1. The proper rate at which the currency of the invoice of the
imported goods here involved should have been converted into United
States dollars under § 522(c) of the Tariff Act of 1930 was
the "free" rate, and not the "official" rate. Pp.
324 U. S. 84,
324 U. S.
94.
2. Section 522(c) is not to be construed as authorizing
certification by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or
proclamation by the Secretary of the Treasury of only one buying
rate for a specified foreign currency. P.
324 U. S.
89.
3. Where, under § 522(c), dual buying rates have been
certified, that rate should be used which is in fact applicable to
the particular transaction, and the use of a rate by which the cost
of the goods will be distorted and an inflated value for customs
purposes placed upon them should be avoided. P.
324 U. S.
90.
4. The result here reached is not inconsistent with provisions
of § 402 of the Act, which require that the value of imported
merchandise shall be the "foreign value or the export value,
whichever is higher." P.
324 U. S.
92.
5. The general authority of the Secretary of the Treasury over
the collection of duties on imports and over collectors of customs,
and his authority under § 624 of the Tariff Act of 1930 to
make rules and regulations for carrying out the provisions of the
Act, cannot detract from the express authority of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York under § 522(c) to determine and
certify the buying rate. P.
324 U. S.
92.
6. The function of the Secretary of the Treasury under §
522(c) in respect of the publishing of the rates certified by the
Bank is purely ministerial. P.
324 U. S.
94.
7. The action of the Secretary of the Treasury in publishing
only one of the rates certified by the Bank, and the decision of
the collector pursuant thereto, were subject to judicial review. P.
324 U. S.
94.
8. As to the contention that confusion and complexity in
administration of the Tariff Act will result if more than one
buying rate may be made applicable to imports from one country, the
showing would have to be far more clear than it is here, and the
meaning
Page 324 U. S. 84
of the Act much more dubious, in order that those administrative
considerations should be given weight in the interpretative
process. P.
324 U. S.
94.
143 F.2d 132, reversed.
Certiorari, 323 U.S. 689, to review the reversal of a judgment
of the Customs Court which sustained a protest of a decision of the
collector of customs.
MR. JUSTICE DOUGLAS delivered the opinion of the Court.
The question in this case is the proper rate at which the
currency of the invoice of imported goods should be converted into
United States dollars under § 522(c) of the Tariff Act of
1930. 46 Stat. 739, 31 U.S.C. § 372(c).
On May 13, 1940, petitioner imported into the United States at
the port of New York certain woolen fabrics which had been exported
from England on May 3, 1940. Payment for the merchandise was made
with pounds sterling purchased through the Guaranty Trust Co. of
New York in the New York market for cable transfer. The Collector
of Customs converted the pounds sterling of the invoice into
dollars at the "official" rate of exchange of $4,035. Petitioner
claimed that the currency of his invoice should have been converted
at the "free" rate of exchange of $3.475138. He paid the higher
rate and filed his protest against the Collector's action under
§ 514
Page 324 U. S. 85
of the Tariff Act of 1930. The Customs Court sustained the
protest. 79 Treas.Dec., No. 7, 14. The Court of Customs and Patent
Appeals reversed. 143 F.2d 132. The case is here on a petition for
a writ of certiorari which we granted because of the importance of
the questions presented.
The "free" rate and the "official" rate have the following
origin.
Sec. 522(a) of the Tariff Act provides that the value of foreign
coin as expressed in the money of account of the United States
shall be that of the pure metal of such coin of standard value, and
that it shall be estimated quarterly by the Director of the Mint
and proclaimed by the Secretary of the Treasury. The value of the
pound sterling at all times relevant here was proclaimed to be
$8.2397. Sec. 522(b) provides that, for the purpose of assessment
and collection of duties upon merchandise imported into the United
States, foreign currency shall be converted, wherever necessary,
into currency of the United States at the values proclaimed by the
Secretary under § 522(a) for the quarter in which the
merchandise was exported. Sec. 522(b) provides, however, for an
exception. That exception is contained in § 5522(c), which
reads as follows:
"If no such value has been proclaimed, or if the value so
proclaimed varies by 5 percentum or more from a value measured by
the buying rate in the New York market at noon on the day of
exportation, conversion shall be made at a value measured by such
buying rate. If the date of exportation falls upon a Sunday or
holiday, then the buying rate at noon on the last preceding
business day shall be used. For the purposes of this subdivision,
such buying rate shall be the buying rate for cable transfers
payable in the foreign currency so to be converted, and shall be
determined by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and certified
daily to the Secretary of the Treasury, who
Page 324 U. S. 86
shall make it public at such times and to such extent as he
deems necessary. In ascertaining such buying rate, such Federal
reserve bank may, in its discretion, (1) take into consideration
the last ascertainable transactions and quotations, whether direct
or through exchange of other currencies, and (2) if there is no
market buying rate for such cable transfers, calculate such rate
from actual transactions and quotations in demand or time bills of
exchange."
