1. When there is a combination or conspiracy to control and
dominate interstate trade and commerce in a commodity, coupled with
the power and intent to exclude competitors to a substantial
extent, the crime of monopolization under § 2 of the Sherman
Anti-Trust Act is complete, and the actual exclusion of competitors
is not necessary to the crime. Pp.
328 U. S.
784-787,
328 U. S. 798,
328 U. S.
808-815.
2. To support a conviction for conspiring to monopolize certain
trade in violation of the Sherman Act, it is not necessary to show
power and intent to exclude all competitors, nor to show a
conspiracy to exclude all competitors. P.
328 U. S.
789.
3. Under § 2 of the Sherman Act, it is the crime of
monopolizing for parties to combine or conspire to acquire or
maintain the power to exclude competitors from any part of the
trade or commerce among the several States or with foreign nations,
provided (a) they also have such a power that they are able, as a
group, to exclude actual or potential competition from the field
and (b) they have the intent and purpose to exercise that power. P.
328 U. S.
809.
4. It is not the form of the combination or the particular means
used but the result to be achieved that the statute condemns. P.
328 U. S.
809.
5. It is not important whether the means used to accomplish the
unlawful objective are in themselves lawful or unlawful. P.
328 U. S.
809.
6. No formal agreement is necessary to constitute an unlawful
conspiracy. P.
328 U. S.
809.
7. The essential combination or conspiracy in violation of the
Sherman Act may be found in a course of dealing or other
circumstances as well as in an exchange of words. Pp.
328 U. S.
809-810.
8. Neither proof of exertion of the power to exclude nor proof
of actual exclusion of existing or potential competitors is
essential to sustain a charge of monopolization under the Sherman
Act. P.
328 U. S.
810.
Page 328 U. S. 782
9. A combination may be one in restraint of interstate trade or
commerce or to monopolize a part of such trade or commerce in
violation of the Sherman Act, although such restraint or monopoly
may not have been actually attained to any harmful extent. P.
328 U. S.
811.
10. The material consideration in determining whether a monopoly
exists is not that prices are raised and that competition actually
is excluded, but that power exists to raise prices or to exclude
competition when it is desired to do so. P.
328 U. S.
811.
11.
United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d
416, approved. Pp.
328 U. S.
811-814.
12. Separate convictions for a conspiracy to restrain trade and
for a conspiracy to monopolize trade do not amount to double
jeopardy or to a multiplicity of punishment in a single proceeding
contrary to the Fifth Amendment, since they are separate statutory
offenses, one being made criminal by § 1 and the other by
§ 2 of the Sherman Act.
Braverman v. United States,
317 U. S. 49,
distinguished. Pp.
328 U. S.
787-788.
13. Separate convictions for monopolization and for conspiring
to monopolize in violation of the Sherman Act do not result in
multiple punishment contrary to the Fifth Amendment, since they are
separate offenses.
United States v. Rabinowich,
238 U. S. 78;
Pinkerton v. United States, 328 U.
S. 640. Pp.
328 U. S.
788-789.
147 F.2d 93, affirmed.
Petitioners were convicted of violating §§ 1 and 2 of
the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. The Circuit Court of Appeals affirmed.
147 F.2d 93. This Court granted certiorari "limited to the question
whether actual exclusion of competitors is necessary to the crime
of monopolization under § 2 of the Sherman Act." 324 U.S. 836.
A petition for rehearing and enlargement of the scope of review in
No. 20 was denied. 324 U.S. 891.
Affirmed, p.
328 U. S.
815.
Page 328 U. S. 783
MR. JUSTICE BURTON delivered the opinion of the Court.
The petitioners are The American Tobacco Company, Liggett &
Myers Tobacco Company, R. J. Reynolds Tobacco Company, [
Footnote 1] American Suppliers, Inc., a
subsidiary of American, and certain officials of the respective
companies who were convicted by a jury, in the District Court of
the United States for the Eastern District of Kentucky, of
violating §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act
pursuant to an information filed July 24, 1940, and modified
October 31, 1940.
Each petitioner was convicted on four counts: (1) conspiracy in
restraint of trade, (2) monopolization, (3) attempt to monopolize,
and (4) conspiracy to monopolize. Each count related to interstate
and foreign trade and commerce in tobacco. No sentence was imposed
under the third count, as the Court held that that count was merged
in the second. Each petitioner was fined $5,000 on each of the
other counts, making $15,000 for each petitioner and a total of
$255,000. Seven other defendants were found not guilty, and a
number of the original defendants were severed from the proceedings
pursuant to stipulation.
The Circuit Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit, on December
8, 1944, affirmed each conviction. 147 F.2d
Page 328 U. S. 784
93. All the grounds urged for review of those judgments were
considered here on petitions for certiorari. On March 26, 1945,
this Court granted the petitions, but each was "limited to the
question whether actual exclusion of competitors is necessary to
the crime of monopolization under Section 2 of the Sherman Act."
324 U.S. 836. On April 23, 1945, Reynolds,
et al., filed a
petition for rehearing and enlargement of the scope of review in
their case, but it was denied. 3 24 U.S. 891. This opinion is
limited to the convictions under § 2 of the Sherman Act,
[
Footnote 2] and deals
especially with those for monopolization under the second count of
the information.
The issue thus emphasized in the order allowing certiorari and
primarily argued by the parties has not been previously decided by
this Court. It is raised by the following instructions which were
especially applicable to the second count, [
Footnote 3] but were related also to the other counts
under § 2 of the Sherman Act:
"Now the term '
monopolize,' as used in Section 2 of the
Sherman Act, as well as in the last three counts
Page 328 U. S. 785
of the Information, means the joint acquisition or maintenance
by the members of a conspiracy formed for that purpose, of the
power to control and dominate interstate trade and commerce in
a commodity to such an extent that they are able, as a group, to
exclude actual or potential competitors from the field, accompanied
with the intention and purpose to exercise such power."
"The phrase 'attempt to monopolize' means the employment of
methods, means, and practices which would, if successful,
accomplish monopolization, and which, though falling short,
nevertheless approach so close as to create a dangerous probability
of it, which methods, means, and practices are so employed by the
members of and pursuant to a combination or conspiracy formed for
the purpose of such accomplishment."
"It is in no respect a violation of the law that a number of
individuals or corporations, each acting for himself or itself, may
own or control a large part, or even all of a particular commodity,
or all the business of a particular commodity."
"An
essential element of the illegal monopoly or
monopolization charged
in this case is the existence
Page 328 U. S. 786
of a combination or conspiracy to acquire and maintain the
power to exclude competitors to a substantial extent."
"Thus, you will see that
an indispensable ingredient of each
of the offenses charged in the Information is a combination or
conspiracy."
(Italics supplied.)
While the question before us, as briefly stated in the Court's
order, makes no express reference to the inclusion in the crime of
"monopolization" of the element of "a combination or conspiracy to
acquire and maintain the power to exclude competitors to a
substantial extent," yet the trial court, in its above-quoted
instructions to the jury, described such a combination or
conspiracy as an "essential element" and an "indispensable
ingredient" of that crime in the present cases. We therefore
include that element in determining whether the foregoing
instructions correctly stated the law as applied to these cases. In
discussing the legal issue, we shall assume that such a combination
or conspiracy to monopolize has been established. Because of the
presence of that element, we do not have here the hypothetical case
of parties who themselves have not "achieved" monopoly, but have
had monopoly "thrust upon" them.
See United States v. Aluminum
Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416, 429.
