The Federal Trade Commission found that respondent, a leading
national brewer which sells a so-called premium beer at higher
prices than the beers of regional and local breweries in the great
majority of markets, had reduced its prices only to those customers
in the St. Louis area, while maintaining higher prices to all
purchasers outside the St. Louis area, and thereby had
"discriminated in price" as between purchasers differently located,
and that this had diverted substantial business from respondent's
St. Louis competitors, had substantially lessened competition and
tended to create a monopoly, in violation of § 2(a) of the
Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, and it ordered
respondent to cease and desist. The Court of Appeals concluded that
the statutory element of price discrimination had not been
established, and it set aside the Commission's order on this ground
alone.
Held: the Court of Appeals erred in its construction of
§ 2(a); the evidence warranted the Commission's finding of
price discrimination, and the judgment is reversed and the case is
remanded for further proceedings. Pp.
363 U. S.
537-554.
(a) Section 2(a) is violated when there is a price
discrimination which deals the requisite injury to sellers' or
"primary line" competition, even though buyers' or "secondary line"
and "tertiary line" competition are unaffected. Pp.
363 U. S.
542-545.
(b) The Court of Appeals erred in concluding that, since all
competing purchasers paid respondent the same price, so far as the
record disclosed, respondent's price cuts were not discriminatory.
Pp.
363 U. S.
545-546.
(c) A price discrimination within the meaning of the portion of
§ 2(a) here involved is merely a price difference; and, in
order to establish such a price discrimination, it is not necessary
to show that the lower price is below cost or unreasonably low for
the purpose or design to eliminate competition, and thereby obtain
a monopoly. Pp.
363 U. S.
546-553.
265 F.2d 677 reversed.
Page 363 U. S. 537
MR. CHIEF JUSTICE WARREN delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question presented is whether certain pricing activities of
respondent, Anheuser-Busch, Inc., constituted price discrimination
within the meaning of § 2(a) of the Clayton Act, 38 Stat. 730,
as amended by the Robinson-Patman Act, 49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C.
§ 13(a).
Section 2(a) provides in pertinent part:
"That it shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce,
in the course of such commerce, either directly or indirectly, to
discriminate in price between different purchasers of commodities
of like grade and quality, where either or any of the purchases
involved in such discrimination are in commerce, where such
commodities are sold for use, consumption, or resale within the
United States or any Territory thereof or the District of Columbia
or any insular possession or other place under the jurisdiction of
the United States, and where the effect of such discrimination may
be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly
in any line of commerce, or to injure, destroy, or prevent
competition with any person who either grants or knowingly receives
the benefit of such discrimination, or with customers of either of
them. . . . "
Page 363 U. S. 538
This controversy had its genesis in a complaint issued by the
Federal Trade Commission in 1955 which charged respondent, a beer
producer, with a violation of § 2(a). The complaint alleged
that respondent had
"discriminated in price between different purchasers of its beer
of like grade and quality by selling it to some of its customers at
higher prices than to other[s];"
that, more specifically, respondent had lowered prices in the
St. Louis, Missouri, market, without making similar price
reductions in other markets; that this discrimination had already
diverted substantial business from respondent's St. Louis
competitors; that it was "sufficient" to have the same impact in
the future; that there was a "reasonable probability" it would
substantially lessen competition in respondent's line of commerce;
and that it might also tend to create a monopoly or to injure,
destroy, or prevent competition with respondent. Thus, the
complaint described a pricing pattern which had adverse effects
only upon sellers' competition, commonly termed primary line
competition, and not upon buyers' competition, commonly termed
secondary line competition.
Both the hearing examiner and, on appeal, the Commission held
that the evidence introduced at the hearing established a violation
of § 2(a). The Commission found the facts to be as
follows:
Respondent, a leading national brewer, [
Footnote 1] sells a so-called premium beer, which is
priced higher than the beers of regional and local breweries in the
great majority of markets, although both the price of respondent's
beer and the premium differential vary from market to market and
from time to time. During the period relevant to this case,
respondent had three principal competitors in the St. Louis area,
all regional breweries: Falstaff Brewing
Page 363 U. S. 539
Corporation, Griesedieck Western Brewing Company, and
Griesedieck Brothers Brewery Company. [
Footnote 2] In accord with the generally prevailing price
structure, these breweries normally sold their products at a price
substantially lower than respondent's.
