A company which was engaged in the manufacture of roofing
materials was found by the Federal Trade Commission to have
discriminated among customers in the prices charged for its
products. The Commission held that the discriminations violated
§ 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended, and ordered the company
to cease and desist from selling
"products of like grade and quality to any purchaser at prices
lower than those granted other purchasers who in fact compete with
the favored purchaser in the resale or distribution of such
products."
Upon the company's petition for review, the Court of Appeals
affirmed, but refused an order of enforcement.
Held:
1. Congress has vested in the Federal Trade Commission the
primary responsibility for fashioning orders dealing with Clayton
Act violations, and the courts will not interfere except where the
remedy selected has no reasonable relation to the unlawful
practices found to exist. P. 473.
2. Although, in the company's price discriminations between
competing purchasers, the Commission found only differentials of 5%
or more, the order was not too broad in prohibiting all price
differentials between competing purchasers, in view of the
Commission's finding that even very small differences in price were
important factors in competition among the company's customers. Pp.
343 U. S.
473-474.
3. Although the price discriminations found were in sales to
retailers and applicators, not in sales to wholesalers, the
extension of the order to "purchasers who in fact compete" was not
unreasonable, in view of the evidence that the company's
classification of its customers -- as wholesalers, retailers, and
applicators -- did not follow real functional differences. Pp.
343 U. S.
474-475.
Page 343 U. S. 471
4. The order does not enjoin lawful acts by reason of the
Commission's failure to except from its prohibitions differentials
permitted by the terms of the Act (making allowance for differences
in cost of manufacture, sale or delivery, or made in good faith to
meet an equally low price of a competitor), since these exceptions
are necessarily implicit in every order issued under authority of
the Act. Pp.
343 U. S.
475-476.
(a) However, in contesting enforcement or contempt proceedings,
the seller may plead only those facts constituting statutory
justification which it has not previously had an opportunity to
present. Pp.
343 U. S.
476-477.
5. The Commission is not entitled to a decree directing
enforcement of an order issued under the Clayton Act in the absence
of a showing that a violation of the order has occurred or is
imminent. Pp.
343 U. S.
477-480.
(a) The provision of the Act authorizing the Commission to apply
for enforcement "if such person fails or neglects to obey such
order" prescribes a prerequisite to the court's granting
enforcement. Pp.
343 U. S.
478-479.
(b) Disobedience or threatened disobedience of the order is a
condition to the granting of enforcement, even where the order
comes before the court upon petition for review by the affected
party. Pp.
343 U. S.
479-480.
191 F.2d 294 affirmed.
Upon a petition for review of a cease and desist order of the
Federal Trade Commission, 46 F.T.C. 379, the Court of Appeals
affirmed and granted enforcement of the order. 189 F.2d 893. On
rehearing, it struck from its decision that part granting
enforcement. 191 F.2d 294. This Court granted certiorari. 342 U.S.
917.
Affirmed, p.
343 U. S. 480.
Page 343 U. S. 472
MR. JUSTICE CLARK delivered the opinion of the Court.
In this case, we granted cross-petitions for certiorari to
review the decree of the Court of Appeals affirming, but refusing
to enforce, a cease and desist order issued by the Federal Trade
Commission to the Ruberoid Co.
Ruberoid is one of the nation's largest manufacturers of asphalt
and asbestos roofing materials and allied products. The Commission
found that Ruberoid, in a number of specific instances, had
discriminated among customers in the prices charged them for
roofing materials. Further finding that the effect of those
discriminations
"may be substantially to lessen competition in the line of
commerce in which [those customers] are engaged, and to injure,
destroy, or prevent competition between [those customers],
[
Footnote 1]"
the Commission held that the discriminations were violations of
§ 2(a) of the Clayton Act, as amended by the Robinson-Patman
Act. [
Footnote 2] 46 F.T.C.
379. Ruberoid was ordered to:
"[C]ease and desist from discriminating in price: "
"By selling such products of like grade and quality to any
purchaser at prices lower than those granted other purchasers who
in fact, compete with the favored purchaser in the resale or
distribution of such products. [
Footnote 3]"
Upon Ruberoid's petition for review, the Court of Appeals
affirmed and granted enforcement of the order. 189 F.2d 893.
However, on rehearing, the Court of Appeals amended its mandate to
strike that part which directed enforcement. 191 F.2d 294. We
granted certiorari to review questions, important in the
administration of the Clayton Act, as to the scope and enforcement
of Federal Trade Commission orders. 342 U.S. 917.
Page 343 U. S. 473
We first consider the contentions of Ruberoid, which are mainly
attacks upon the breadth of the order. Orders of the Federal Trade
Commission are not intended to impose criminal punishment or exact
compensatory damages for past acts, but to prevent illegal
practices in the future. In carrying out this function, the
Commission is not limited to prohibiting the illegal practice in
the precise form in which it is found to have existed in the past.
If the Commission is to attain the objectives Congress envisioned,
it cannot be required to confine its roadblock to the narrow lane
the transgressor has traveled; it must be allowed effectively to
close all roads to the prohibited goal, so that its order may not
be bypassed with impunity. [
Footnote 4] Moreover, "[t]he Commission has wide
discretion in its choice of a remedy deemed adequate to cope with
the unlawful practices" disclosed.