The present cases are not comparable to cases where the parties,
for example, merely have made a new discovery or an original entry
into a new field and unexpectedly or unavoidably have found
themselves enjoying a monopoly, coupled with power and intent to
maintain it. In the
Aluminum Co. case, discussed later,
there was a use of various unlawful means to establish or maintain
the monopoly. Here, we have the additional element of a combination
or conspiracy to acquire or maintain the power to exclude
competitors that is charged in the fourth count.
Page 328 U. S. 787
The present opinion is not a finding by this Court one way or
the other on the many closely contested issues of fact. The present
opinion is an application of the law to the facts as they were
found by the jury and which the Circuit Court of Appeals held
should not be set aside. [
Footnote
4] The trial court's instruction did not call for proof of an
"actual exclusion" of competitors on the part of the petitioners.
For the purposes of this opinion, we shall assume, therefore, that
an actual exclusion of competitors by the petitioners was not
claimed or established by the prosecution. Simply stated, the issue
is: do the facts called for by the trial court's definition of
monopolization amount to a violation of § 2 of the Sherman
Act?
Before reaching that issue, we shall touch upon another
contention which the petitioners have made and which the Government
has undertaken to answer. This is the contention that the separate
convictions returned under the conspiracy count in restraint of
trade and under the conspiracy count to monopolize trade amount to
double jeopardy, or to a multiplicity of punishment in a single
proceeding, and therefore violate the Fifth Amendment to the
Federal Constitution. [
Footnote
5] The petitioners argue that § 2 of the Sherman Act
should be interpreted to require proof of actual exclusion of
competitors in order to show "monopolization," and they claim that
only thus can a "conspiracy to monopolize" trade be sufficiently
differentiated from a "conspiracy in restraint of" trade as to
avoid subjecting the parties accused under those counts to double
jeopardy.
Page 328 U. S. 788
Petitioners seek support for these contentions as to the two
conspiracy counts from the principles stated in
Braverman v.
United States, 317 U. S. 49, and
in
Blockburger v. United States, 284 U.
S. 299. On the authority of the
Braverman case,
petitioners claim that there is but one conspiracy -- namely, a
conspiracy to fix prices. In contrast to the single conspiracy
described in that case in separate counts, all charged under the
general conspiracy statute, § 37, Criminal Code, 35 Stat.
1096, 18 U.S.C. § 88, we have here separate statutory
offenses, one a conspiracy in restraint of trade that may stop
short of monopoly and the other a conspiracy to monopolize that may
not be content with restraint short of monopoly. One is made
criminal by § 1 and the other by § 2 of the Sherman
Act.
We believe also that, in accordance with the
Blockburger case, §§ 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act
require proof of conspiracies which are reciprocally
distinguishable from and independent of each other although the
objects of the conspiracies may partially overlap.
Cf. United
States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.
S. 150,
310 U. S. 226.
In the present cases, the court below has found that there was more
than sufficient evidence to establish a conspiracy in restraint of
trade by price-fixing and other means, and also a conspiracy to
monopolize trade with the power and intent to exclude actual and
potential competitors from at least a part of the tobacco
industry.
Petitioners further suggest that the second count (to
monopolize), and the fourth count (to conspire to monopolize), may
lead to multiple punishment, contrary to the principle of the
Blockburger case. Petitioners argue that the Government's
theory of monopolization calls for proof of a joint enterprise with
power and intent to exclude competitors and therefore that the
conspiracy to monopolize
Page 328 U. S. 789
must be a part of that proof. It long has been settled, however,
that a "conspiracy to commit a crime is a different offense from
the crime that is the object of the conspiracy."
United States
v. Rabinowich, 238 U. S. 78,
238 U. S. 85;
Pinkerton v. United States, 328 U.
S. 640. Petitioners, for example, might have been
convicted here of a conspiracy to monopolize without ever having
acquired the power to carry out the object of the conspiracy --
i.e., to exclude actual and potential competitors from the
cigarette field.
Cf. United States v. Shapiro, 103 F.2d
775-776.
Although there is no issue of fact or question as to the
sufficiency of the evidence to be discussed here, nevertheless, it
is necessary to summarize the principal facts of that conspiracy to
monopolize certain trade, which was charged in the fourth count.
These facts demonstrate also the vigor and nature of the intent of
the petitioners to exclude competitors in order to maintain that
monopoly if need or occasion shall offer itself to attempt such an
exclusion. To support the verdicts, it was not necessary to show
power and intent to exclude
all competitors, or to show a
conspiracy to exclude
all competitors. The requirement
stated to the jury and contained in the statute was only that the
offenders shall "monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among
the several States, or with foreign nations." This particular
conspiracy may well have derived special vitality, in the eyes of
the jury, from the fact that its existence was established, not
through the presentation of a formal written agreement, but through
the evidence of widespread and effective conduct on the part of
petitioners in relation to their existing or potential
competitors.
The three years at issue in the charges made were those
immediately preceding the filing of the informations on
Page 328 U. S. 790
July 24, 1940, [
Footnote 6]
but, for convenience, the statistics relied upon generally have
been those for the calendar years 1937, 1938, and 1939. Because of
the circumstantial nature of most of the evidence, and because of
the essentiality of figures for comparative years in establishing
any restraint of trade or monopoly, the record also contains much
important material drawn from earlier years. Some appreciation of
the history and development of the cigarette industry is essential
to an understanding of the cases. However, in applying the law to
the central issue in these cases, the variations among the several
petitioners participating in each step are not material in reaching
the conclusion on the legal question before us. There were many
variations in the business activities of the several petitioners.
It would be cumbersome and difficult to state exactly which
petitioners and what combination of petitioners did each of the
acts mentioned. It is, however, not fair to refer, without
explanation, to all the acts simply as having been done by "the
petitioners." In its usual sense, "the petitioners" would include
all of them. Obviously, however, the corporate and individual
petitioners did not and could not all act precisely alike. To refer
only to "the corporate petitioners" would be unsatisfactory
because, in addition to American, Liggett, and Reynolds, there is
the corporate petitioner, American Suppliers, Inc. It participated
in only a limited number of activities, and then only as a
subsidiary of American. Furthermore, as pointed out by Reynolds in
its petition for rehearing and for enlargement of scope of review
in its
Page 328 U. S. 791
case, Reynolds' participation in some parts of the combination
or conspiracy differs in many respects from that of American and
Liggett.
The fact is that Reynolds, in 1913, actually broke into the
cigarette field with its Camel cigarettes, and as a vigorous
competitor of American, Liggett, and P. Lorillard Company,
revolutionized the cigarette industry. Gradually Reynolds grew to
be one of the "Big Three" with American and Liggett. The later
evidence then tends to show that those three, in spite of the
earlier competitive history of Reynolds, have operated together in
recent years in violation of the Sherman Act. Similarly, much of
the evidence relating to the purchase of tobacco at auction does
not apply in precisely equal degree to each petitioner. However,
taking the story as a whole, each petitioner now has been convicted
of the same offense under like counts, and the problem before us is
only to state the rule of law to be applied in defining
monopolization under the Sherman Act as applied to all of the
petitioners alike. To distinguish among them at each stage would
not change the legal conclusion on the one issue here presented,
but would confuse what should be a clear summary of the facts
essential to an understanding of that legal issue. Accordingly,
each reference to "petitioners" in this recital will mean "some or
all of the petitioners as disclosed by the record."