In 1953, most of the national breweries, including respondent,
granted their employees a wage increase, and, on October 1,1953,
they put into effect a general price increase. [
Footnote 3] Although many regional and local
breweries throughout the country followed suit by raising their
prices, Falstaff, Griesedieck Western, and Griesedieck Brothers
maintained their pre-October price of $2.35 per standard case.
Although respondent's sales in the St. Louis area did not decline,
its national sales fell, along with industry sales in general.
On January 4, 1954, respondent lowered its price in the St.
Louis market from $2.93 to $2.68 per case, thereby reducing the
previous 58$ differential to 33$. A second price cut occurred on
June 21, 1954, this time to $2.35, the same price charged by
respondent's three competitors. On January 3, 1954, the day before
the first price cut, respondent's price in the St. Louis market had
been lower
Page 363 U. S. 540
than its price in other markets, [
Footnote 4] and, during the period of the price reductions
in the St. Louis area, respondent made no similar price reductions
in any other market. In March, 1955, respondent increased its St.
Louis price 45� per case, and Falstaff, Griesedieck Western,
and Griesedieck Brothers almost immediately raised their prices
15�, which reestablished a substantial differential. This
ended the period of alleged price discrimination.
The Commission concluded:
"As a result of maintaining higher prices to all purchasers
outside of the St. Louis area and charging the lower prices, as
reduced in 1954, to only those customers in the St. Louis area,
respondent discriminated in price as between purchasers differently
located."
Since, as will appear, it is this aspect of the decision which
concerns us, it is necessary only to sketch summarily the remaining
elements in the Commission's decision. The Commission's finding of
competitive injury was predicated to a substantial degree upon what
it regarded as a demonstrated diversion of business to respondent
from its St. Louis competitors during the period of price
discrimination. For example, by comparing that period with a
similar period during the previous year, the Commission determined
that respondent's sales had risen 201.5%, Falstaff's sales and
dropped
Page 363 U. S. 541
slightly, Griesedieck Western's sales had fallen about 33%, and
Griesedieck Brothers' sales had plummeted about 41%. In tabular
form, the relative market positions of the St. Louis sellers were
as follows:
Dec. 31 June 30 Mar. 1 July 31
1953 1954 1955 1955
Respondent . . . 12.5 16.55 39.3 21.03
Griesedieck
Brothers . . . 14.4 12.58 4.8 7.36
Falstaff . . . . 29.4 32.05 29.1 36.62
Griesedieck
Western . . . . 38.9 33. 23.1 27.78
All others . . . 4.8 5.82 3.94 7.21
The Commission rejected respondent's contention that its price
reductions had been made in good faith to meet the equally low
price of a competitor within the meaning of the proviso to §
2(b) of the Act, 49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. § 13(b), and also
found respondent's attack upon the examiner's cease and desist
order to be meritless. The Commission thereupon adopted and issued
that order, with only slight modification. [
Footnote 5]
On review, the Court of Appeals set aside the order. 265 F.2d
677. We granted certiorari 361 U.S. 880, because a conflict had
developed among the Courts of Appeals on a question of importance
in the administration of the statute.
See Atlas Building
Products Co. v. Diamond Block & Gravel Co., 269 F.2d 950
(C.A. 10th Cir.).
Page 363 U. S. 542
The limited nature of our inquiry can be fully appreciated only
in the light of the correspondingly narrow decision of the Court of
Appeals, which rested entirely upon the holding that the threshold
statutory element of price discrimination had not been established.
Thus, the Court of Appeals did not consider whether the record
supported a finding of the requisite competitive injury, whether
respondent's good faith defense was valid, or whether the
Commission's order was unduly broad. We have concluded that the
Court of Appeals erred in its construction of § 2(a), and that
the evidence fully warranted the Commission's finding of price
discrimination. Respondent would have us affirm nonetheless on any
of the alternative grounds it strongly urged below. While this is,
to be sure, an appropriate course of action under proper
circumstances, we believe that it would be unwise for us to grapple
with these intricate problems, the solution to which requires a
careful examination of a voluminous record, before they have been
dealt with by the Court of Appeals. Therefore, the case will be
remanded, and of course nothing in this opinion should be
interpreted as intimating a view upon the remaining aspects of the
controversy.