Jacob Siegel Co. v. Federal
Trade Comm'n, 327 U. S. 608,
327 U. S. 611
(1946). Congress placed the primary responsibility for fashioning
such orders upon the Commission, and Congress expected the
Commission to exercise a special competence in formulating remedies
to deal with problems in the general sphere of competitive
practices. [
Footnote 5]
Therefore, we have said that
"the courts will not interfere except where the remedy selected
has no reasonable relation to the unlawful practices found to
exist."
Id. at
327 U. S.
613.
In the light of these principles, we examine the specific
objections of Ruberoid to the order in this case. First, it is
argued that the order went too far in prohibiting all price
differentials between competing purchasers, although only
differentials of 5% or more were found. But the Commission found
that very small differences in price
Page 343 U. S. 474
were material factors in competition among Ruberoid's customers,
and Ruberoid offered no evidence to the contrary. In this state of
the record, the Commission was not required to limit its
prohibition to the specific differential shown to have been adopted
in past violations of the statute. [
Footnote 6] In the absence of any indication that a lesser
discrimination might not affect competition, there was no need to
afford an escape clause through which the seller might frustrate
the whole purpose of the proceedings and the order by limiting
future discrimination to something less than 5%. [
Footnote 7]
The roofing material customers of Ruberoid may be classified as
wholesalers, retailers, and roofing contractors or applicators.
[
Footnote 8] The
discriminations found by the Commission were in sales to retailers
and applicators. The
Page 343 U. S. 475
Commission held that there was insufficient evidence in the
record to establish discrimination among wholesalers, as such.
Ruberoid contends that the order should have been similarly limited
to sales to retailers and applicators. But there was ample evidence
that Ruberoid's classification of its customers did not follow real
functional differences. Thus, some purchasers which Ruberoid
designated as "wholesalers" and to which Ruberoid allowed extra
discounts in fact competed with other purchasers as applicators.
And the Commission found that some purchasers operated as both
wholesalers and applicators. So finding, the Commissioner
disregarded these ambiguous labels, which might be used to cloak
discriminatory discounts to favored customers, and stated its order
in terms of "purchasers who in fact compete." Thus stated, we think
the order is understandable, reasonably related to the facts shown
by the evidence, and within the broad discretion which the
Commission possesses in determining remedies.
Finally, Ruberoid complains that the order enjoins lawful acts
by failing to except from its prohibitions differentials which
merely make allowance for differences in cost of manufacture, sale
or delivery, or which are made in good faith to meet an equally low
price of a competitor. Differences in price satisfying either of
these tests are permitted by the terms of the Act. [
Footnote 9] It is argued that the Commission
has radically broadened its prohibitory
Page 343 U. S. 476
powers through failure to include these provisos in the order.
We do not think so, because we think the provisos are necessarily
implicit in every order issued under the authority of the Act, just
as if the order set them out
in extenso. Although previous
Commission orders have included these provisos, they gained no
force by that inclusion. Their absence cannot preclude the seller
from differentiating in price in a new competitive situation
involving different circumstances where it can justify the
discrimination in accordance with the statutory provisos. Nor is
the seller required to seek modification of the order each time,
for example, that a competitor's price reduction requires it either
to lower its price in good faith to meet the lower competing price
or to lose a fleeting sales opportunity. On the other hand, the
implied inclusion of the provisos in the order does not shift from
the seller the burden of proof of justification. [
Footnote 10] Neither does recognition of
the implicit availability of these defenses allow the seller to
relitigate issues already settled by prior proceedings before the
Commission which resulted in an order that was affirmed in the
courts. If questions of justification, claimed upon the basis of
facts relating to costs or meeting competition, have once been
finally decided against the seller, it cannot again interpose the
same defense upon substantially similar facts when the Commission
seeks to show that its order has been violated. [
Footnote 11]
Page 343 U. S. 477
The same result follows where the evidence supporting the
defense, although not produced in the previous proceedings, was
then available to the seller. In short, the seller, in contesting
enforcement or contempt proceedings, may plead only those facts
constituting statutory justification which it has not had a
previous opportunity to present.
The sole question presented by the Commission's petition
concerns the lower court's holding, with one dissent, that the
Commission could not
"obtain a decree directing enforcement of an order issued under
the Clayton Act in the absence of showing that a violation of the
order has occurred or is imminent. [
Footnote 12]"
The pertinent parts of the Act provide:
"If such person [subject to the order] fails or neglects to obey
such order of the commission . . . while the same is in effect, the
commission . . . may apply to the circuit court of appeals of the
United States . . . for the enforcement of its order. . . . [T]he
court . . . shall have power to make and enter . . . a decree
affirming, modifying, or setting aside the order of the commission.
. . ."