First of all, the monopoly found by the jury to exist in the
present cases appears to have been completely separable from the
old American Tobacco Trust which was dissolved in 1911. [
Footnote 7] The conspiracy to
monopolize and
Page 328 U. S. 792
the monopolization charged here do not depend upon proof
relating to the old tobacco trust, but upon a dominance and control
by petitioners in recent years over purchases
Page 328 U. S. 793
of the raw material and over the sale of the finished product in
the form of cigarettes. The fact, however, that the purchases of
leaf tobacco and the sales of so many products of the tobacco
industry have remained largely within the same general group of
business organizations for over a generation inevitably has
contributed to the ease with which control over competition within
the industry and the mobilization of power to resist new
competition can be exercised. A friendly relationship within such a
long established industry is, in itself, not only natural but
commendable and beneficial, as long as it does not breed illegal
activities. Such a community of interest in any industry, however,
provides a natural foundation for working policies and
understandings favorable to the insiders and unfavorable to
outsiders. The verdicts indicate that practices of an informal and
flexible nature were adopted, and that the results were so
uniformly beneficial to the petitioners in protecting their common
interests as against those of competitors that, entirely from
circumstantial evidence, the jury found that a combination or
conspiracy existed among the petitioners from 1937 to 1940, with
power and intent to exclude competitors to such a substantial
extent as to violate the Sherman Act as interpreted by the trial
court. [
Footnote 8]
Page 328 U. S. 794
The position of the petitioners in the cigarette industry from
1931 to 1939 is clear from the following tables:
PERCENTAGE OF TOTAL U.S. PRODUCTION OF SMALL CIGARETTES
1931-1939
bwm:
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------
1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939
American . . . . . . . 39.5 36.6 33.0 26.1 24.0 22.5 21.5 22.7
22.9
Liggett. . . . . . . . 22.7 23.0 28.1 27.4 26.0 24.6 23.6 22.9
21.6
Reynolds . . . . . . . 28.4 21.8 22.8 26.0 28.1 29.5 28.1 25.3
23.6
Lorillard. . . . . . . 6.5 5.2 4.7 4.1 3.8 4.3 4.7 5.1 5.8
Brown & Williamson . . O.2 6.9 5.5 8.3 9.6 9.6 9.9 9.9
10.6
Philip Morris. . . . . O.9 1.4 O.8 2.0 3.1 4.1 5.4 5.7 7.1
Stephano . . . . . . . O.1 O.1 O.2 O.5 1.4 1.9 2.5 3.1 3.3
Axton-Fisher . . . . . O.7 3.1 4.4 4.4 3.0 2.2 2.4 2.7 2.4
Larus. . . . . . . . . O.2 1.0 O.2 O.6 O.7 O.8 1.0 1.3 1.3
Combined Percentages
of American, Liggett
and Reynolds . . . . 90.7 81.4 83.9 79.5 78.0 76.7 73.3 71.0
68.0
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------
ewm:
Page 328 U. S. 795
bwm:
VOLUME OF CIGARETTE PRODUCTION -- 1931-1939
(billions of cigarettes)
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Total U.S. Production . . 117.1 106.6 114.9 130.0 140.0 158.9
170.0 171.7 180.7
American. . . . . . . . . 46.2 39.0 37.9 33.9 33.5 35.8 36.6
39.0 41.4
Liggett . . . . . . . . . 26.6 24.6 32.2 35.6 36.3 39.1 40.2
39.3 39.0
Reynolds. . . . . . . . . 33.3 23.2 26.2 33.8 39.4 46.9 47.8
43.5 42.6
Lorillard . . . . . . . . 7.6 5.5 5.4 5.3 5.3 6.8 8.1 8.8
10.5
Brown & Williamson. . . . O.3 7.3 6.3 10.8 13.4 15.2 16.8
17.1 19.1
Phillip Morris. . . . . . 1.0 1.5 O.9 2.6 4.4 6.4 9.2 9.7
12.8
Stephano. . . . . . . . . O.1 O.1 O.2 O.7 2.0 3.0 4.2 5.4
6.0
Axton-Fisher. . . . . . . O.8 3.3 5.0 5.7 4.2 3.5 4.1 4.5
4.3
Larus . . . . . . . . . . O.3 1.0 O.3 O.7 1.0 1.2 1.7 2.2
2.3
Combined volume of
American, Liggett
and Reynolds. . . . . . 106.1 86.8 96.3 103.3 109.2 121.8 124.6
121.8 123.0
----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
ewm:
The first table shows that, although American, Liggett, and
Reynolds gradually dropped in their percentage of the national
domestic cigarette production from 90.7% in 1931 to 73.3%, 71% and
68%, respectively, in 1937, 1938, and 1939, they have accounted at
all times for more than 68%, and usually for more than 75%, of the
national production. The balance of the cigarette production has
come from six other companies. No one of those six ever has
produced more than the 10.6% once reached by Brown & Williamson
in 1939. The second table shows that, while the percentage of
cigarettes produced by American, Liggett, and Reynolds in the
United States dropped gradually from 90.7% to 68%, their combined
volume of production actually increased from 106 billion in 1931 to
about 125 billion, 122 billion, and 123 billion, respectively, in
1937, 1938 and 1939. The remainder of the production was divided
among the other six companies. No one of those six ever has
produced more than about 19 billion cigarettes a year, which was
the high point reached by Brown & Williamson in 1939.
The further dominance of American, Liggett, and Reynolds within
their special field of burley blend cigarettes, as
Page 328 U. S. 796
compared with the so-called "10-cent cigarettes," is also
apparent. In 1939, the 10-cent cigarettes constituted about 14 1/2%
of the total domestic cigarette production. Accordingly, the 68% of
the total cigarette production enjoyed by American, Liggett, and
Reynolds amounted to 80% of that production within their special
field of cigarettes. The second table shows a like situation. In
1939, the 10-cent cigarettes accounted for 25.6 billion of the
cigarettes produced. Deducting this from the 57.7 billion
cigarettes produced by others than American, Liggett, and Reynolds
left only about 32 billion cigarettes of a comparable grade
produced in that year by competitors of the "Big Three" as against
the 123 billion produced by them. In addition to the combined
production by American, Liggett, and Reynolds in 1939 of over 68%
of all domestic cigarettes, they also produced over 63% of the
smoking tobacco and over 44% of the chewing tobacco. They never
were important factors in the cigar of snuff fields of the tobacco
industry.
The foregoing demonstrates the basis of the claim of American,
Liggett, and Reynolds to the title of the "Big Three." The marked
dominance enjoyed by each of these three, in roughly equal
proportions, is emphasized by the fact that the smallest of them at
all times showed over twice the production of the largest outsider.
Without adverse criticism of it, comparative size on this great
scale inevitably increased the power of these three to dominate all
phases of their industry. "Size carries with it an opportunity for
abuse that is not to be ignored when the opportunity is proved to
have been utilized in the past."
United States v. Swift &
Co., 286 U. S. 106,
286 U. S. 116.
An intent to use this power to maintain a monopoly was found by the
jury in these cases.
The record further shows that the net worth of American,
Liggett, and Reynolds in terms of their total assets,
Page 328 U. S. 797
less current liabilities, rose from $277,000,000 in 1912 to over
$551,000,000 in 1939. Their net annual earnings, before payment of
interest and dividends, rose from about $28,000,000 in 1912 to over
$75,000,000 in 1939. The record is full of evidence of the close
relationship between their large expenditures for national
advertising of cigarettes and resulting volumes of sales. In each
of the years 1937, 1938, and 1939, American, Liggett, and Reynolds
expended a total of over $40,000,000 a year for advertising. Such
advertising is not here criticized as a business expense. Such
advertising may benefit indirectly the entire industry, including
the competitors of the advertisers. Such tremendous advertising,
however, is also a widely published warning that these companies
possess and know how to use a powerful offensive and defensive
weapon against new competition. New competition dare not enter such
a field unless it be well supported by comparable national
advertising. Large inventories of cigarettes, and large sums
required for payment of federal taxes in advance of actual sales,
further emphasize the effectiveness of a well financed monopoly in
this field against potential competitors if there merely exists an
intent to exclude such competitors. Prevention of all potential
competition is the natural program for maintaining a monopoly here,
rather than any program of actual exclusion. "Prevention" is
cheaper and more effective than any amount of "cure."