A discussion of the import of the § 2(a) phrase
"discriminate in price," in the context of this case, must begin
with a consideration of the purpose of the statute with respect to
primary line competition. The Court of Appeals expressed some doubt
that § 2(a) was designed to protect this competition at all,
but respondent has not undertaken to defend that position here.
This is entirely understandable. While "precision of expression is
not an outstanding characteristic of the Robinson-Patman Act,"
Automatic Canteen Co. v. Federal Trade Comm'n,
346 U. S. 61,
346 U. S. 65, it
is certain at least that § 2(a) is violated where there is a
price discrimination which deals the requisite injury to primary
line competition, even
Page 363 U. S. 543
though secondary line and tertiary line competition are
unaffected. The statute could hardly be read any other way, for it
forbids price discriminations
"where the effect . . . may be substantially to lessen
competition or tend to create a monopoly
in any line of
commerce, or to injure, destroy, or prevent competition with
any person
who either grants or knowingly receives the
benefit of such discrimination, or with customers of either of
them."
(Emphasis added.)
The legislative history of § 2(a) is equally plain. The
section, when originally enacted as part of the Clayton Act in
1914, was born of a desire by Congress to curb the use by
financially powerful corporations of localized price-cutting
tactics which had gravely impaired the competitive position of
other sellers. [
Footnote 6] It
is, of course, quite true -- and too well known to require
extensive exposition -- that the 1936 Robinson-Patman amendments to
the Clayton Act were motivated principally by congressional
Page 363 U. S. 544
concern over the impact upon secondary line competition of the
burgeoning of mammoth purchasers, notably chain stores. [
Footnote 7] However, the legislative
history of these amendments leaves no doubt that Congress was
intent upon strengthening the Clayton Act provisions, not weakening
them, and that it was no part of Congress' purpose to curtail the
preexisting applicability of § 2(a) to price discriminations
affecting primary line competition. [
Footnote 8]
The federal courts, both before and after the amendment of
§ 2(a), have taken this view of the scope of the statute in
cases involving impairment of primary line competition.
See
Porto Rican American Tobacco Co. v. American Tobacco Co., 30
F.2d 234 (C.A. 2d Cir. 1929);
E. B. Muller & Co. v. Federal
Trade Comm'n, 142 F.2d 511 (C.A. 6th Cir. 1944);
Maryland
Baking Co. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 243 F.2d 716 (C.A. 4th
Cir. 1957);
Atlas Building Products Co. v. Diamond Block &
Gravel Co., supra (1959). In fact, the original focus of
§ 2(a) on sellers' competition was so evident that this Court
was compelled to hold explicitly, contrary to lower court
decisions, [
Footnote 9] that
the statute was not restricted to price discriminations impeding
primary line competition, but protected secondary line competition
as well.
Van Camp
&
Page 363 U. S. 545
sons v. American Can Co., 278 U.
S. 245 (1929). And, more recently, in
Moore v.
Mead's Fine Bread Co., 348 U. S. 115
(1954), the Court sustained a treble damage judgment in favor of a
competing seller which was based partly upon a violation of §
2(a).
Thus, neither the language of § 2(a), its legislative
history, nor its judicial application countenances a construction
of the statute which draws strength from even a lingering doubt as
to its purpose of protecting primary line competition. But the
rationale of the Court of Appeals appears to have been shaped by
precisely this type of doubt. The view of the Court of Appeals was
that, before, there can be a price discrimination within the
meaning of § 2(a), "[t]here must be some relationship between
the different purchasers which entitles them to comparable
treatment." 265 F.2d at 681. Such a relationship would exist, the
court reasoned, if different prices were being charged to competing
purchasers. But the court observed that, in this case, all
competing purchasers paid respondent the same price, so far as the
record disclosed. Consequently, the court concluded that, even
assuming the price cuts "were directed at [Anheuser-Busch's] local
competitors, they were not discriminatory." [
Footnote 10]
Ibid.
This qualification upon the applicability of § 2(a) to
primary line-competition cases is in no way adumbrated by the
prevailing line of relevant decisions. In
Mead's Fine Bread
Co., supra, in
Maryland Baking Co., supra, and in
Porto Rican American Tobacco Co., supra, violations of
§ 2(a) were predicated upon injury to primary line competition
without reliance upon the presence or
Page 363 U. S. 546
absence of competition among purchasers as a relevant factor.