"Any party required by such order of the commission . . . to
cease and desist from a violation charged may obtain a review of
such order in said circuit court of appeals by filing in the court
a written petition praying that the order of the commission . . .
be set aside. . . . [T]he court shall have the same jurisdiction to
affirm, set aside, or modify the order of the commission . . . as
in the case of an application
Page 343 U. S. 478
by the commission . . . for the enforcement of its order. . .
."
"The jurisdiction of the circuit court of appeals of the United
States to enforce, set aside, or modify orders of the commission .
. . shall be exclusive. [
Footnote 13]"
The Commission argues first that the provision authorizing it to
apply for enforcement "if such person fails or neglects to obey
such order" is merely "a Congressional directive to the Commission
as to the circumstances under which it may go into court to seek
enforcement," which does not amount to a prerequisite to the
court's granting of enforcement. [
Footnote 14] We cannot subscribe to this argument, which
disregards the unequivocal language of the statute and its
consistent interpretation over the thirty-eight-year period of its
existence. [
Footnote 15]
Congress, in 1938, amended similar language in the Federal Trade
Commission Act so that the reviewing court is now plainly required,
upon affirmance, to enforce an order based upon violation of that
Act. [
Footnote 16] The
Commission has
Page 343 U. S. 479
repeatedly sought similar amendment of the Clayton Act
provisions involved in this case. [
Footnote 17] We will not now achieve the same result by
reinterpretation in the face of Congress' failure to pass the bills
thus brought before it. [
Footnote 18] Effective enforcement of the Clayton Act by
the Commission may be handicapped by the present provisions, but
that is a question of policy for Congress.
Alternatively, the Commission argues that, even though
disobedience of the order is a condition to enforcement upon the
application of the Commission, there is no such condition where the
order comes before the court upon petition for review by the
affected party. This argument begins with the difference in
language between the statutory paragraphs providing for review at
the instance of the respective parties, but consideration of the
section as a whole convinces us that the most that can be said for
the argument is that the section is ambiguous. We think the
statutory prerequisite to enforcement applies when the Commission
seeks enforcement by cross-petition after review has been set in
motion by the party subject to the order as well as when the
Commission makes the original application. [
Footnote 19] There is no reason why one who has
complied with the order, but who seeks to have it reviewed and
modified or set aside, should be placed in a worse position than
one who does not exercise that right. We
Page 343 U. S. 480
doubt that Congress intended its requirement for enforcement to
depend entirely upon which party goes to court first.
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE BLACK concurs in the judgment and opinion of the
Court, except that he thinks the Commission's order should
expressly except from its prohibitions differentials which merely
make allowances for differences in the cost of manufacture, sale,
or delivery, or which are made in good faith to meet an equally low
price of a competitor.
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER, not having heard the argument, owing to
illness, took no part in the disposition of this case.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS dissents from the denial of enforcement of
the order.
* Together with No. 504,
Ruberoid Co. v. Federal Trade
Commission, also on certiorari to the same court.
[
Footnote 1]
46 F.T.C. 379, 386.
[
Footnote 2]
38 Stat. 730, as amended, 49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. §
13.
[
Footnote 3]
46 F.T.C. 379, 387.
[
Footnote 4]
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S.
37,
334 U. S. 51-52
(1948);
cf. International Salt Co. v. United States,
332 U. S. 392,
332 U. S.
398-400 (1947).
[
Footnote 5]
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Cement Institute, 333 U.
S. 683,
333 U. S.
726-727 (1948), 15 U.S.C. § 47.
[
Footnote 6]
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S.
37,
334 U. S. 51-52
(1948);
cf. Labor Board v. Express Publishing Co.,
312 U. S. 426,
312 U. S.
436-437 (1941).
[
Footnote 7]
"True, the Commission did not merely prohibit future discounts,
rebates, and allowances in the exact mathematical percentages
previously utilized by respondent. Had the order done no more than
that, respondent could have continued substantially the same
unlawful practices despite the order, by simply altering the
discount percentages and the quantities of salt to which the
percentages applied."
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S.
37,
334 U. S. 52-53
(1948). The discussion following these words in the
Morton
Salt case, of certain aspects of the order in question there,
manifestly affords no support to Ruberoid's contention here.
Id. at
334 U. S.
53-54.
[
Footnote 8]
Ruberoid suggests a fourth category of purchasers --
manufacturers -- and contends that the order is too broad in that
it prohibits discrimination in sales to that group,
e.g.,
in sales of shingles to competing manufacturers of prefabricated
houses. We need not consider whether such an order would be too
broad, because we do not think the order here applies to such
sales. By its terms, the order covers only sales to those
competitively engaged "in the resale or distribution of such
products (
i.e., asbestos or asphalt roofing
materials')," and not sales to those who use roofing materials in
the fabrication of wholly new and different products.
[
Footnote 9]
"[N]othing herein contained shall prevent differentials which
make only due allowance for differences in the cost of manufacture,
sale, or delivery resulting from the differing methods or
quantities in which such commodities are to such purchasers sold or
delivered. . . ."
49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. § 13(a)
"[N]othing herein contained shall prevent a seller rebutting the
prima-facie case thus made by showing that his lower price . . .
was made in good faith to meet an equally low price of a
competitor. . . ."