With this background of a substantial monopoly, amounting to
over two-thirds of the entire domestic field of cigarettes, and to
over 80% of the field of comparable cigarettes, and with the
opposition confined to several small competitors, the jury could
have found from the actual operation of the petitioners that there
existed a combination or conspiracy among them not only in
restraint of trade, but to monopolize a part of the tobacco
Page 328 U. S. 798
industry. The trial court described this combination or
conspiracy as an "essential element" and "indispensable ingredient"
of the offenses charged. It is therefore only in conjunction with
such a combination or conspiracy that these cases will constitute a
precedent. The conspiracy so established by the verdicts under the
second count appears to have been one to fix and control prices and
other material conditions relating to the purchase of raw material
in the form of leaf tobacco for use in the manufacture of
cigarettes. It also appears to have been one to fix and control
prices and other material conditions relating to the distribution
and sale of the product of such tobacco in the form of cigarettes.
The jury found a conspiracy to monopolize to a substantial degree
the leaf market and the cigarette market. The jury's verdicts also
found a power and intent on the part of the petitioners to exclude
competition to a substantial extent in the tobacco industry.
I
The verdicts show that the jury found that the petitioners
conspired to fix prices and to exclude undesired competition
against them in the purchase of the domestic type of flue-cured
tobacco and of burley tobacco. These are raw materials essential to
the production of cigarettes of the grade sold by the petitioners
and also, to some extent, of the 10-cent grade of cigarettes which
constitutes the only substantial competition to American, Liggett,
and Reynolds in the cigarette field of the domestic tobacco
industry. The tobaccos involved in these cases are the flue-cured,
burley and Maryland tobaccos. The flue-cured or bright tobacco is
grown in a number of areas called "belts." These are in Virginia,
North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia and Florida. The tobacco
takes its name of flue-cured from the "curing" process to which
Page 328 U. S. 799
it is subjected and which consists of hanging the tobacco leaves
in barns heated by a system of flues. Between 50% and 60% of the
total flue-cured product is for export to England. The petitioners
purchased a combined total of between 50% and 80% of the domestic
flue-cured tobacco. The burley tobacco is produced largely in the
burley belt in Kentucky and Tennessee. It is cured without heating,
by exposing the leaves to the air in barns in which they are hung.
The petitioners purchased from 60% to 80% of the annual crop of
burley. The Maryland tobacco is grown in the southern part of that
State. Some of it is sold in auction markets, the rest is packed in
hogsheads and sold in two Baltimore warehouses by the Maryland
Tobacco Growers' Association and by commercial merchants. The
greater part of the Maryland tobacco was purchased by petitioners.
The crops in the more southerly belts mature first, and the burley
crops are not ready for market until late fall. When the tobacco is
ready for market, the farmers strip, sort, and grade the leaves
according to their judgment as to quality, tie them into bundles
called "hands" (except in Georgia, where the tobacco remains
loose), and truck them to tobacco auction markets. In the
possession of the farmers, the crops are perishable, as they
require a redrying process. Under the modern system of marketing,
the tobacco cannot be stored to await another season. The farmers
have no facilities for redrying the tobacco, and therefore must
sell their crops in the season in which those crops are raised, or
they will lose them. The petitioners kept large enough tobacco
stocks on hand to last about three years. The value of these stocks
was over $100,000,000 for each company, and these stocks assured
their independence of the market in any one year. Auction markets
for the sale of leaf tobacco have been in operation for many years,
and were well established long before the dissolution of
Page 328 U. S. 800
the tobacco trust in 1911. [
Footnote 9] Such markets are located in 75 towns in the
flue-cured region and 42 towns in the burley area. There are four
Maryland markets. Since the crop in the Georgia Belt matures first,
the markets in that belt open first, usually about August 1. The
auctioneers then follow the marketing seasons to the North,
reaching the "Old Belt" in North Carolina and Virginia in the
latter part of September. The dates for opening the markets in the
flue-cured belts are set by the Tobacco Association of the United
States, of which buyers, including petitioners, warehousemen and
others connected with the industry, but not including farmers, are
members. Burley sales begin in Lexington, Kentucky, which is the
principal market, on the first Monday in December. The other burley
markets open the next day. Sales continue, excepting at Christmas
time, for the next few months.
The Government introduced evidence showing that, although there
was no written or express agreement discovered among American,
Liggett, and Reynolds, their practices included a clear course of
dealing. This evidently convinced the jury of the existence of a
combination or conspiracy to fix and control prices and practices
as to domestic leaf tobacco, both in restraint of trade as such,
and to establish a substantially impregnable defense against any
attempted intrusion by potential competitors into these
markets.
It appeared that petitioners refused to purchase tobacco on
these markets unless the other petitioners were also represented
thereon. There were attempts made by
Page 328 U. S. 801
others to open new tobacco markets, but none of the petitioners
would participate in them unless the other petitioners were
present. Consequently, such markets were failures due to the
absence of buyers. It appeared that the tobacco farmers did not
want to sell their tobacco on a market in which the only purchasers
were speculators or dealers. The prices paid under such
circumstances were likely to be low in order that the purchasers
eventually might resell the tobacco to the manufacturing companies.
The foreign purchasers likewise would not participate without the
presence of the petitioners. In this way, the new tobacco markets
and their locations were determined by the unanimous consent of the
petitioners and, in arriving at their determination, the
petitioners consulted with each other as to whether or not a
community deserved a market.
The Government presented evidence to support its claim that,
before the markets opened, the petitioners placed limitations and
restrictions on the prices which their buyers were permitted to pay
for tobacco. None of the buyers exceeded these price ceilings.
Grades of tobacco were formulated in such a way as to result in the
absence of competition between the petitioners. There was
manipulation of the price of lower grade tobaccos in order to
restrict competition from manufacturers of the lower priced
cigarettes. Methods used included the practice of the petitioners
of calling their respective buyers in, prior to the opening of the
annual markets, and giving them instructions as to the prices to be
paid for leaf tobacco in each of the markets. These instructions
were in terms of top prices or price ranges. The price ceilings
thus established for the buyers were the same for each of them. In
case of tie bids, the auctioneer awarded the sale customarily to
the buyer who bid first. Under this custom, the buyers representing
the petitioners often made bids on various baskets of tobacco
Page 328 U. S. 802
before an opening price could be announced, so that they might
have their claim to the tobacco recognized at the understood
ceiling price in the case of tie bids. Often a buyer would bid
ahead by indicating that he wanted a certain basket further along
in the line of baskets, and in such cases, the tobacco in question
was awarded to such buyer without the mention of any price, it
being understood that it was sold at the top price theretofore
previously determined upon.
Where one or two of the petitioners secured their percentage of
the crop on a certain market or were not interested in the purchase
of certain offerings of tobacco, their buyers nevertheless would
enter the bidding in order to force the other petitioners to bid up
to the maximum price. The petitioners were not so much concerned
with the prices they paid for the leaf tobacco as that each should
pay the same price for the same grade, and that none would secure
any advantage in purchasing tobacco. They were all to be on the
same basis as far as the expenses of their purchases went. The
prices which were set at top prices by petitioners, or by the first
of them to purchase on the market, became, with few exceptions, the
top prices prevailing on those markets. Competition also was
eliminated between petitioners by the purchase of grades of tobacco
in which but one of them was interested. To accomplish this, each
company formulated the grades which it alone wished to purchase.