And in
E. B. Muller & Co., supra, while there was
evidence that the purchasers in question were competing, the court
explicitly rejected the notion that this was a necessary element of
a violation in a primary line case. 142 F.2d at 518.
But cf.
Balian Ice Cream Co. v. Arden Farms Co., 231 F.2d 356.
More important, however, is the incompatibility of the Circuit
Court's rule with the purpose of § 2(a). The existence of
competition among buyers who are charged different prices by a
seller is obviously important in terms of adverse effect upon
secondary line competition, but it would be merely a fortuitous
circumstance so far as injury to primary line competition is
concerned. Since, as we have indicated, an independent and
important goal of § 2(a) is to extend protection to
competitors of the discriminating seller, the limitation of that
protection by the alien factor of competition among purchasers
would constitute a debilitating graft upon the statute.
Although respondent's starting point is the same as that of the
Court of Appeals -- that a price discrimination is not synonymous
with a price difference -- its test of price discrimination is
somewhat broader. [
Footnote
11] Respondent concedes that a competitive relationship among
purchasers is not a prerequisite of price discrimination, but
maintains that at least there must be
"proof that the lower price is below cost or unreasonably low
for the purpose or design to eliminate competition, and thereby
obtain a monopoly."
Since such a finding is lacking here, respondent argues that it
cannot be said that there was price discrimination.
Page 363 U. S. 547
Respondent asserts that its view is supported by legislative
history, court decisions, and reason. Respondent relies heavily, as
did the Court of Appeals, upon a statement made during Congress'
consideration of the Robinson-Patman legislation by Representative
Utterback, a manager of the conference bill which became §
2(a). In this rather widely quoted exegesis of the section,
Representative Utterback declared that "a discrimination is more
than a mere difference," and exists only when there is "some
relationship . . . between the parties to the discrimination which
entitles them to equal treatment." Such a relationship would
prevail among competing purchasers, according to the Congressman,
and also "where . . . the price to one is so low as to involve a
sacrifice of some part of the seller's necessary costs and profit,"
so that "it leaves that deficit inevitably to be made up in higher
prices to his other customers." 80 Cong.Rec. 9416. [
Footnote 12] Respondent also cites
expressions in the legislative history of the Clayton Act which
reflect Congress' concern over classic examples of predatory
business practices.
See H.R.Rep. No. 627, 63d Cong.,
2d
Page 363 U. S. 548
Sess. 8; S.Rep. No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 2-4. Moreover,
respondent maintains that the principle it advances has found
expression in the decisions of the federal courts in primary line
competition cases, which consistently emphasize the unreasonably
low prices and the predatory intent of the defendants. [
Footnote 13] Respondent also urges
that its view is grounded upon the statutory scheme of § 2(a),
which penalizes sellers only if an anticompetitive effect stems
from a discriminatory pricing pattern, not if it results merely
from a low price. Thus, the argument goes, unless there is proof
that high prices in one area have subsidized low prices in another,
the price differential does not fall within the compass of the
section. In such a case, it is contended, § 3 of the
Robinson-Patman Act, 49 Stat. 1528, 15 U.S.C. § 13a, may be
applicable, but not § 2(a). [
Footnote 14] Finally, respondent argues that, unless its
position is accepted, the law will impose rigid price uniformity
upon the business world, contrary to sound economics and the policy
of the antitrust laws.
Page 363 U. S. 549
The trouble with respondent's arguments is not that they are
necessarily irrelevant in a § 2(a) proceeding, but that they
are misdirected when the issue under consideration is solely
whether there has been a price discrimination. We are convinced
that, whatever may be said with respect to the rest of §§
2(a) and 2(b) -- and we say nothing here -- there are no overtones
of business buccaneering in the § 2(a) phrase "discriminate in
price." Rather, a price discrimination within the meaning of that
provision is merely a price difference.
When this Court has spoken of price discrimination in §
2(a) cases, it has generally assumed that the term was synonymous
with price differentiation. In
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Cement
Institute, 333 U. S. 683,
333 U. S. 721,
the Court referred to "discrimination in price" as "selling the
same kind of goods cheaper to one purchaser than to another." And
in
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S.