At all times prior to March 25, 1940, the Federal Reserve Bank
of New York, pursuant to its authority under § 522(c),
certified daily to the Secretary of the Treasury one buying rate
for the pound sterling. When the present war between Great Britain
and Germany was declared, the British Government inaugurated a
detailed system for controlling foreign exchange. It required,
among other things, that all persons resident in the United Kingdom
sell to the British Treasury at prices fixed by it all foreign
currency which they were entitled to sell, and prohibited, with
certain exceptions, exportation of foreign currency from the United
Kingdom and the purchase and sale of foreign currency in the United
Kingdom from or to any person other than an authorized dealer and
at prices fixed by the British Treasury. On March 7, 1940, an Order
in Council, effective March 25, 1940, was issued by the British
Government, which provided that certain classes of merchandise
[
Footnote 1] (whiskey, furs,
tin, rubber and jute) might not be exported from the United Kingdom
to the United States and certain other countries except when
payment had been or would be made to persons resident in the United
Kingdom in specified currencies. These currencies included United
States dollars or English pounds purchased
Page 324 U. S. 87
in the United Kingdom after September 3, 1939, from an
authorized dealer in foreign currency. Authorized dealers sold
English pounds only at the rate of $4.035, prescribed by the
British Treasury, from January 8, 1940, to September 30, 1942, when
the present case was tried.
On March 19, 1940, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York notified
the Secretary that, because of the order of the British Government
of March 7, 1940, it would certify, beginning March 25, 1940, two
rates for the pound sterling -- one to be designated as the "free"
rate, the other as the "official" rate. The latter was the rate
fixed by the British Treasury. On April 15, 1940, the Secretary of
the Treasury notified the collectors of customs that, until further
notice he would publish only the "official" rate, and he directed
them to use that rate for assessing and collecting duties on
imported merchandise whenever it varied by more than 50 percent
from the value of the pound proclaimed by the Secretary under
§ 522(a) of the Act. [
Footnote
2] T.D. 50134, 75 Treas.Dec. 370, 371, 5 Fed.Reg. 1447.
On the date petitioner exported his merchandise from England,
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York certified to the Secretary of
the Treasury that at noon on that day the "free" rate for the
English pound was $3.475138, and the "official" rate was $4.035.
The Secretary, in accordance with his notification of April 15,
1940, to the collectors of customs published only the "official"
rate. T.D. 50146, 75 Treas.Dec. 388. Since the "official" rate
varied by more than 5 percent from the proclaimed value of the
pound for that quarter, the collector used the "official" rate in
converting pounds into dollars for the purpose of assessing and
collecting duties upon the value of the
Page 324 U. S. 88
woolen fabrics. The pounds sterling which petitioner used in the
purchase of the woolens were not obtained from an authorized dealer
as defined in the British order of March 7, 1940, but, as we have
noted, through the Guaranty Trust Co. of New York in the New York
market for cable transfer. Petitioner claims that the invoice
currency should have been converted at the "free" rate of $3.475138
as determined and certified by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
for the date of this exportation.