49 Stat. 1526, 15 U.S.C. § 13(b),
Standard Oil Co. v.
Federal Trade Comm'n, 340 U. S. 231
(1951). Ruberoid does not complain of the omission from the order
of the statutory provisos relating to the seller's right to select
its own customers and to price changes in response to changing
conditions affecting the market for, or the marketability of, the
goods concerned. Hence, we do not deal with those defenses
here.
[
Footnote 10]
Cf. Federal Trade Comm'n v. Morton Salt Co.,
334 U. S. 37,
334 U. S. 44-45
(1948), cost justification;
Federal Trade Comm'n v. A. E.
Staley Mfg. Co., 324 U. S. 746
(1945), "meeting competition" justification.
[
Footnote 11]
Where the Commission seeks both affirmance and enforcement of
its order in one proceeding, contending that the seller has
continued in its unlawful practices since the order was issued, the
court, in deciding whether the order should be affirmed, will, of
course, review the determination of the Commission in the ordinary
manner. But questions thus settled will not be open in deciding
whether the order has been violated, and should therefore be
enforced.
[
Footnote 12]
191 F.2d 294, 295.
[
Footnote 13]
38 Stat. 735, as amended, 15 U.S.C. § 21.
[
Footnote 14]
Brief for the Federal Trade Commission in No. 448, p. 16.
[
Footnote 15]
E.g., Federal Trade Comm'n v. Whitney & Co., 192
F.2d 746 (1951);
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Standard Brands,
Inc., 189 F.2d 510 (1951);
Federal Trade Comm'n v.
Herzog, 150 F.2d 450 (1945);
Federal Trade Comm'n v.
Baltimore Paint & Color Works, 41 F.2d 474 (1930);
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Balme, 23 F.2d 615 (1928);
Federal Trade Comm'n v. Standard Education Society, 14
F.2d 947 (1926). The last three cases cited arose under the Federal
Trade Commission Act, but, since the Clayton Act provisions
involved here are identical with the corresponding provisions of
the Federal Trade Commission Act prior to 1938, 38 Stat. 720, the
decisions make no distinction between them.
[
Footnote 16]
"To the extent that the order of the Commission is affirmed, the
court shall thereupon issue its own order commanding obedience to
the terms of such order of the Commission."
52 Stat. 113, 15 U.S.C. § 45(c). Unless the party subject
to an order issued under the provisions of the Federal Trade
Commission Act files a petition for review within sixty days, the
order becomes final and its violation punishable. 52 Stat. 113-114,
15 U.S.C. § 45(g) and (1).
[
Footnote 17]
E.g., F.T.C.Ann.Rep. 7-8 (1951); F.T.C.Ann.Rep. 12
(1948); F.T.C.Ann.Rep. 13 (1947); F.T.C.Ann.Rep. 12 (1946).
[
Footnote 18]
E.g., H.R.10176, 75th Cong., 3d Sess.; H.R.3402, 81st
Cong., 1st Sess.
[
Footnote 19]
Accord, e.g., Federal Trade Comm'n v. Fairyfoot Products
Co., 94 F.2d 844 (1938);
Butterick Co. v. Federal Trade
Comm'n, 4 F.2d 910 (1925);
L. B. Silver Co. v. Federal
Trade Comm'n, 292 F. 752 (1923).
MR. JUSTICE JACKSON, dissenting in No. 504.
The Federal Trade Commission, in July of 1943, instituted before
itself a proceeding against petitioner on a charge of
discriminating in price between customers in violation of
subsection (a) of § 2 of the Clayton Act as amended by the
Robinson-Patman Act, approved June 19, 1936, 15 U.S.C. §
13(a).
Several violations were proved and admitted to have occurred in
1941. No serious opposition was offered to an order to cease and
desist from such discriminations, but petitioner did object to
being ordered to cease types of violations it never had begun, and
asked that any order include a clause to the effect that it did not
forbid the price differentials between customers which are
expressly allowed by statute.
Page 343 U. S. 481
However, the Commission refused to include such a provision as
"unnecessary to assure respondent [petitioner here] its full legal
rights." It also rejected the specific and limited order
recommended by its Examiner and substituted a sweeping general
order to
"cease and desist from discriminating in price: by selling such
products of like grade and quality to any purchaser at prices lower
than those granted other purchasers who in fact, compete with the
favored purchaser in the resale or distribution of such
products."
It wrote no opinion, and gave only the most cryptic reasons in
its findings. [
Footnote 2/1]
On proceedings for review, petitioner attacked this order for
its indeterminateness and its prohibition of differentials allowed
by statute. The Court of Appeals, however, affirmed, saying:
"We sympathize with the petitioner's position, and can realize
the difficulties of conducting business under such general
prohibitions. Nevertheless we are convinced that the cause of the
trouble is the Act itself, which is vague and general in its
wording and which cannot be translated with assurance into any
detailed set of guiding yardsticks. [
Footnote 2/2]"
This appraisal of the result of almost ten years of litigation
exposes a grave deficiency either in the Act itself or in the
administrative process by which it has been applied. Admitting that
the statute is "vague and general in its wording," it does not
follow that a cease and desist order implementing it should be. I
think such an outcome of administrative proceedings is not
acceptable. We would rectify and advance the administrative
process,
Page 343 U. S. 482
which has become an indispensable adjunct to modern government,
by returning this case to the Commission to perform its most useful
function in administering an admittedly complicated Act.