37,
334 U. S. 45,
the Court said,
"Congress meant by using the words 'discrimination in price' in
§ 2 that in a case involving competitive injury between a
seller's customers the Commission need only prove that a seller had
charged one purchaser a higher price for like goods than he had
charged one or more of the purchaser's competitors. [
Footnote 15]"
The commentators have generally shared this view. [
Footnote 16]
Page 363 U. S. 550
These assumptions, we now conclude, were firmly rooted in the
structure of the statute, for it is only by equating price
discrimination with price differentiation that § 2(a) can be
administered as Congress intended. As we read that provision, it
proscribes price differences, subject to certain defined defenses,
[
Footnote 17] where the
effect of the differences
"may be substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a
monopoly in any line of commerce, or to injure, destroy, or prevent
competition with any person who either grants or knowingly receives
the benefit"
of the price differential, "or with customers of either of
them."
See Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co.,
334 U. S. 37,
334 U. S. 45-47.
In other words, the statute itself spells out the conditions which
make a price difference illegal or legal, and we would derange this
integrated statutory scheme were we to read other conditions into
the law by means of the nondirective phrase, "discriminate in
price." Not only would such action be contrary to what we conceive
to the the meaning of the statute, but, perhaps because of this, it
would be thoroughly undesirable.
Page 363 U. S. 551
As one commentator has succinctly put it,
"Inevitably every legal controversy over any price difference
would shift from the detailed governing provisions -- 'injury,'
cost justification, 'meeting competition,' etc. -- over into the
'discrimination' concept for
ad hoc resolution divorced
from specifically pertinent statutory text."
Rowe, Price Differentials and Product Differentiation: The
Issues Under the Robinson-Patman Act, 66 Yale L.J. 1, 38. [
Footnote 18]
In the face of these considerations, we do not find respondent's
arguments persuasive. The fact that activity which falls within the
civil proscription of § 2(a) may also be criminal under §
3 is entirely irrelevant. The partial overlap between these
sections, which was to a significant extent the byproduct of the
tortuous path of the Robinson-Patman bills through Congress,
[
Footnote 19] has been
widely recognized.
"[T]his section [§ 3] does not restrict the operation of
the prohibitions, with civil sanctions, of the Robinson-Patman
amendments to § 2(a) of the Clayton Act."
Corn Products Refining Co. v. Federal Trade Comm'n,
324 U. S. 726,
324 U. S. 734.
[
Footnote 20]
Page 363 U. S. 552
The other materials adduced by respondent do no more than
indicate that the factors in question -- predatory intent and
unreasonably low local price cuts -- may possibly be relevant to
other matters which may be put in issue in a § 2(a)
proceeding. For example, it might be argued that the existence of
predatory intent bears upon the likelihood of injury to
competition, [
Footnote 21]
and that a price reduction below cost tends to establish such an
intent. [
Footnote 22]
Practically all of the legislative materials and court decisions
relied upon by respondent are explicable on this basis, since
hardly any of them are concerned specifically with the meaning of
price discrimination. [
Footnote
23] Moreover, many of the legislative expressions cited by
respondent may merely be descriptive of the prototype of the
evil
Page 363 U. S. 553
with which Congress dealt in § 2(a), rather than
delineative of the outer reach of that section. A possible
exception is the statement of Representative Utterback. But the
primary function of statutory construction is to effectuate the
intent of Congress, and that function cannot properly be discharged
by reliance upon a statement of a single Congressman in the face of
the weighty countervailing considerations which are present in this
case. [
Footnote 24]
Nothing that we have said, of course, should be construed to be
the expression of any view concerning the relevance of the factors
stressed by respondent to statutory standards other than price
discrimination. We wish merely to point out, on the one hand, why
respondent's arguments, in our view, are not pertinent to the issue
at bar, and, on the other, that we are not foreclosing respondent
from urging in the Court of Appeals that such arguments are
material to issues not now before us.