It was noted in
United States v. Whitridge,
197 U. S. 135,
197 U. S. 142,
that the assessment of an
ad valorem tax on imports
involved an ascertainment of the true value of the article taxed as
of the date of the tax, and that the invoice price was an
approximate measurement of that value. As pointed out in that case,
the history of the statute shows a closer approximation to that
value as the legislation has evolved. And the enactments made
subsequent to the decision in the
Whitridge case are
consistent with that trend. In the beginning, Congress prescribed
specific dollar values of specified coins. Act of July 31, 1789,
§ 18, 1 Stat. 29, 41. Not long after, the President was given
authority to prescribe regulations for computing duties on imports
where the original cost was exhibited in a depreciated currency of
a foreign government. Act of March 2, 1799, § 61, 1 Stat. 627,
673. In 1873, Congress provided for an annual estimate by the
Director of the Mint of the full metal value of standard coins of
the various nations and a proclamation of the value by the
Secretary of the Treasury. Act of March 3, 1873, 17 Stat. 602. That
estimate was required to be made quarterly, rather than annually,
by the Act of October 1, 1890, § 52, 26 Stat. 567, 624. Then
came the Act of August 27, 1894, § 25, 28 Stat. 508, 552,
which retained the provision for the estimate and proclamation of
metallic values and gave the Secretary of the Treasury power to
order a reliquidation at a different value on a showing that the
value of the
Page 324 U. S. 89
invoice currency in United States currency was 10 percent more
or less than the proclaimed value.
United States v. Whitridge,
supra. The procedure under the latter provision depended on a
consular certificate to establish the percentage of depreciation of
the currency. T.D. No. 23725, 5 Treas.Dec. 396. There was thus no
single source (and none at all in the United States) to which
customs officials could look to determine the extent to which
foreign currency had depreciated. Moreover, violent fluctuations in
foreign exchange rates had occurred after the first World War. It
was for those reasons that § 403(c) was added to the Emergency
Tariff Act of 1921, 42 Stat. 9, 17.
See S.Rep. No. 16,
67th Cong., 1st Sess., p. 16; H.Rep. No. 79, 67th Cong., 1st Sess.,
p. 12;
Fry & Friedsam v. United States, 12 Cust.App.
486, 489. And § 403(c) of the 1921 Act now appears as §
522(c) of the 1930 Act, on whose meaning the present decision
turns.
This history makes clear the search which has been made for a
measure of the true dollar values of imported merchandise for
customs purposes which was accurate (
see Cramer v. Arthur,
102 U. S. 612,
102 U. S.
617), and, at the same time, administratively feasible
and efficient. The formula finally selected is dependent on the
actual value of the foreign currency in our own money. The rate for
the foreign exchange with which the imported goods are purchased is
recognized as the measure of value of the foreign currency; the use
of that rate reflects values in United States currency which are
deemed sufficiently accurate to serve as the measure of the
valuation of the goods for purposes of the
ad valorem tax.
As noted in
United States v. Whitridge, supra, p.
197 U. S. 144,
the actual "unit of cost" conforms with the truth and the meaning
of the invoice.
We would depart from that scheme if we read § 522(c) as
saying that, on a given date, only one buying rate for a specified
foreign currency could be certified by the Federal
Page 324 U. S. 90
Reserve Bank of New York or proclaimed by the Secretary of the
Treasury. Dual or multiple exchange rates have resulted in recent
years from measures for the control and restriction of foreign
exchange and export transactions. [
Footnote 3] In the present case, the British Government
fixed the "official" rate for the purchase of specified commodities
for export. One who purchased woolens for export need not acquire
pounds at that rate. A lower rate was available, and was indeed
taken advantage of by petitioner when he purchased pounds to pay
for the woolens. If the higher "official" rate is used in the
valuation of the woolens, the cost of the goods will be distorted
and an inflated value for customs purposes will be placed upon
them. Such a result would be quite out of harmony with the history
of these statutes, and should be avoided unless the result is
plainly required by the language of § 522(c). We do not think
it is.
We may assume that the dual or multiple exchange rates which
have emerged were not in contemplation when the 1930 Act was
passed. As we have noted, they are parts of rather recent measures
for the control and restriction of foreign exchange and export
transactions. But if Congress has made a choice of language which
fairly brings a given situation within a statute, it is unimportant
that the particular application may not have been contemplated by
the legislators.
Puerto Rico v. Shell Co., 302 U.
S. 253,
302 U. S. 257;
Browder v. United States, 312 U.
S. 335,
312 U. S. 339,
and cases cited. Sec. 522(c) contains no language indicating that
the Secretary of the Treasury has any function to perform except
the publication of any buying
Page 324 U. S. 91
rate which is certified. The determination of the rate is left
exclusively to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. It alone is
given discretion in computing it. The duty of the Secretary to
publish the certified rate is as clear as the duty of the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York to determine and certify it. It is true
that § 522(c) speaks only of the "buying rate." And that use
of the singular, rather than the plural, is stressed by respondent.