If the Court of Appeals were correct, it would mean that the
intercession of the administrative process between the Congress and
the Court does nothing either to define petitioner's duties and
liabilities or to impose sanctions. Congress might as well have
declared, in these comprehensive terms, a duty not to discriminate,
and provided for prosecution of violations in the courts. That, of
course, would impose on the courts the task of determining the
meaning and application of the law to the facts. But that is just
the task that this order imposes upon the courts in event of a
contempt proceeding. The courts have derived no more detailed
"guiding yardsticks" from the Commission than from Congress. On the
contrary, the ultimate enforcement is further confused by the
administrative proceeding, because it winds up with an order which
literally forbids what the Act expressly allows, and thus adds to
the difficulty of eventual sanctions should they become
necessary.
If the unsound result here were an isolated example of malaise
in the administrative scheme, its tolerance by the Court would be
less troubling, though no less wrong. But I think its decision may
encourage a deterioration of the administrative process of which
this case is symptomatic, and which invites invasion of the
independent agency administrative field by executive agencies.
Other symptoms, betokening the same basic confusion, are the
numerous occasions when administrative findings are inadequate for
purposes of review and recent instances in which part of the
government appears before us fighting another part -- usually a
wholly executive-controlled agency attacking one of the independent
administrative agencies -- the Departments of Agriculture
(
Secretary of
Page 343 U. S. 483
Agriculture v. United States et al., No. 710, now
pending in this Court) and Justice (
United States v. Interstate
Commerce Commission, 337 U. S. 426),
against the Interstate Commerce Commission, the Department of
Justice against the Maritime Commission (
Far East Conference v.
United States, 342 U. S. 570),
the Secretary of the Interior against the Federal Power Commission
(
United States ex rel. Chapman v. Federal Power
Commission, No. 658, now pending in this Court,
certiorari
granted, 343 U.S. 941). Abstract propositions may not solve
concrete cases, but, when basic confusion is responsible for a
particular result, resort to the fundamental principles which
determine the position of the administrative process in our system
may help to illuminate the shortcomings of that result.
I
The Act, like many regulatory measures, sketches a general
outline which contemplates its completion and clarification by the
administrative process before court review or enforcement.
This section of the Act admittedly is complicated and vague, in
itself, and even more so in its context. Indeed, the Court of
Appeals seems to have thought it almost beyond understanding. By
the Act, nothing is commanded to be done or omitted
unconditionally, and no conduct or omission is
per se
punishable. The commercial discriminations which it forbids are
those only which meet three statutory conditions and survive the
test of five statutory provisos. To determine which of its
overlapping and conflicting policies shall govern a particular case
involves inquiry into grades and qualities of goods,
discriminations and their economic effects on interstate commerce,
competition between customers, the economic effect of price
differentials to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly,
allowance for differences in cost of
Page 343 U. S. 484
manufacturing sale or delivery, and good faith in meeting of the
price, services, or facilities of competitors.
This Act exemplifies the complexity of the modern lawmaking task
and a common technique for regulatory legislation. It is typical of
instances where the Congress cannot itself make every choice
between possible lines of policy. It must legislate in
generalities, and delegate the final detailed choices to some
authority with considerable latitude to conform its orders to
administrative, as well as legislative, policies.
The large importance that policy and expertise were expected to
play in reducing this Act to "guiding yardsticks" is evidenced by
the fact that authority to enforce the section is not confided to a
single body for all industries, but is dispersed among four
administrative agencies which deal with special types of commerce
besides the Federal Trade Commission. [
Footnote 2/3]
A seller may violate this section of the Act without guilty
knowledge or intent, and may unwittingly subject himself to a cease
and desist order. But neither violation of the Act nor of the order
will call for criminal sanctions; neither is even enforceable on
behalf of the United States by injunction until after an
administrative proceeding has resulted in a cease and desist order
and it has been reviewed and affirmed, if review be sought, by the
Court of Appeals. Only an enforcement order issued from the court
carries public sanctions, [
Footnote
2/4] and its violation is punishable as a contempt.
Page 343 U. S. 485
Thus, Congress, in this Act, has refrained from imposition of an
unconditional duty directly enforceable by the government through
civil or criminal proceedings in court, as it has in the Sherman
Anti-Trust Act and the Wilson Tariff Act of 1894. [
Footnote 2/5] It has carefully kept such cases as
this out of the courts, and has shielded a violator from any
penalty until the administrative tribunal hands down a definitive
order. The difference is accented by another section of the
Robinson-Patman Act which does make participation by any person in
specified transactions which discriminate "to his knowledge" a
criminal violation judicially punishable. [
Footnote 2/6]
It may help clarify the proper administrative function in such
cases to think of the legislation as unfinished law which the
administrative body must complete before it is ready for
application. [
Footnote 2/7] In a
very real sense, the legislation
Page 343 U. S. 486
does not bring to a close the making of the law. The Congress is
not able or willing to finish the task of prescribing a positive
and precise legal right or duty by eliminating all further choice
between policies, expediences, or conflicting guides, and so leaves
the rounding out of its command to another smaller and specialized
agency.