The other companies recognized the grades so formulated as
distinctive grades, and did not compete for them. While the
differences between the grades so formulated were distinguishable
by the highly trained special buyers, they were in reality so
minute as to be inconsequential. This element, however, did not
mean that a company could bid any price it wished for its
especially formulated grades of tobacco. The other companies
prevented that by bidding up the tobacco at least to a point where
they did not risk being
Page 328 U. S. 803
awarded the sale to themselves. Each company determined in
advance what portion of the entire crop it would purchase before
the market for that season opened. The petitioners then separately
informed their buyers of the percentage of the crop which they
wished to purchase, and gave instructions that only such a
percentage should be purchased on each market. The purchases were
spread evenly over the different markets throughout the season. No
matter what the size of the crop might be, the petitioners were
able to purchase their predetermined percentages thereof within the
price limits determined upon by them, thus indicating a stabilized
market. The respective petitioners employed supervisors whose
functions were to see that the prices were the same on one market
as on another. Where, because of difference in appraisals of grades
or other similar factors, the bidding was out of line with the
predetermined price limits or there was a tendency for prices to
vary from those on other markets, the supervisors sought to
maintain the same prices and grades on different markets. This was
sought to be achieved by instructions to buyers to change the
prices bid or the percentages purchased, and such actions proved to
be successful in maintaining and equalizing the prices on the
different markets.
At a time when the manufacturers of lower priced cigarettes were
beginning to manufacture them in quantity, the petitioners
commenced to make large purchases of the cheaper tobacco leaves
used for the manufacture of such lower priced cigarettes. No
explanation was offered as to how or where this tobacco was used by
petitioners. The compositions of their respective brands of
cigarettes calling for the use of more expensive tobaccos remained
unchanged during this period of controversy and up to the end of
the trial. The Government claimed that such purchases of cheaper
tobacco evidenced a combination and a purpose among the petitioners
to deprive the manufacturers
Page 328 U. S. 804
of cheaper cigarettes of the tobacco necessary for their
manufacture, as well as to raise the price of such tobacco to such
a point that cigarettes made therefrom could not be sold at a
sufficiently low price to compete with the petitioners' more highly
advertised brands.
II
The verdicts show also that the jury found that the petitioners
conspired to fix prices and to exclude undesired competition in the
distribution and sale of their principal products. The petitioners
sold and distributed their products to jobbers and to selected
dealers who bought at list prices, less discounts. Almost all of
the million or more dealers who handled the respective petitioners'
products throughout the country consisted of such establishments as
small storekeepers, gasoline station operators, and lunch room
proprietors who purchased the cigarettes from jobbers. The jobbers,
in turn, derived their profits from the difference between the
wholesale price paid by them and the price charged by them to local
dealers. A great advantage therefore accrued to any dealer buying
at the discounted or wholesale list prices. Selling to dealers at
jobbers' prices was called "direct selling," and the dealers as
well as the jobbers getting those prices were referred to as being
on the "direct list." The list prices charged and the discounts
allowed by petitioners have been practically identical since 1923,
and absolutely identical since 1928. Since the latter date, only
seven changes have been made by the three companies, and those have
been identical in amount. The increases were first announced by
Reynolds. American and Liggett thereupon increased their list
prices in identical amounts.
The following record of price changes is circumstantial evidence
of the existence of a conspiracy and of a power and intent to
exclude competition coming from cheaper
Page 328 U. S. 805
grade cigarettes. During the two years preceding June, 1931, the
petitioners produced 90% of the total cigarette production in the
United States. In that month, tobacco farmers were receiving the
lowest prices for their crops since 1905. The costs to the
petitioners for tobacco leaf therefore were lower than usual during
the past 25 years, and their manufacturing costs had been
declining. It was one of the worst years of financial and economic
depression in the history of the country. On June 23, 1931,
Reynolds, without previous notification or warning to the trade or
public, raised the list price of Camel cigarettes, constituting its
leading cigarette brand, from $6.40 to $6.85 a thousand. The same
day, American increased the list price for Lucky Strike cigarettes,
its leading brand, and Liggett the price for Chesterfield
cigarettes, its leading brand, to the identical price of $6.85 a
thousand. No economic justification for this raise was
demonstrated. The president of Reynolds stated that it was "to
express our own courage for the future and our own confidence in
our industry." The president of American gave as his reason for the
increase, "the opportunity of making some money." He further
claimed that, because Reynolds had raised its list price, Reynolds
would therefore have additional funds for advertising, and American
had raised its price in order to have a similar amount for
advertising. The officials of Liggett claimed that they thought the
increase was a mistake, as there did not seem to be any reason for
making a price advance, but they contended that, unless they also
raised their list price for Chesterfields, the other companies
would have greater resources to spend in advertising, and thus
would put Chesterfield cigarettes at a competitive disadvantage.
This general price increase soon resulted in higher retail prices
and in a loss in volume of sales. Yet, in 1932, in the midst of the
national depression, with the sales of the petitioners' cigarettes
falling off greatly in number, the
Page 328 U. S. 806
petitioners still were making tremendous profits as a result of
the price increase. Their net profits in that year amounted to more
than $100,000,000. This was one of the three biggest years in their
history.
Before 1931, certain smaller companies had manufactured
cigarettes retailing at 10 cents a package, which was several cents
lower than the retail price for the leading brands of the
petitioners. Up to that time, the sales of the 10-cent cigarettes
were negligible. However, after the above described increase in
list prices of the petitioners in 1931, the 10-cent brands made
serious inroads upon the sales of the petitioners. These cheaper
brands of cigarettes were sold at a list price of $4.75 a thousand,
and, from 1931 to 1932, the sales of these cigarettes multiplied 30
times, rising from O.28% of the total cigarette sales of the
country in June, 1931, to 22.78% in November, 1932. In response to
this threat of competition from the manufacturers of the 10-cent
brands, the petitioners, in January, 1933, cut the list price of
their three leading brands from $6.85 to $6 a thousand. In
February, they cut again to $5.50 a thousand. The evidence tends to
show that this cut was directed at the competition of the 10-cent
cigarettes. Reports that previously had been sent in by various
officials and representatives to their companies told of the
petitioners' brands losing in competition with the 10-cent brands.
The petitioners were interested in a sufficiently low retail price
for their products so that they would defeat the threat from the
lower priced cigarettes, and found that, in order to succeed in
their objective, it was necessary that there be not more than a
3-cent differential on each package at retail between the cheaper
cigarettes and their own brands. The petitioners' cuts in their
list prices and the subsequent reductions in the retail prices of
their products resulted in a victory over the 10-cent brands. The
letters of petitioners' representatives to their companies reported
upon the progress of
Page 328 U. S. 807
this battle, giving an account of the decline in sales of the
10-cent brands because of the price reductions in the "15-cent
brands," and prophesying that certain of the 10-cent brands would
"pass out of the picture." Following the first price cut by
petitioners, the sales of the 10-cent brands fell off considerably.
After the second cut, they fell off to a much greater extent. When
the sale of the 10-cent brands had dropped from 22.78% of the total
cigarette sales in November, 1932, to 6.43% in May, 1933, the
petitioners, in January, 1934, raised the list price of their
leading brands from $5.50 back up to $6.10 a thousand. During the
period that the list price of $5.50 a thousand was in effect,
Camels and Lucky Strikes were being sold at a loss by Reynolds and
American. Liggett at the same time was forced to curtail all of its
normal business activities and cut its advertising to the bone in
order to sell at this price. The petitioners, in 1937, again
increased the list prices of their above named brands to $6.25 a
thousand and in July, 1940, to $6.53 a thousand.