We may note, however, in passing that § 1 of the Revised
Statutes, 1 U.S.C. § 1, provides that "words importing the
singular number may extend and be applied to several persons or
things." Beyond that is the fact that we are construing a provision
of a tariff act designed, as we have said, to value imports for
customs purposes by means of the buying rate of the invoice
currency. The use of the singular is not inappropriate, since there
is a buying rate for the foreign exchange used to purchase each
separate import. We assume that the "official" rate was the
all-inclusive rate, and could have been used in payment of exported
goods of all kinds. But § 522(c) means to us that that buying
rate is to be used which is in fact applicable to the particular
transaction. To look to other transactions for the buying rate is
to make a valuation of a wholly hypothetical import, not a
valuation of the actual one before the collector of customs.
Congress could, of course, choose any standard of valuation for the
purposes of the assessment and collection of duties. But Congress
in this situation endeavored to provide a flexible and realistic,
not an arbitrary, standard. We can indeed see no difference in
principle between the use of one of several rates for the currency
of a single country and the use of one of several rates, each of
which is for the currency of a different country. In each,
different rates are used to ascertain the value of specific
imports. The language of § 522(c), read against the background
of these statutes, indicates to us that Congress undertook to
provide in each case the rate which
Page 324 U. S. 92
gives the closest approximation to the value in dollars of the
imported merchandise. That purpose would be thwarted if, in the
circumstances of this case, only one buying rate could be used in
making the valuation of the goods. The application of the
"official" rate to this particular transaction would assume that
petitioner imported whiskey, furs, tin, rubber, or jute, rather
than woolens. The valuation of the woolens would be inflated, and a
higher duty would be paid than a fair reading of § 522(c)
necessitates.
It is said that this result runs counter to the provisions of
§ 402 of the Act, which require that the value of imported
merchandise shall be the "foreign value or the export value,
whichever is higher." But it is not apparent how that policy need
in any way be defeated or impaired by the use of the "free" rate of
exchange where it is in fact applicable.
Reliance for the other conclusion is also placed on the general
authority given the Secretary over the collection of duties on
imports [
Footnote 4] and over
collectors of customs. [
Footnote
5] It is also pointed out that § 624 of the Tariff Act of
1930 provides that,
"In addition to the specific powers conferred by this Act, the
Secretary of the Treasury is authorized to make such rules and
regulations as may be necessary to carry out the provisions of this
act. [
Footnote 6]"
But these
Page 324 U. S. 93
provisions merely implement authority which is granted the
Secretary, and make clear the existence of authority which
otherwise might be only implied. They may not be used to detract
from the express authority given the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York under § 522(c). But this result is criticized on the
ground that it interferes with the control of foreign exchange,
which fiscal function has been entrusted to the Secretary, not to
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. It hardly need be pointed out
in reply, however, that our decision, like § 522(c), is
concerned only with the assessment and collection of duties upon
imports through the use of a formula which Congress designed. If
the use of that formula under the changed conditions of these war
years is disadvantageous or undesirable, Congress, of course, can
change it. But we cannot assume that Congress did not mean what it
said when it selected the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, rather
than the Secretary, to perform a restricted function on this single
phase of the complicated foreign exchange problem.
Nor is there substance in the argument that the Secretary's
action in publishing only one of the rates certified by the Bank is
nonreviewable. Sec. 522(c) plainly gives discretion to the Bank to
determine the buying rate. And, for the reasons stated, we cannot
say that only one buying rate must be determined and certified.
[
Footnote 7] The exercise
of
Page 324 U. S. 94
the Bank's discretionary power under § 522(c) is in the
category of administrative or executive action which this Court
held nonreviewable in
Cramer v. Arthur, supra, and in
Hadden v. Merritt, 115 U. S. 25,
115 U. S. 27-28.
And see United States v. George S. Bush & Co.,
310 U. S. 371,
310 U. S. 380.
But the function of the Secretary in this regard is purely
ministerial, and is to be contrasted to other situations in which
the Secretary is exercising discretionary authority.