It is characteristic of such legislation that it does not
undertake to declare an end result in particular cases, but rather
undertakes to control the processes in the administrator's mind by
which he shall reach results. Because Congress cannot predetermine
the weight and effect of the presence or absence of all of the
competing considerations or conditions which should influence
decisions regulating modern business, it attempts no more than to
indicate generally the outside limits of the ultimate result and to
set out matters about which the administrator must think when he is
determining what within those confines the compulsion in a
particular case is to be.
Such legislation does not confer on any of the parties in
interest the right to a particular result, nor even to what we
might think ought to be the correct one, but it gives them the
right to a process for determining these rights and duties.
Montana-Dakota Utilities Co. v. Northwestern Public Service
Co., 341 U. S. 246,
341 U. S. 251;
Phelps Dodge Corp. v. Labor Board, 313 U.
S. 177,
313 U. S.
194-195.
Such legislation represents inchoate law in the sense that it
does not lay down rules which call for immediate compliance on pain
of punishment by judicial process. The intervention of another
authority must mature and perfect an effective rule of conduct
before one is subject to coercion. The statute, in order to rule
any individual case, requires an additional exercise of discretion
and that
Page 343 U. S. 487
last touch of selection which neither the primary legislator nor
the reviewing court can supply. The only reason for the
intervention of an administrative body is to exercise a grant of
unexpended legislative power to weigh what the legislature wants
weighed, to reduce conflicting abstract policies to a concrete net
remainder of duty or right. Then, and then only, do we have a
completed expression of the legislative will in an administrative
order which we may call a sort of secondary legislation, ready to
be enforced by the courts.
II
The constitutional independence of the administrative
tribunal presupposes that it will perform the function of
completing unfinished law.
The rise of administrative bodies probably has been the most
significant legal trend of the last century, and perhaps more
values today are affected by their decisions than by those of all
the courts, review of administrative decisions apart. They also
have begun to have important consequences on personal rights.
Cf. United States v. Spector, 343 U.
S. 169. They have become a veritable fourth branch of
the Government, which has deranged our three-branch legal theories
much as the concept of a fourth dimension unsettles our
three-dimensional thinking.
Courts have differed in assigning a place to these seemingly
necessary bodies in our constitutional system. Administrative
agencies have been called
quasi-legislative,
quasi-executive, or
quasi-judicial, as the
occasion required, in order to validate their functions within the
separation of powers scheme of the Constitution. The mere retreat
to the qualifying "
quasi" is implicit with confession that
all recognized classifications have broken
Page 343 U. S. 488
down, and "
quasi" is a smooth cover which we draw over
our confusion, as we might use a counterpane to conceal a
disordered bed.
The perfect example is the Federal Trade Commission itself. By
the doctrine that it exercises legislative discretions as to policy
in completing and perfecting the legislative process, it has
escaped executive domination, on the one hand, and been exempted in
large measure from judicial review, on the other. If all it has to
do is to order the literal statute faithfully executed, it would
exercise a function confided exclusively to the President, and
would be subject to his control.
Cf. Myers v. United
States, 272 U. S. 52;
U.S.Const., Art. II, §§ 1, 3. This Court saved it from
executive domination only by recourse to the doctrine that,
"In administering the provisions of the statute in respect of
'unfair methods of competition,' that is to say, in filling in and
administering the details embodied by that general standard, the
commission acts in part
quasi-legislatively and in part
quasi-judicially."
Humphrey's Executor v. United States, 295 U.
S. 602,
295 U. S.
628.
When Congress enacts a statute that is complete in policy
aspects and ready to be executed as law, Congress has recognized
that enforcement is only an executive function, and has yielded
that duty to wholly executive agencies, even though determination
of fact questions was necessary. [
Footnote 2/8] Examples of the creation of such
rights
Page 343 U. S. 489
and obligations are patent, revenue and customs laws. Only where
the law is not yet clear of policy elements, and therefore not
ready for mere executive enforcement, is it withdrawn from the
executive department and confided to independent tribunals. If the
tribunal to which such discretion is delegated does nothing but
promulgate as its own decision the generalities of its statutory
charter, the rationale for placing it beyond executive control is
gone.
Page 343 U. S. 490
III.
The quasi-legislative function of filling in blank spaces in
regulatory legislation and reconciling conflicting policy standards
must neither be passed on to the courts nor assumed by
them.
That the work of a Commission in translating an abstract statute
into a concrete cease and desist order in large measure escapes
judicial review because of its legislative character is an axiom of
administrative law, as the Court's decision herein shows. In
delegating the function of filling out the legislative will in
particular cases, Congress must not leave the statute too empty of
meaning. Courts look to its standards to see whether the
Commission's result is within the prescribed terms of reference --
whether the secondary legislation properly derives from the primary
legislation.