Certain methods used by the petitioners to secure a reduction in
the retail prices of their cigarettes were in evidence. Reynolds
and Liggett required their retailers to price the 10-cent brands at
a differential of not more than 3 cents below Camel and
Chesterfield cigarettes. They insisted upon their dealers
correcting a greater differential by increasing the retail price of
the 10-cent brands to 11 cents with petitioners' brands at 14 cents
a package, or by requiring that petitioners' brands be priced at 13
cents with the lower priced cigarettes at 10-cents a package.
Salesmen for Liggett were instructed to narrow the differential to
3 cents, it being deemed of no consequence whether the dealer
raised the price of the 10-cent brands or reduced the price of
Chesterfields. Reynolds referred to a differential of more than 3
cents as "discriminatory" on the ground that the dealer then
Page 328 U. S. 808
would make a higher gross profit on the higher priced cigarettes
than on the 10-cent brands. After the list price reductions were
made and at the height of the price war, the petitioners commenced
the distribution of posters, advertising their brands at 10-cents a
package, and made attempts to have dealers meet these prices. Among
the efforts used to achieve their objectives, petitioners gave
dealers direct list privileges of purchase, together with
discounts, poster advertising displays, cash subsidies, and free
goods. In addition to the use of these inducements, petitioners
also used threats and penalties to enforce compliance with their
retail price program, removed dealers from the direct lists,
cancelled arrangements for window advertising, changed credit terms
with a resulting handicap to recalcitrant dealers, discontinued
cash allowances for advertising, refused to make deals giving free
goods, and made use of price-cutters to whom they granted
advantageous privileges to drive down retail prices where a parity,
or price equalization, was not maintained by dealers between brands
of petitioners or where the dealers refused to maintain the 3 cent
differential between the 10-cent brands and the leading brands of
petitioners' cigarettes. There was evidence that, when dealers
received an announcement of the price increase from one of the
petitioners and attempted to purchase some of the leading brands of
cigarettes from the other petitioners at their unchanged prices
before announcement of a similar change, the latter refused to fill
such orders until their prices were also raised, thus bringing
about the same result as if the changes had been precisely
simultaneous.
III
It was on the basis of such evidence that the Circuit Court of
Appeals found that the verdicts of the jury were sustained by
sufficient evidence on each count. The question squarely presented
here by the order of this
Page 328 U. S. 809
Court in allowing the writs of certiorari is whether actual
exclusion of competitors is necessary to the crime of
monopolization in these cases under § 2 of the Sherman Act. We
agree with the lower courts that such actual exclusion of
competitors is not necessary to that crime in these cases, and that
the instructions given to the jury, and hereinbefore quoted,
correctly defines the crime. A correct interpretation of the
statute and of the authorities makes it the crime of monopolizing,
under § 2 of the Sherman Act, for parties, as in these cases,
to combine or conspire to acquire or maintain the power to exclude
competitors from any part of the trade or commerce among the
several states or with foreign nations, provided they also have
such a power that they are able, as a group, to exclude actual or
potential competition from the field and provided that they have
the intent and purpose to exercise that power.
See United
States v. Socony-Vacuum Oil Co., 310 U.
S. 150,
310 U. S. 226,
n. 59, and authorities cited.
It is not the form of the combination or the particular means
used, but the result to be achieved, that the statute condemns. It
is not of importance whether the means used to accomplish the
unlawful objective are, in themselves, lawful or unlawful. Acts
done to give effect to the conspiracy may be, in themselves, wholly
innocent acts. Yet, if they are part of the sum of the acts which
are relied upon to effectuate the conspiracy which the statute
forbids, they come within its prohibition. No formal agreement is
necessary to constitute an unlawful conspiracy. Often, crimes are a
matter of inference deduced from the acts of the person accused and
done in pursuance of a criminal purpose. Where the conspiracy is
proved, as here, from the evidence of the action taken in concert
by the parties to it, it is all the more convincing proof of an
intent to exercise the power of exclusion acquired through that
conspiracy. The essential combination or conspiracy in violation of
the Sherman Act may be found in a course
Page 328 U. S. 810
of dealings or other circumstances as well as in any exchange of
words.
United States v. Schrader's Son, 252 U. S.
85. Where the circumstances are such as to warrant a
jury in finding that the conspirators had a unity of purpose or a
common design and understanding, or a meeting of minds in an
unlawful arrangement, the conclusion that a conspiracy is
established is justified. Neither proof of exertion of the power to
exclude nor proof of actual exclusion of existing or potential
competitors is essential to sustain a charge of monopolization
under the Sherman Act.
In
Apex Hosiery Co. v. Leader, 310 U.
S. 469,
310 U. S. 496,
this Court said in a footnote,
"On finding . . . a power to control the output, supply of the
market and the transportation facilities of potential competitors,
in the anthracite coal market, the arrangement was held void in
United States v. Reading Co., 253 U. S.
26,
253 U. S. 47-48."
It has been held that, regardless of the use made of it, a power
resulting from the deliberately calculated purchase of a control
which enables a holding company to dominate two great competing
interstate railroad carriers and two great competing coal companies
engaged extensively in mining and selling anthracite coal which
must be distributed over these railroads is a menace and an undue
restraint upon interstate commerce within the meaning of the
Anti-Trust Act, and is in flagrant violation of the prohibition
against monopoly in the Second Section of that Act.
United
States v. Reading Co., 253 U. S. 26. In
Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.
S. 197, in referring to the holding company device there
in issue, this Court said that the mere existence of such a
combination and the power acquired by the holding company as its
trustee constituted a menace to, and a direct restraint upon, that
freedom of commerce which Congress intended to recognize and
protect, and which the public is entitled to have
Page 328 U. S. 811
protected. A combination may be one in restraint of interstate
trade or commerce or to monopolize a part of such trade or commerce
in violation of the Sherman Act although such restraint or monopoly
may not have been actually attempted to any harmful extent.
See
United States v. International Harvester Co., 214 F. 987;
id., 274 U. S. 274 U.S.
693. The authorities support the view that the material
consideration in determining whether a monopoly exists is not that
prices are raised and that competition actually is excluded, but
that power exists to raise prices or to exclude competition when it
is desired to do so.
United States v. American Tobacco
Co., 164 F. 700, 721, remanded for further proceedings,
221 U. S. 221 U.S.
106,
221 U. S.
188.
"It is undoubtedly true . . . that trade and commerce are
'monopolized' within the meaning of the federal statute when, as a
result of efforts to that end, such power is obtained that a few
persons, acting together, can control the prices of a commodity
moving in interstate commerce. It is not necessary that the power
thus obtained should be exercised. Its existence is
sufficient."
United States v. Patten, 187 F. 664, 672,
reversed
on other grounds, 226 U. S. 226 U.S.
525.
Cf. North American Co. v. SEC, 327 U.
S. 686.
The precise question before us has not been decided previously
by this Court. However, on March 12, 1945, two weeks before the
grant of the writs of certiorari in the present cases, a decision
rendered in a suit in equity brought under §§ 1 and 2 of
the Sherman Anti-Trust Act against the Aluminum Company of America
closely approached the issue we have here. That case was decided by
the Circuit Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit under unique
circumstances which add to its weight as a precedent.