Cf. Boske
v. Comingore, 177 U. S. 459. The
power to publish the certified rate may not be exercised in such a
way as to defeat the method of assessment which Congress has
provided.
Cf. Campbell v. United States, 107 U.
S. 407. Congress has granted judicial review of the
decisions of the collector including the legality of the orders and
findings entering into the protested decision. Secs. 514-517. If
the decision of the collector contravenes the statutory scheme and
disregards rights which Congress has bestowed, the fact that he
acts pursuant to the directions of the Secretary does not save his
decision from review.
Campbell v. United States, supra. We
think that the use of the "official" rate of exchange in assessing
and collecting duties upon these imports transcended the authority
of the collector and of the Secretary, and that the "free" rate of
exchange certified by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York should
have been used.
It is finally said that, if more than one buying rate may be
made applicable to imports from one country, [
Footnote 8] confusion
Page 324 U. S. 95
and complexity in administration of the Tariff Act will result.
But that showing would have to be far more clear, and the meaning
of the Act much more dubious, for us to give those administrative
considerations weight in the interpretative process.
Reversed.
MR. JUSTICE JACKSON took no part in the consideration or
decision of this case.
[
Footnote 1]
Subsequent to the exportation of the merchandise involved in the
present case, this Order was amended, effective June 10, 1940, to
include goods of any class or description.
[
Footnote 2]
As we have noted, the value of the pound sterling at all times
pertinent to this case was proclaimed to be $8.2397.
[
Footnote 3]
See United States Tariff Commission, Regulation of
Tariffs in Foreign Countries by Administrative Action (1934);
Twenty-second Annual Report of The United States Tariff Commission
(1938) p. 1; Southard, Foreign Exchange Practice and Policy (1940)
pp. 185
et seq.
[
Footnote 4]
"The Secretary of the Treasury shall direct the superintendence
of the collection of the duties on imports as he shall judge best."
Rev.Stat. § 249, 19 U.S.C. § 3.
And see
Rev.Stat. § 248, 5 U.S.C. § 242.
[
Footnote 5]
"The Secretary of the Treasury shall prescribe forms of entries,
oaths, bonds, and other papers, and rules and regulations not
inconsistent with law, to be used in carrying out the provisions of
law relating to raising revenue from imports, or to duties on
imports, or to warehousing, and shall give such directions to
collectors and prescribe such rules and forms to be observed by
them as may be necessary for the proper execution of the law."
Rev.Stat. § 251, 19 U.S.C. Supp. III, § 66.
And
see Rev.Stat. § 161, 5 U.S.C. § 22.
[
Footnote 6]
Sec. 502(c) of the Act provides that
"It shall be the duty of all officers of the customs to execute
and carry into effect all instructions of the Secretary of the
Treasury relative to the execution of the revenue laws, and in case
any difficulty arises as to the true construction or meaning of any
part of the revenue laws, the decision of the Secretary shall be
binding upon all officers of the customs."
[
Footnote 7]
The case is therefore different from
Collector
v. Richards, 23 Wall. 246. In that case, the
Director of the Mint certified two values of the franc -- one under
the provisions of the Act of March 2, 1873, 17 Stat. 602, the other
under the Act of May 22, 1846, 9 Stat. 14. The Director of the Mint
was uncertain whether the latter act had been repealed by the
former. The Secretary proclaimed the rate estimated by the Director
under the 1873 Act. This Court sustained a collection of duties on
that basis, holding that the provisions of the 1873 Act controlled.
Thus, the decision was that only one value of the franc controlled,
not that the power of the Secretary to proclaim the value included
the power to choose between two available ones.
[
Footnote 8]
It should be noted that, where two or more currencies of
different character circulate in a foreign country, the Treasury
has provided for the use of the foreign exchange rate for each, the
rate used being the rate for the currency in which the same or
similar merchandise is usually bought and sold in the ordinary
course of trade.
See Customs Regulations of 1937, Art.
776(a) and (e), as amended by Treas.Dec. 50251(i) and (j), October
10, 1940.
MR. JUSTICE FRANKFURTER, dissenting.
As part of the effective financial conduct of the war, the
United Kingdom brought sterling under control by fixing its
exchange value. A limited supply of sterling in foreign countries
presented a special problem. But though that supply was out of its
bounds, Great Britain, by various mechanisms, could bring it under
control. Apparently it moved to do so as quickly as economic and
political considerations permitted.
