedings
pending before him. [
Footnote
2/19]"
Following this decision, the Secretary held new hearings, made
new findings, and entered a new order, according to which this
Court in a later
United States v. Morgan [
Footnote 2/20] ordered the more than one-half
million dollar fund distributed.
Despite the fact that the Court purports not to pass either on
the validity of requiring all handlers to bear the full burdens of
pool membership or upon the ability of the Secretary to apply
against these handlers any future scheme of regulation which meets
the Court's standards for the period here in question, [
Footnote 2/21] it seems clear that, in
failing to follow the
Morgan procedure, the Court, in
effect, rules against the Secretary on both these questions. This
is because the Court's refusal to pass specifically on these
questions leaves standing the District Court's holding that the
Secretary cannot require these handlers to bear the full burdens of
pool membership for the period during which the compensatory
payments struck down here were made. The regulation under which the
Secretary claims that these handlers are subject to the full
burdens of pool membership is a part of the same section [
Footnote 2/22] as the one under which the
handlers made the compensatory payments of which they complain.
Page 370 U. S. 113
That section provides that all handlers like petitioners are
pool handlers, and required to bear all the burdens of pool
membership unless they elect to be nonpool handlers and make
compensatory payments. The Secretary's contention is that, once the
part of the regulation which provides for the compensatory payment
is struck down, as the Court does here, the remainder of the
regulation which requires all handlers to be pool handlers applies.
By remanding this case to the District Court, which has already
ruled adversely on this claim, the Court, without so much as saying
a single word on this point, effectively prevents the Secretary
from trying to protect pool farmers from free-riding outside milk
by treating these handlers as pool members for the period here in
dispute.
The full effect of the Court's failure to follow the
Morgan procedure and decide whether the Secretary's
provisions for full regulation of these handlers are valid, or just
what the Secretary could do to protect the prices he has fixed, is,
in my opinion, likely to be a wholly unjust and inequitable
windfall of over $700,000 to the handlers, since it will ultimately
have to come out of the pockets of the farmers, who bear the
burdens of this pool. How many more such windfalls to other
handlers involving how many countless thousands of dollars in this
and the other 22 similarly situated pools the Court's action will
bring one can only guess. [
Footnote
2/23] One familiar with the Act and its history need not guess,
however, about the fact that such a result would have been
abhorrent to the Congress which passed this Act for the benefit of
farmers. I would affirm the decision of the court below which
upheld the Secretary.
[
Footnote 2/1]
297 U. S. 297 U.S.
1.
[
Footnote 2/2]
50 Stat. 246, 7 U.S.C. § 601
et seq.
[
Footnote 2/3]
49 Stat. 750.
[
Footnote 2/4]
48 Stat. 31.
[
Footnote 2/5]
See Nebbia v. New York, 291 U.
S. 502,
291 U. S.
515-518,
291 U. S. 530;
United States v. Rock Royal Co-operative, Inc.,
307 U. S. 533,
307 U. S.
548-550.
[
Footnote 2/6]
50 Stat. 246, as amended, 7 U.S.C. § 608c.
[
Footnote 2/7]
49 Stat. 750.
[
Footnote 2/8]
50 Stat. 247, 7 U.S.C. § 608c(18).
[
Footnote 2/9]
49 Stat. 757, 7 U.S.C. § 608c(7)(D).
[
Footnote 2/10]
Congress specifically provided in § 8c(11)(C) of the Act
that the Secretary's price-fixing powers were to be exercised on a
regional basis, rather than a national basis, whenever
practicable:
"All orders issued under this section which are applicable to
the same commodity or product thereof shall, so far as practicable,
prescribe such different terms, applicable to different production
areas and marketing areas, as the Secretary finds necessary to give
due recognition to the differences in production and marketing of
such commodity or product in such areas."
49 Stat. 759, 7 U.S.C. § 608c(11)(C).
See also
§ 8c(11)(A). 49 Stat. 759, 7 U.S.C. § 608c(11)(A).
[
Footnote 2/11]
49 Stat. 755, 7 U.S.C. § 608c(5)(G). (Emphasis
supplied.)
[
Footnote 2/12]
See Bailey Farm Dairy Co. v. Anderson, 157 F.2d 87, 96;
Kass v. Brannan, 196 F.2d 791, 800 (L. Hand, J.,
dissenting).
[
Footnote 2/13]
The amendment adopted by the Senate, but rejected by the
Conference, is indicated in italics:
"No marketing agreement or order applicable to milk and its
products in any marketing area shall prohibit
or in any manner
limit, except as provided for milk only in subsection (d), the
marketing in that area of any milk or product thereof produced in
any production area in the United States."