United
States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d 416. That court
sat in that case under a new statute authorizing it to render a
decision "in lieu of a
Page 328 U. S. 812
decision by the Supreme Court," and providing that such decision
"shall be final, and there shall be no review of such decision by
appeal or certiorari or otherwise." [
Footnote 10]
Page 328 U. S. 813
We find the following statements from the opinion of the court
in that case to be especially appropriate here, and we welcome this
opportunity to endorse them:
"Many people believe that possession of unchallenged economic
power deadens initiative, discourages thrift, and depresses energy;
that immunity from competition is a narcotic, and rivalry is a
stimulant, to industrial progress; that the spur of constant stress
is necessary to counteract an inevitable disposition to let well
enough alone. . . . These considerations, which we have suggested
only as possible purposes of the Act, we think the decisions prove
to have been in fact its purposes. [148 F.2d at 427.]"
"
* * * *"
"Starting, however, with the authoritative premise that all
contracts fixing prices are unconditionally prohibited, the only
possible difference between them and a monopoly is that, while a
monopoly necessarily involves an equal or even greater power to fix
prices, its mere existence might be thought not to constitute an
exercise of that power. That distinction is nevertheless purely
formal; it would be valid only so long as the monopoly remained
wholly inert; it would disappear as soon as the monopoly began to
operate, for, when it did -- that is, as soon as it began to sell
at all -- it must sell at some price, and the only price at which
it could sell is a price which it itself fixed. Thereafter, the
power and its exercise must needs coalesce. Indeed, it would be
absurd to condemn such contracts unconditionally and not to extend
the condemnation to monopolies, for the contracts are only steps
toward that entire control which monopoly confers; they are really
partial monopolies. [
Id., 148 F.2d at 427, 428.]"
"
* * * *"
"It does not follow, because 'Alcoa' had such a monopoly, that
it 'monopolized' the ingot market; it may not have achieved
monopoly; monopoly may have been thrust upon it. If it had been a
combination of existing smelters which united the whole
industry
Page 328 U. S. 814
and controlled the production of all aluminum ingot, it would
certainly have 'monopolized' the market. In several decisions, the
Supreme Court has decreed the dissolution of such combinations
although they had engaged in no unlawful trade practices. . . . We
may start, therefore, with the premise that to have combined ninety
percent of the producers of ingot would have been to 'monopolize'
the ingot market, and, so far as concerns the public interest, in
can make no difference whether an existing competition is put an
end to or whether prospective competition is prevented. The Clayton
Act itself speaks in that alternative: 'to injure, destroy, or
prevent competition.' § 13(a). [
Id., 148 F.2d at
429.]"
"
* * * *"
"It insists that it never excluded competitors; but we can think
of no more effective exclusion than progressively to embrace each
new opportunity as it opened, and to face every newcomer with new
capacity already geared into a great organization, having the
advantage of experience, trade connections, and the elite of
personnel. Only in case we interpret 'exclusion' as limited to
manoeuvres not honestly industrial, but actuated solely by a desire
to prevent competition, can such a course, indefatigably pursued,
be deemed not 'exclusionary.' So to limit it would, in our
judgment, emasculate the Act -- would permit just such
consolidations as it was designed to prevent. [
Id., 148
F.2d at 431.]"
"
* * * *"
"In order to fall within § 2, the monopolist must have both
the power to monopolize and the intent to monopolize. To read the
passage as demanding any 'specific' intent makes nonsense of it,
for no monopolist monopolizes unconscious of what he is doing.
[
Id., 148 F.2d at 432.]"
In the present cases, the petitioners have been found to have
conspired to establish a monopoly, and also to have the power and
intent to establish and maintain the monopoly.
Page 328 U. S. 815
To hold that they do not come within the prohibition of the
Sherman Act would destroy the force of that Act. Accordingly, the
instructions of the trial court under § 2 of the Act are
approved, and the judgment of the Circuit Court of Appeals is
Affirmed. [
Footnote
11]
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER entirely agrees with the judgment and
the opinion in these cases. He, however, would have enlarged the
scope of the orders allowing the petitions for certiorari so as to
permit consideration of the alleged errors in regard to the
selection of the jury.
MR. JUSTICE REED and MR. JUSTICE JACKSON took no part in the
consideration or decision of these cases.
* Together with No.19,
Liggett & Myers Tobacco Co. et
al. v. United States, and No. 20,
R. J. Reynolds Tobacco
Co. et al. v. United States, on certiorari to the same court,
argued and decided on the same dates.
[
Footnote 1]
Here referred to as American, Liggett, and Reynolds.
[
Footnote 2]
"SEC. 2. Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to
monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or
persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the
several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of
a misdemeanor, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by
fine not exceeding $5,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding one
year, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the
court."
26 Stat. 209, 15 U.S.C. § 2.
[
Footnote 3]
The second count included particularly the following:
"Before and during the period of three years next preceding the
filing of this information, . . . defendants, . . . well knowing
the foregoing facts, have, . . . unlawfully monopolized the
aforesaid interstate and foreign trade and commerce in tobacco, in
violation of Section Two of the Act of Congress of July 2, 1890, .
. ."
"
* * * * "
"In adopting and exercising such methods, means, and practices,
each defendant has acted with full knowledge that unanimity of
action with reference thereto was and would be the policy, intent,
and practice of the others, that such unanimity of action would
necessarily result in drawing to defendant major tobacco companies
as a group the power to dominate, control, and exclude others from
the aforesaid interstate and foreign trade and commerce, has
intended such result, and such result has in fact been
achieved."
"Said unlawful monopolization has had the effects, among others,
of permitting a few companies to attain control of a bottleneck in
a great industry, through which a major farm commodity, on which
several million are dependent, must pass on its way through the
hands of jobbers and retailers, to the many millions of people who
use tobacco products; of enabling these few companies to abuse
their resulting strategic and dominant position by making the
income of growers of leaf tobacco lower than it otherwise would
have been, by making the income of distributors and other
manufacturers of tobacco products lower than it otherwise would
have been, and by keeping from all other groups in the industry,
and from consumers, the benefits which otherwise would flow from
free, vigorous and normal competition."
[
Footnote 4]
The verdict in a criminal case is sustained only when there is
"relevant evidence from which the jury could properly find or
infer, beyond a reasonable doubt," that the accused is guilty.
Mortensen v. United States, 322 U.
S. 369,
322 U. S.
374.
[
Footnote 5]
" . . . nor shall any person be subject for the same offense to
be twice put in jeopardy of life or limb. . . ."
[
Footnote 6]
"No person shall be prosecuted, tried, or punished for any
offense, not capital, . . . unless the indictment is found, or the
information is instituted, within three years next after such
offense shall have been committed. . . ."
Rev.Stat. § 1044, as amended by 45 Stat. 51, 18 U.S.C.
§ 582.
[
Footnote 7]
The history of the tobacco industry in America and of the
litigation which resulted in the dissolution of the tobacco trust
in 1911 is set forth in
United States v. American Tobacco
Co., 221 U.S.
221 U. S. 106-193.
See also United States v. American Tobacco Co., 191 F.
371-431, containing the decree of dissolution
and see 164
F. 700-728;
id., 164 F. 1024, for the report of the case
in the Circuit Court. While the names of some of the parties in the
earlier case are those of the present petitioners, the present
proceedings do not reflect a failure on their part to observe the
requirements of the 1911 decree. Although the decree of dissolution
resulted in the separation of assets among the American, Liggett,
and Reynolds companies, as well as P. Lorillard Company and others,
there is no contention here that common ownership of stock and the
interlocking of officers and directors among those companies have
continued to exist. The tobacco industry also has changed from one
dealing primarily in the distribution of smoking tobacco, chewing
tobacco, little cigars, and cigarettes to one dealing primarily in
cigarettes. The record shows that, in 1910, the weight of the
tobacco used in the domestic manufacture of cigarettes was about
31,000,000 pounds out of 522,000,000 pounds, or less than 6%,
whereas, in 1939, it was 509,000,000 pounds out of 885,000,000
pounds, or 57.5%.