See the statement of
the Chancellor of the Exchequer on April 9, 1940, in reply to
various questions in the House of Commons, 359 H.C.Deb. (5th
ser.1940) 461-463. Thus, while "the vast bulk of transactions
between sterling and other currencies" was conducted at the
exchange rate fixed by the Government, the supply and demand of
sterling abroad created a market. By virtue of various British
restrictions, this free sterling market became increasingly thin.
See 26 Fed.Res.Bull. (July, 1940) 638; The Commercial and
Financial Chronicle, April 20, 1940, Vol. 150, Pt. 2, pp. 2478-79.
Nevertheless, until the British Government completely clamped down
on the use of this free sterling in payment of exports, it was
possible to pay for such exports in sterling purchased at a lower
rate than that which the British Government believed to be a
reflection of the true value of the pound and officially fixed at
such.
Plainly enough, a single currency having multiple values has
important bearings upon the flow of goods and
Page 324 U. S. 96
upon international economic relations. In the case of Great
Britain, the situation may not have been serious, because, as we
noted, free sterling played a relatively small share in the
economic interchange between the two countries. The "free" rate was
employed only in limited transactions, and evidently represented on
the part of Great Britain merely a transitory compromise with
circumstances. In short, the official rate was not an unreality.
But, in the case of some countries, a dual system of rates of
exchange may have a decisive economic effects through highly
organized manipulation of exchange, with all the evils that result
from confusion and from depreciated currencies.
To dispose of the case on the assumption that it merely involves
enforcement of a Congressional policy for assuring approximate
accuracy in determining the true dollar value of a particular
importation is to throw the significance of the case out of focus.
The problem, as I see it, is whether Congress, by § 522(c) of
the Tariff Act of 1930, 46 Stat. 590, 739, 31 U.S.C. § 372(c),
prohibited the Secretary of the Treasury from safeguarding the
public interest, as he did, in relation to dislocations in the
money markets following the outbreak of the war and to their
repercussions both upon our domestic economy and our international
relations. That the Treasury's instruction to the collectors of
customs to assess tariff duties on the basis of the sterling rate
fixed by the British Government was not an ordinary Treasury order
affecting the collection of revenue is attested by the fact that
the instruction was the result of a conference of the Secretary of
State, the Secretary of the Treasury, the Attorney General, and the
Secretary of Agriculture.
See New York Times, April 17,
1940, p. 4, col. 5; The Commercial and Financial Chronicle, April
20, 1940, Vol. 150, Pt. 2, pp. 2478-79.
It is not suggested that, apart from § 522(c), this
Government could not protect its interests in relation to the
Page 324 U. S. 97
abnormal currency situations precipitated by the war through
such action as the Secretary of the Treasury here took. The wide
duties of financial supervision possessed by the Secretary by
virtue of his office and the broad powers implied in various
provisions of law,
see for instance, 5 U.S.C. § 242,
19 U.S.C. § 3; § 624 of the Tariff Act of 1930, 46 Stat.
590, 759, 19 U.S.C. § 1624, and
Boske v. Comingore,
177 U. S. 459,
would give him ample warrant to fix a rate for dollar conversions
of foreign currencies on a uniform basis reflecting the dominant
value among multiple values of a foreign currency and one not
subject to manipulations or influences adverse to our
interests.
Withdrawal of this power of the Secretary of the Treasury
implies a radical curtailment of his historic and appropriate
authority to protect the nation's fiscal interests. If it chose, of
course, Congress could so curtail the Secretary's powers. But such
an important change in the executive responsibility for our fiscal
affairs ought to be disclosed through some unequivocal
Congressional expression. To find such destructive force in §
522(c) is to attribute to it a potency not designed by Congress. It
is conceded that, in the legislation which is now § 522(c),
Congress was concerned solely with fluctuations in a single
exchange rate, a problem thrown up after the First World War. And
so Congress designated the Federal Reserve Bank as a factfinding
agency to ascertain the most durable among fluctuating quotations.