What we have said makes it quite evident, we believe, that our
decision does not raise the specter of a flat prohibition of price
differentials, inasmuch as price differences constitute but one
element of a § 2(a) violation. In fact, as we have indicated,
respondent has vigorously contested this very case on the entirely
separate grounds of insufficient injury to competition and good
faith lowering of price to meet competition. Nor is it relevant
that the Commission did not proceed upon the basis of the
respondent's price differentials which existed prior to the period
in question in this case. This choice is committed to the
Page 363 U. S. 554
discretion of the Commission; and it may well be that the
Commission did not believe the remaining statutory elements could
be established with respect to other differentials. Our interest is
solely with this case, and, at this stage of the litigation, that
interest is confined exclusively to identifying and keeping
distinct the various statutory standards which are part of the
§ 2(a) complex.
The judgment of the Court of Appeals is reversed and the case is
remanded to that court for further proceedings not inconsistent
with this opinion.
Reversed.
[
Footnote 1]
Anheuser-Busch ranked second nationally in gross sales in 1952
and 1955, and first in 1953 and 1954.
[
Footnote 2]
It appears that Griesedieck Western sold out to Carling Brewing
Company in October, 1954.
[
Footnote 3]
Respondent maintains -- and petitioner agrees -- that the
evidence establishes that it did not raise its price in Missouri or
Wisconsin. In view of our disposition of the case, this is
immaterial to the issue presented on this review.
Possibly we should note that most of the facts in this
particular paragraph are taken from the initial decision. Although
the Commission adopted "the findings, conclusions, and order, as
modified, contained in the initial decision," there is some
disagreement as to how encompassing this incorporation order was.
See note 10
infra. Since that dispute concerns matters not relevant to
our decision, and since the facts set forth above are merely
background, and appear to be unquestioned, we find it unnecessary
to resolve the disagreement.
[
Footnote 4]
The following table discloses the degree of this price
spread:
St. Louis, Mo. . . . $2.93 Washington, D.C. . . . . $3.65
Chicago, Ill. . . . 3.44 Detroit, Mich. . . . . . 3.55
Cincinnati, Ohio . . 3.75 Boston, Mass. . . . . . 3.69
Houston, Tex. . . . 3.70 Kansas City, Mo. . . . . 3.15
Bronx, N.Y. . . . . 3.68 St. Paul, Minn. . . . . 3.53
Kearney, Nebr. . . . 3.68 Sioux Falls, S. Dak. . . 3.50
St. Joseph, Mo. . . 3.17 Denver, Colo. . . . . . ____
Buffalo, N.Y. . . . 3.60 San Francisco, Calif. . 3.79
Baltimore, Md. . . . 3.62 Los Angeles, Calif. . . 3.80
[
Footnote 5]
"It Is Ordered that the respondent, Anheuser-Busch, Inc., a
corporation, and its officers, representatives, agents and
employees, directly or through any corporate or other device, in
the sale of beer of like grade and quality, do forthwith cease and
desist from discriminating, directly or indirectly, in price,
between different purchasers engaged in the same line of commerce,
where either, or any, of the purchases involved in such
discrimination are in commerce, as 'commerce' is defined in the
Clayton Act, by a price reduction in any market where respondent is
in competition with any other seller, unless it proportionally
reduces its prices everywhere for the same quantity of beer."
[
Footnote 6]
"Section 2 of the bill . . . is expressly designed with the view
of correcting and forbidding a common and widespread unfair trade
practice whereby certain great corporations and also certain
smaller concerns which seek to secure a monopoly in trade and
commerce by aping the methods of the great corporations, have
heretofore endeavored to destroy competition and render
unprofitable the business of competitors by selling their goods,
wares, and merchandise at a less price in the particular
communities where their rivals are engaged in business than at
other places throughout the country. . . . In the past it, has been
a most common practice of great and powerful combinations engaged
in commerce -- notably the Standard Oil Co., and the American
Tobacco Co., and others of less notoriety, but of great influence
-- to lower prices of their commodities, oftentimes below the cost
of production in certain communities and sections where they had
competition, with the intent to destroy and make unprofitable the
business of their competitors, and with the ultimate purpose in
view of thereby acquiring a monopoly in the particular locality or
section in which the discriminating price is made. . . ."
H.R.Rep. No. 627, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 8.
See also
S.Rep. No. 698, 63d Cong., 2d Sess. 2-4.
[
Footnote 7]
See H.R.Rep. No. 2287, 74th Cong., 2d Sess.; S.Rep. No.