Then, too, we look to administrative findings not to reconsider
their justification, but to learn whether the parties have had the
process of determination to which the statute has entitled them and
whether the Commission has thought about -- or at least has written
about -- all factors which Congress directed it to consider in
translating unfinished legislation into a "detailed set of guiding
yardsticks" that becomes law of the case for parties and courts.
[
Footnote 2/9]
However, a determination by an independent agency, with
"
quasi-legislative" discretion in its armory, has a
Page 343 U. S. 491
much larger immunity from judicial review than does a
determination by a purely executive agency. The court, in review of
a case under the tax law or the patent law, where the legislative
function has been exhausted and policy considerations are settled
in the Acts themselves, follows the same mental operation as the
executive officer. On the facts, there results an obligation to pay
tax or there is a right to a patent. The court can deduce these
legal rights or obligations from the statute in the same manner as
the executive officer. Hence, review of such executive decisions
proceeds with no more deference to the administrative judgment than
to a decision of a lower court.
Very different, however, is the review of the
"
quasi-legislative" decision. There, the right or
liability of the parties is not determined by mere application of
statute to the facts. The right or obligation results not merely
from the abstract expression of the will of Congress in the
statute, but from the Commission's completion and concretization of
that will in its order.
Cf. Montana-Dakota Utilities Co. v.
Northwestern Public Service Co., supra, at
341 U. S. 251;
Phelps Dodge Corp. v. Labor Board, supra.
On review, the Court does not decide whether the correct
determination has been reached. So far as the Court is concerned, a
wide range of results may be equally correct. In review of such a
decision, the Court does not at all follow the same mental
processes as the Commission did in making it, for the judicial
function excludes (in theory at least) the policymaking or
legislative element, which rightfully influences the Commission's
judgment but over which judicial power does not extend. Since it is
difficult for a court to determine from the record where
quasi-legislative policymaking has stopped and
quasi-judicial application of policy has begun, the entire
process escapes very penetrating scrutiny.
Cf.
Page 343 U. S. 492
Federal Power Commission v. Hope Natural Gas Co.,
320 U. S. 591.
Courts are no better equipped to handle policy questions and no
more empowered to exercise legislative discretion on contempt
proceedings than on review proceedings. It is plain that, if the
scheme of regulating complicated enterprises through unfinished
legislation is to be just and effective, we must insist that the
legislative function be performed and exhausted by the
administrative body before the case is passed on to the courts.
IV
This proceeding should be remanded for a more definitive and
circumscribed order.
Returning to this case, I cannot find that ten years of
litigation have served any useful purpose whatever. No doubt, it is
administratively convenient to blanket an industry under a
comprehensive prohibition in bulk -- an undiscriminating
prohibition of discrimination. But this not only fails to give the
precision and concreteness of legal duties to the abstract policies
of the Act, it really promulgates an inaccurate partial paraphrase
of its indeterminate generalities. Instead of completing the
legislation by an order which will clarify the petitioner's duty,
it confounds confusion by literally ordering it to cease what the
statute permits it to do.
This Court and the court below defer solution of the problems
inherent in such an order on the theory that, if petitioner offends
again, there may be an enforcement order, and if it then offends
again, there may be a contempt proceeding, and that will be time
enough for the court to decide what the order against the
background of the Act really means. While I think this less than
justice, I am not greatly concerned about what the Court's decision
does to this individual petitioner, for whom I foresee no danger
more serious than endless litigation.
Page 343 U. S. 493
But I am concerned about what it does to administrative law.
To leave definition of the duties created by an order to a
contempt proceeding is for the courts to end where they should
begin. Injunctions are issued to be obeyed, even when justification
to issue them may be debatable.
United States v. United Mine
Workers of America, 330 U. S. 258,
330 U. S. 289
et seq., 330 U. S. 307.
But, in this case, issues that seem far from frivolous as to what
is forbidden are reserved for determination when punishment for
disobedience is sought. The Court holds that some modifications are
"implicit" in this order. Why should they not be made explicit? Why
approve an order whose literal terms we know go beyond the
authorization, on the theory that its excesses may be retracted if
ever it needs enforcement? Why invite judicial indulgence toward
violation by failure to be specific, positive and concrete?
It does not impress me as lawyerly practice to leave to a
contempt proceeding the clarification of the reciprocal effects of
this Act and order, and determination of the effect of statutory
provisos which are then to be read into the order. The courts
cannot and should not assume that function. It is, by our own
doctrine, a legislative or "
quasi-legislative" function,
and the courts cannot take over the discretionary functions of the
Commission which should enter into its determinations. Plainly this
order is not in shape to enforce, and does not become so by the
Court's affirmance.
This proceeding should be remanded to the Commission with
directions to make its order specific and concrete, to specify the
types of discount which are forbidden and reserve to petitioner the
rights which the statute allows it, unless they are deemed lost,
forfeited or impaired by the violations, in which case any
limitation should be set forth. The Commission should, in short, in
the light of its own policy and the record, translate
Page 343 U. S. 494
this Act into a "set of guiding yardsticks," admittedly now
lacking. If that cannot be done, there should be no judicial
approval for an order to cease and desist from we don't know
what.