But multiple rates for a single currency -- with their effects upon
the flow of goods and upon international economic relations and the
opportunities they afford for highly organized manipulations of
exchange -- present a totally different problem. That problem, as
is admitted by the Federal Reserve Bank, appearing before us as
amicus curiae, was not at all in the contemplation of
Congress. That problem was not dealt with by Congress, because it
did not confront
Page 324 U. S. 98
Congress. As a problem, it did not emerge until, in 1940, the
present war confronted the Federal Reserve Bank and the Secretary
of the Treasury with it.
The Federal Reserve Bank and the Secretary of the Treasury,
having different functions, naturally dealt with it differently.
Although, to be sure, § 522(c) charged the Federal Reserve
Bank with the ascertainment of a single exchange rate, the Bank,
naturally enough, solved the dilemma which confronted it when there
were two rates for sterling by reporting both, although the
significance of the two rates and the range of their functions
varied greatly. It was not for the Bank to pick only one rate, for
the Bank is merely a reporting agency, and not a policymaking
agency. But the determination whether one of the two rates is the
rate, and, if so, which should have that fiscal function is a
policy problem, and the Secretary of the Treasury is the agency
vested with responsibility for fiscal policies.
For the selection by the Secretary of the Treasury of an
exchange rate in a situation like the one before us has
implications far beyond translating into dollars the value at which
a particular importer actually settled for the foreign price of his
goods. The selection of the governing rate of exchange in the case
of multiple rates affects at least three very important phases of
our international economic relations. By § 402 of the Tariff
Act of 1930, 46 Stat. 590, 708, 19 U.S.C. § 1402, in the
assessment of
ad valorem duties, it is necessary to
ascertain the foreign market value, which normally means the
foreign home value. Commodities subject to the "official" rate and
commodities available through "free" sterling may well have an
identical home value, and yet, according to the contention of the
importer, one valuation would have to be reached according to
§ 522(c) and another according to § 402. Again, the
Secretary of the Treasury may impose countervailing duties whenever
he finds that imported
Page 324 U. S. 99
goods enjoy a bounty, direct or indirect. Section 303 of the
Tariff Act of 1930, 46 Stat. 590, 687, 19 U.S.C. § 1303. Such
bounties may readily take the form of favorable exchange rates. An
unwarrantably rigid denial to the Secretary of the determination of
an exchange rate which in substance corresponds to the realties of
international exchange may force him to exercise the penalizing
power of imposing countervailing duties. Finally, foreign exchange
rates affect the fruitful use of foreign trade agreements. Section
350 of the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended by 48 Stat. 943, 19
U.S.C. § 1351
et seq.
All these dangerous potentialities would, of course, be
irrelevant if Congress had dealt with the problem of multiple rates
in a rigid way and put the responsibility upon the Federal Reserve
Bank to select one of such multiple rates. But the hand of the
Government ought not to be tied too closely where, to put it
mildly, the Congressional purpose has been ambiguously expressed.
We cannot find such purpose from a reading of what Congress has
written. We are hardly justified in assuming that, if Congress had
addressed itself to this problem, it would have tied the hands of
the Secretary of the Treasury and brought into play all the
difficulties that have been indicated in the ascertainment of
foreign home value, in the imposition of countervailing duties, and
in embarrassing the policy of trade agreements. The power of
Congress to pass new legislation is hardly a reason for giving old
legislation a construction that disregards its history and its
context and the unhappy consequences of such disregard.
Of course, general condemnation of a practice covers any
specific manifestation of it, even though the latter was
"unforeseen" by Congress,
Puerto Rico v. Shell Co.,
302 U. S. 253,
just as a general outlawry of the use of a false document hits also
a use to which the document was not "ordinarily" put when the
legislation was passed.
Browder
Page 324 U. S. 100
v. United States, 312 U. S. 335. But
these are instances of proper statutory construction quite
irrelevant to the present case. It is one thing for judges not to
excise a particular situation from language appropriately
describing a general problem. Judicial interpolation into a statute
of a wholly unrelated problem not envisaged by Congress is quite
another matter. In this case, we have not an unforeseen situation
fitting into a general context. Here, we have an unforeseen problem
with which Congress did not deal, and yet, by not dealing with it,
is said to have taken away authority theretofore belonging to the
Secretary of the Treasury. If the problem itself was not in the
contemplation of Congress, as this problem was not, how can it be
said that Congress legislated concerning that problem?
The judgment should be affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE BLACK joins in this dissent.