1502, 74th Cong., 2d Sess.; F.T.C., Final Report on the Chain-Store
Investigation, S.Doc. No. 4, 74th Cong., 1st Sess.;
Federal
Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S.
37,
334 U. S. 43;
Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to Study the
Antitrust Laws, 155-156; Austin, Price Discrimination and Related
Problems under the Robinson-Patman Act (2d rev. ed., 1959), 8-11;
Palamountain, The Politics of Distribution, 188-234; Rowe, The
Evolution of the Robinson-Patman Act: A Twenty-Year Perspective, 57
Col.L.Rev. 1059.
[
Footnote 8]
See sources cited in
note 7 supra.
[
Footnote 9]
See Mennen Co. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 288 F. 774
(C.A. 2d Cir.);
National Biscuit Co. v. Federal Trade
Comm'n, 299 F. 733 (C.A. 2d Cir.).
[
Footnote 10]
There is a dispute as to whether the Commission adopted a
finding by the examiner which related to the purpose of the price
reductions. Since we conclude that the issue of predatory intent is
irrelevant to the question before us, it is unnecessary for us to
resolve this dispute.
[
Footnote 11]
Respondent maintains that the opinion of the Court of Appeals
may and should be read to encompass respondent's views. It is true
that there are certain passages in the opinion which lend some
support to respondent's interpretation. In view of our disposition
of the case, it is unnecessary for us either to accept or reject
that construction.
[
Footnote 12]
The statement in full is as follows:
"In its meaning as simple English, a discrimination is more than
a mere difference. Underlying the meaning of the word is the idea
that some relationship exists between the parties to the
discrimination which entitles them to equal treatment, whereby the
difference granted to one casts some burden or disadvantage upon
the other. If the two are competing in the resale of the goods
concerned, that relationship exists. Where, also, the price to one
is so low as to involve a sacrifice of some part of the seller's
necessary costs and profit as applied to that business, it leaves
that deficit inevitably to be made up in higher prices to his other
customers; and there, too, a relationship may exist upon which to
base the charge of discrimination. But where no such relationship
exists, where the goods are sold in different markets and the
conditions affecting those markets set different price levels for
them, the sale to different customers at those different prices
would not constitute a discrimination within the meaning of this
bill."
[
Footnote 13]
See, e.g., Porto Rican American Tobacco Co. v. American
Tobacco Co., supra; Atlas Building Products Co. v. Diamond Block
& Gravel Co., supra; Maryland Baking Co. v. Federal Trade
Comm'n, supra.
[
Footnote 14]
Section 3 provides:
"It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the
course of such commerce, to be a party to, or assist in, any
transaction of sale, or contract to sell, which discriminates to
his knowledge against competitors of the purchaser, in that, any
discount, rebate, allowance, or advertising service charge is
granted to the purchaser over and above any discount, rebate,
allowance, or advertising service charge available at the time of
such transaction to said competitors in respect of a sale of goods
of like grade, quality, and quantity; to sell, or contract to sell,
goods in any part of the United States at prices lower than those
exacted by said person elsewhere in the United States for the
purpose of destroying competition, or eliminating a competitor in
such part of the United States; or, to sell, or contract to sell,
goods at unreasonably low prices for the purpose of destroying
competition or eliminating a competitor."
[
Footnote 15]
See also Federal Trade Comm'n v. A. E. Staley Mfg. Co.,
324 U. S. 746,
324 U. S. 757;
Samuel H. Moss, Inc. v. Federal Trade Comm'n, 148 F.2d
378, 379; 2 Cir., 155 F.2d 1016.
Compare Automatic Canteen Co.
of America v. Federal Trade Comm'n supra, at
346 U. S. 70,
note 10,
346 U. S.
71.
[
Footnote 16]
See Att'y Gen. Nat'l Comm'n Antitrust Rep. 156; Austin,
Price Discrimination and Related Problems Under the Robinson-Patman
Act (2d rev. ed. 1959), 18-20; McAllister, Price Control by Law in
the United States: A Survey, 4 Law and Contemp.Prob. 273, 291-293;
Rowe, Price Differentials and Product Differentiation: The Issues
Under the Robinson-Patman Act, 66 Yale L.J. 1, 36-38; Comment, 12
Stan.L.Rev. 460, 461.
But see Zorn and Feldman, Business
Under The New Price Laws, 75.