If that were done, I should be included to accept the
Government's argument that, along with affirmance, enforcement may
be ordered. I see no real sense, when the case is already before
the Court and is approved, in requiring one more violation before
its obedience will be made mandatory on pain of contempt. But, as
this order stands, I am not surprised that enforcement should be
left to some later generation of judges.
[
Footnote 2/1]
A comprehensive study has pointed out the early failure of this
Commission (and it applies as well to others) to clarify and
develop the law, and thereby avoid litigation, by careful published
opinions. Henderson, The Federal Trade Commission 334.
[
Footnote 2/2]
Ruberoid Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 189 F.2d 893,
894.
[
Footnote 2/3]
15 U.S.C. § 21, vests enforcement in the Interstate
Commerce Commission, where applicable, to certain regulated common
carriers; in the Federal Communications Commission as to wire and
radio communications; Civil Aeronautics Board as to air carriers;
Federal Reserve Board as to banks, etc., and Federal Trade
Commission as to all other types of commerce.
[
Footnote 2/4]
15 U.S.C. § 21.
[
Footnote 2/5]
15 U.S.C. §§ 1-4, 8, 9.
[
Footnote 2/6]
15 U.S.C. § 13(a).
[
Footnote 2/7]
For emphasis and appreciation of this concept of American
administrative law and of the function of the administrative
tribunal as we have evolved it, I am indebted to an unpublished
treatise by Dr. Robert F. Weissenstein, whose Viennese and European
background, education, and practice gave him a perspective attained
with difficulty by us who are so accustomed to our own process.
Lord Chancellor Herschell has employed a different but effective
figure. "The truth is," said he,
"the legislation is a skeleton piece of legislation left to be
filled up in all its substantial and material particulars by the
action of rules to be made by the Board of Trade. . . . [I]t was
the intention of the Legislature, having expressed the general
object, and having provided the necessary penalty, to leave the
subordinate legislation, so to speak, to be carried out by the
Board of Trade."
Institute of Patent Agents v. Lockwood, [1894] A.C.
347, 356-357.
For an excellent study of English "Delegated Legislation Today,"
see Willis, Parliamentary Powers of English Government
Departments, c. II, p. 47. For the extent to which this system has
been used in England,
see Lord Macmillan, Local Government
Law and Administration in England and Wales, Vol. I, Preface.
[
Footnote 2/8]
The legislative history of the Fair Labor Standards Act, 29
U.S.C. § 201
et seq., exemplifies the choice which
Congress must make between itself completing the legislation and
delegating the completion to an administrative agency. H.R.Rep. No.
2738, 75th Cong., 3d Sess., sets forth a summary of both the House
Bill and the Senate Bill. The Senate Bill provided for the creation
of a Labor Standards Board composed of five members, which was
empowered to declare from time to time, for such occupations as are
brought within the bill, minimum wages
"which shall be as nearly adequate as economically feasible
without curtailing opportunity for employment, to maintain a
minimum standard of living necessary for health, efficiency, and
general wellbeing . . . ,"
but not in excess of 40 cents per hour.
Id. at 15.
Similar provisions empowered the Board to determine maximum hours
provided that in no case should the maximum be set at less than 40
hours.
Id. at 16. Likewise, the Board was empowered to
require the elimination of substandard labor conditions.
Id. at 17.
The House Bill, on the other hand, itself laid down the minimum
wage and maximum hour requirements,
id. 22-23, and gave to
the Secretary of Labor discretion only to determine which
industries were within the terms of the law, plus the power to
investigate compliance with the law.
Id. at 23. The Act as
ultimately adopted followed the House Bill; although there was
created the office of Administrator of the Wage and Hour Division
in the Department of Labor, the Administrator was given discretion
only in minor matters relating to the applicability of the
congressional standards. 52 Stat. 1060, 29 U.S.C. § 201
et
seq.
The Administration favored the plan of delegating legislative
discretion to an independent administrative body to apply general
standards to concrete cases.
See testimony of Secretary of
Labor Frances Perkins, Joint Hearings before the Senate Committee
on Educations and Labor and the House Committee on Labor on S. 2475
and H.R. 7200, 75th Cong., 1st Sess. 178. However, the attempt of
Congress itself to complete this complex law for enforcement by the
Executive, through the courts, not only flooded the courts with
litigation, but the courts' interpretation of the Act, contrary to
the policy which Congress thought it had indicated, had disastrous
consequences. 61 Stat. 84, 29 U.S.C. § 251
et
seq.
[
Footnote 2/9]
If the independent agencies could realize how much
trustworthiness judges give to workmanlike findings and opinions,
and how their causes are prejudiced on review by slipshod,
imprecise findings and failure to elucidate by opinion the process
by which ultimate determinations have been reached, their work and
their score on review would doubtless improve.
See
Henderson, The Federal Trade Commission, c. VI, p. 327.
See
also Commission on Organization of the Executive Branch of the
Government, Task Force Report on Regulatory Commissions (App. N.)
pp. 129-130.