79 Cong.Rec. 11655. The wording of this amendment shows that the
Court's attempted explanation of why "in any manner limit" was
omitted from the final language of § 8c(5)(G) does not bear
analysis. The Court's explanation is that someone might construe
"limit" as prohibiting "the type of price-fixing (limitation)
covered by subsection (D)." But it seems very clear that the
wording of the Senate amendment was expressly designed to prevent
such a construction, while at the same time making "in any manner
limit" applicable to milk. Consequently, it seems apparent that, in
rejecting the Senate amendment, the Conference was not refusing to
apply "in any manner limit" to milk because to do so would
interfere with the operation of subsection (D), but was, in fact,
omitting that language because, to be effective, price-fixing
itself necessarily required limitations on the selling of outside
milk within the area. This is clearly shown by the Conference
Report, H.R.Rep. No. 1757, 74th Cong., 1st Sess. 21:
"The Senate amendment extended this provision (§ 8c(5)(G))
so that no marketing agreement or order so applicable could limit
in any manner the marketing in the marketing area of milk or its
products produced anywhere except that certain limitations on the
marketing of milk were specifically permitted. . . . The conference
agreement also denied the authority to limit in any manner the
marketing in any area of milk product . . . [but] does not refer to
milk, and
so does not negative the applicability to milk,
for use in fluid form or for manufacturing purposes, of the
provisions of the bill relating to milk such as
the provisions
on price-fixing, price adjustment, payments for milk,
etc."
(Emphasis supplied.)
[
Footnote 2/14]
79 Cong.Rec. 9572. (Emphasis supplied.)
[
Footnote 2/15]
79 Cong.Rec. 13022. (Emphasis supplied.)
[
Footnote 2/16]
See note 9 of the
Court's opinion At least 18 other pools apply a compensatory
payment provision like the one in this case for at least part of
the year.
See note 13
of the Court's opinion
[
Footnote 2/17]
Certainly neither of the formulas which the Court in its
note 13 intimates might be
proper would protect the farmers in the pool for neither of
these formulas even goes so far as to wipe out the discriminatory
advantage that unregulated outside milk has over pool milk. In
sustaining the Secretary's regulation in this case, the Judicial
Officer relied in part on the following reasons:
"[T]he marketwide pool existing under Order No. 27, as amended,
carries the longtime and seasonal reserves of milk for numerous
secondary markets in Pennsylvania and the Northeastern States. The
New York-New Jersey market carries the surplus burden for outside
handlers who distribute some milk in the marketing area. These
handlers usually have a relatively high percentage of their milk in
fluid milk utilization, and this utilization is considerably higher
than the average for the market regulated by Order No. 27. This
higher utilization, of course, results in a competitive advantage
in milk procurement to the outside handler as against the regulated
handler, and outside and regulated handlers draw on the same
production area for supplies. Furthermore, the regulated handler
has to equalize his utilization with other handlers, and his
producers are paid on the basis of a uniform price reflecting the
utilization in the market as a whole, rather than his individual
utilization."
Thus, a compensatory payment such as the Court suggests, based
on the difference between the fluid price and the blend price,
obviously would do nothing at all to wipe out the advantage that
the outside handler has because of his higher fluid-surplus ratio,
which is due, as shown above, to (1) the fact that the pool carries
part of his area's surplus and (2) the fact that he does not have
to equalize his own utilization as do pool handlers. Only a
compensatory payment which gives the outside handler less for his
surplus milk than the pool farmer gets will narrow the competitive
advantage which outside milk has. A compensatory payment based on
the difference between the fluid price and actual cost, the other
alternative suggested by the Court, would obviously be even more
subject to this same defect than the fluid-blend price compensatory
payment.
See also Hutt, Restrictions on the Free Movement
of Fluid Milk Under Federal Milk Marketing Orders, 37 U.Det.L.J.
525, 573-576, particularly at note 220.
[
Footnote 2/18]
307 U. S. 307 U.S.
183.
Cf. Inland Steel Co. v. United States, 306 U.
S. 153.
[
Footnote 2/19]
307 U.S. at
307 U. S.
198.
[
Footnote 2/20]
313 U. S. 313 U.S.
409.
[
Footnote 2/21]
The Court's citation of
Morgan v. United States,
304 U. S. 1,
304 U. S. 23, as
purported justification for its avoidance of this issue, is
particularly appropriate, and I fear prophetic. For, in large part
due to this Court's avoidance of a similar issue in the
Morgan case, that case wandered through the courts for
almost eight years, including four trips to this Court.
[
Footnote 2/22]
7 CFR § 1002.29(d).
[
Footnote 2/23]
A suit involving the provision of the Cleveland order similar to
the one struck down here has already found its way into court.
See Lawson Milk Co. v. Benson, 187 F. Supp.
66, appeal pending.