[
Footnote 17]
In addition to the statutory provisions regarding injury to
competition, set out at p.
363 U. S. 537,
supra, there are other relevant
portions of the statute, such as the seller's § 2(b) defense
of "showing that his lower price . . . was made in good faith to
meet an equally low price of a competitor. . . ." And a proviso to
§ 2(a) states:
"That nothing herein contained shall prevent differentials which
make only due allowance for differences in the cost of manufacture,
sale, or delivery resulting from the differing methods or
quantities in which such commodities are to such purchasers sold or
delivered. . . ."
And still another proviso to § 2(a) states:
"That nothing herein contained shall prevent price changes from
time to time where in response to changing conditions affecting the
market for or the marketability of the goods concerned, such as but
not limited to actual or imminent deterioration of perishable
goods, obsolescence of seasonal goods, distress sales under court
process, or sales in good faith in discontinuance of business in
the goods concerned."
[
Footnote 18]
See also Austin, Price Discrimination and Related
Problems Under the Robinson-Patman Act (2d rev. ed. 1959), 18-20;
McAllister, Price Control by Law in the United States: A Survey, 4
Law and Contemp.Prob. 273, 291-293.
[
Footnote 19]
See Palamountain, The Politics of Distribution,
188-234; Rowe, The Evolution of the Robinson-Patman Act: A
Twenty-Year Perspective, 57 Col.L.Rev. 1059.
[
Footnote 20]
"Subsection (h) of the Senate amendment . . . appears in the
conference report as section 3 of the bill itself. It contains the
operative and penal provisions of what was originally the Borah-Van
Nuys bill (S. 4171). While they overlap in some respects, they are
in no way inconsistent with the provisions of the Clayton Act
amendment provided for in section 1. Section 3 authorizes nothing
which that amendment prohibits, and takes nothing from it. On the
contrary, where only civil remedies and liabilities attach to
violations of the amendment provided in section 1, section 3 sets
up special prohibitions as to the particular offenses therein
described, and attaches to then also the criminal penalties therein
provided."
H.R.Rep. No. 2951, 74th Cong., 2d Sess. 8.
See also
Nashville Milk Co. v. Carnation Co., 355 U.
S. 373,
355 U. S. 378;
Austin, Price Discrimination and Related Problems Under the
Robinson-Patman Act (2d rev. ed. 1959), 3-4; 108 U. of Pa.L.Rev.
116, 121; 45 Va.L.Rev. 1397, 1400; sources cited in
note 19 supra.
[
Footnote 21]
Of course, we do not depart from our holding in
Federal
Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt, supra, 334 U.S. at pp.
334 U. S. 50-51,
as to adequacy of proof of tendency to injure competition in cases
involving discrimination between purchasers. The instant case, as
we have pointed out, involves differences in prices among competing
sellers.
[
Footnote 22]
See Balian Ice Cream Co. v. Arden Farms Co., supra, 231
F.2d at 369; Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to
Study The Antitrust Laws, 165; Rowe, Price Discrimination,
Competition, and Confusion: Another Look at Robinson-Patman, 60
Yale L.J. 929, 956; The "New" Federal Trade Commission and the
Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws, 65 Yale L.J. 34, 74-75; A
Symposium on the Robinson-Patman Act, 49 N.W.U.L.Rev. 197, 215,
224.
But cf. Nashville Milk Co. v. Carnation Co.,
355 U. S. 373,
355 U. S. 378;
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Ruberoid Co., 343 U.
S. 470,
343 U. S. 484
(dissenting opinion).
[
Footnote 23]
Perhaps it is worth noting in this connection that the Senate
and House committee reports appear to use the words
"discrimination" and "differential" interchangeably.
See
H.R.Rep. No. 2287, 74th Cong., 2d Sess. 10; S.Rep. No. 1502, 74th
Cong., 2d Sess. 5.
[
Footnote 24]
Representative Utterback's comment has been criticized as
"ambiguous and misleading and . . . too often accepted without
analysis." Austin, Price Discrimination and Related Problems Under
the Robinson-Patman Act (2d rev. ed. 1959), 18. It is, of course,
possible that the Congressman was so intent upon the immediate
problem -- protection of secondary line competition -- that he did
not reflect upon the significance of his statement when applied to
primary line cases.