"By the 1911 decree, the cigarette brands of the trust were
distributed as follows: to American: Sweet Caporal, Pall Mall,
Hassan and Mecca. To Liggett: American Beauty, Fatima, Piedmont,
Imperiales, Home Run, and King Bee. To P. Lorillard Company:
Helman, Murad, Mogul, Turkish Trophies, and Egyptian Deities.
Neither the old trust nor the petitioners in the present cases have
ever done much general cigar business. Reynolds in 1911 had no
cigarette business, and it received none by the decree. It then was
small in comparison with the other companies named. In 1913, it put
its Camel cigarettes on the market. These were neither Turkish,
Pseudo-Turkish, nor Virginia cigarettes. They were made largely of
burley tobacco which had not been used in any successful cigarette
up to that time. They were 'cased' or flavored -- an old process in
preparing plug tobacco but an innovation in cigarettes. That
competition was highly successful. Reynolds' sales rose to where,
in 1919, it made about 40% of all domestic cigarette sales in the
United States. By 1917, its total production exceeded by 50% the
total national production of cigarettes in 1911. In 1916, American
launched a new brand of burley cigarettes -- Lucky Strikes. Liggett
changed its Chesterfield brand from a Virginia-type cigarette to a
burley blend. Lorillard, in 1926, launched a new brand of Old Gold
cigarettes. By that time, the 'Big Three' were American, Liggett,
and Reynolds, and those companies are the three cigarette producing
companies that are parties to the present proceedings."
[
Footnote 8]
The identity of the parties referred to in the present cases is
more readily recognizable when they are identified with their
products as follows:
American -- Lucky Strike, Pall Mall (by a subsidiary), Herbert
Tareytown cigarettes, Bull Durham tobacco, about 50 brands of
chewing tobacco, and hundreds of brands of smoking tobacco.
Liggett -- Chesterfield and about 15 other brands of cigarettes,
45 brands of smoking tobacco, including Velvet and Duke's Mixture,
and over 25 brands of chewing tobacco.
Reynolds -- Camel cigarettes, 12 brands of smoking tobacco,
including Prince Albert, and 88 brands of chewing tobacco.
P. Lorillard Company -- Old Gold, and Sensation cigarettes, as
well as other tobacco products.
Philip Morris & Co., Ltd. -- Philip Morris, and Paul Jones
cigarettes.
British-American Tobacco Company, Limited -- Many tobacco
products, including those of its subsidiary, Brown & Williamson
Tobacco Corporation.
Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corporation -- Raleigh
cigarettes.
The Imperial Tobacco Company, Ltd. -- Tobacco products sold in
Great Britain and Ireland.
Universal Leaf Tobacco Company, Inc. -- Dealers in leaf
tobacco.
Stephano Brothers, Axton-Fisher Tobacco Company and Larus Bro.
Co., Inc., are all producers of the so-called "10 cent cigarettes."
Their cigarettes, like certain comparable cigarettes produced by P.
Lorillard Company and by Philip Morris & Co., Ltd.,
Incorporated, generally sell for 10 cents a package, in contrast to
13 or 15 cents or more for the leading brands of burley blend
cigarettes.
[
Footnote 9]
For a description of auction methods of selling in Georgia,
see Townsend v. Yeomans, 301 U. S. 441,
301 U. S. 445,
and in North Carolina,
see Currin v. Wallace, 306 U. S.
1,
306 U. S. 7-8.
See also market practices described in the report of the
Committee on Agriculture of the House of Representatives, June 5,
1935, to accompany H.R. 826. H.Rep. No.1102, 74th Cong., 1st
Sess.
[
Footnote 10]
"In every suit in equity brought in any district court of the
United States under any of said Acts [including the Sherman
Anti-Trust Act], wherein the United States is complainant, an
appeal from the final decree of the district court will lie only to
the Supreme Court, and must be taken within sixty days from the
entry thereof:
Provided, however, That if, upon any such
appeal, it shall be found that, by reason of disqualification,
there shall not be a quorum of Justices of the Supreme Court
qualified to participate in the consideration of the case on the
merits, then, in lieu of a decision by the Supreme Court, the case
shall be immediately certified by the Supreme Court to the circuit
court of appeals of the circuit in which is located the district in
which the suit was brought which court shall thereupon have
jurisdiction to hear and determine the appeal in such case, and it
shall be the duty of the senior circuit judge of said circuit court
of appeals, qualified to participate in the consideration of the
case on the merits, to designate immediately three circuit judges
of said court, one of whom shall be himself and the other two of
whom shall be the two circuit judges next in order of seniority to
himself, to hear and determine the appeal in such case, and it
shall be the duty of the court, so comprised, to assign the case
for argument at the earliest practicable date and to hear and
determine the same, and the decision of the three circuit judges so
designated, or of a majority in number thereof, shall be final, and
there shall be no review of such decision by appeal or certiorari
or otherwise. . . ."
32 Stat. 823, as amended by 58 Stat. 272, 15 U.S.C.Supp.IV,
§ 29.
The proviso in the above section was added by Public Law 332,
78th Cong., 2d Sess., approved June 9, 1944, which also made the
Act applicable "to every case pending before the Supreme Court of
the United States on the date of its enactment." 58 Stat. 272. The
case against the Aluminum Company of America was then pending in
this Court, and, on June 12, 1944, this Court certified it to the
Circuit Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit because of the lack
of a quorum of Justices of the Supreme Court qualified to
participate in the consideration of it on its merits. It was tried
before the three senior judges of the Circuit Court of Appeals
(Judges Learned Hand, Swan, and Augustus N. Hand), and is the only
case that has been tried under that proviso.
[
Footnote 11]
Upon suggestion of the death of Edward H. Thurston, a petitioner
in Case No.19, a motion to dismiss the writ of certiorari as to him
was granted by the Court on February 11, 1946, 327 U.S. 764. It
remains for the Circuit Court of Appeals and the District Court of
the United States for the Eastern District of Kentucky to take such
further action as law and justice may require.
See Singer v.
United States, 323 U. S. 338,
323 U. S. 346;
United States v. Johnson, 319 U.
S. 503,
319 U. S.
520.
MR. JUSTICE RUTLEDGE, concurring.
I concur in the Court's opinion and judgment. In doing so,
however, I express no judgment concerning other questions
determined on the appeal to the Circuit Court of Appeals, 147 F.2d
93, and presented in the application for certiorari or the later
petition for rehearing and enlargement of the scope of review here,
including the question whether, upon the particular facts, the law
has been applied in such a manner as to bring about, in substantial
effect, multiple punishment for the same offense.
Cf. Pinkerton
v. United States, ante, pp.
328 U. S. 640,
328 U. S. 648,
dissenting opinion.
Page 328 U. S. 816
That question has been discussed in the briefs and the argument,
for its bearing upon the disposition of the single question which
certiorari was granted to review -- namely, "whether actual
exclusion of competitors is necessary to the crime of
monopolization under Section 2 of the Sherman Act." 324 U.S. 836.
On this issue, I have no doubt of the correctness of the Court's
conclusion that the offense of monopolization is complete when
power is acquired to exclude competitors, and therefore that actual
exclusion need not be shown, for the reasons set forth in the
opinion. Whether, in this view, multiple punishment may arise upon
application of the law to particular facts under counts charging
conspiracy in restraint of trade, monopolization, and conspiracy to
monopolize presents a different question which can be determined
only by examination of the manner in which the particular
application has been made. Since, in view of the limited character
of our action in granting certiorari, neither the issue of multiple
punishment nor the facts of record upon which it arises are before
us for review, it would be inappropriate to express opinion on that
question.