1. By orders issued under the New York Milk Control Statute,
dealers were required to pay producers of milk a minimum price per
quart, and were subject to higher minimum resale prices.
Competition made it impossible for the dealer in this case to sell
for more than the resale minimum, and the "spread," or difference
between that and the minimum purchase price, was not enough to
cover the cost of its operations.
Held that, upon these
facts only, with nothing to show the degree of efficiency with
which its business was conducted, there is no ground to conclude
that the price limits are arbitrary, and therefore in violation of
the due process clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. P.
293 U. S.
170.
2. The Fourteenth Amendment does not protect a business against
the hazards of competition.
Public Service Comm'n v. Great
Northern Utilities Co., 289 U. S. 130. P.
293 U. S.
170.
3. One who complains that regulations promulgated under
legislative authority by a state board are unreasonable and
oppressive should seek relief by resisting the regulations before
that board or by applying to the board to modify them, before
bringing suit.
Petersen Baking Co. v. Bryan, 290 U.
S. 570. P.
293 U. S. 172.
6 F. Supp.
297 affirmed.
Appeal from a decree of the District Court of three judges
dismissing the bill in a suit attacking an order fixing minimum
prices under the New York Milk Control Act.
Page 293 U. S. 167
MR. JUSTICE CARDOZO delivered the opinion of the Court.
In this suit for an injunction, the appellant, a wholesale milk
dealer, contests the validity under the Fourteenth Amendment of
orders of the New York milk control board limiting the price of
milk. A District Court of three judges, organized in accordance
with § 266 of the Judicial Code (28 U.S.C. § 380), has
denied a motion by the complainant for an interlocutory injunction,
and granted a motion by the defendants to dismiss the bill.
6 F. Supp.
297. No testimony was taken, but, for the purposes of the two
motions, certain facts were stipulated and
Page 293 U. S. 168
embodied in findings. Nothing important is there added to what
is stated in the complaint. From the final decree, there has been
an appeal to this Court. 28 U.S.C. § 380.
The attempt is made in the bill to state two causes of action,
pleaded in separate counts. The first cause of action assails the
Milk Control Act (N.Y.Laws 1933, c. 158) as a whole, and was
dismissed on the authority of
Nebbia v. New York,
291 U. S. 502. It
has not been pressed in this Court, and must be treated as
abandoned. [
Footnote 1] The
second cause of action, the only one contested here, assumes
provisionally the validity of the statute and assails the orders
made under it in their application to appellant. On that head, the
bill recounts the orders of the board prescribing a minimum selling
price to be charged by dealers to their customers, and also a
minimum buying price to be paid by dealers to producers. The milk
sold by the appellant is known as grade B. At the time of the
trial, the minimum wholesale price for milk of that grade in the
City of New York was nine cents per quart, except that dealers such
as the appellant marketing their product without a well established
tradename might sell one cent a quart below the minimum for others.
By the same orders, the minimum price for fluid milk to be paid to
producers was fixed at five cents a quart. A separate schedule of
the orders gives the rates for fluid cream. The complainant's
license was revoked by the board after notice and a hearing because
of underpayments to producers. The license was, however, to be
reinstated upon payment of the difference ($23,000). The bill prays
a decree cancelling the revocation with exemption for the
future.
The question on this appeal is whether the allegations of the
bill, admitted in the stipulation, but not substantially
Page 293 U. S. 169
enlarged, make out a cause of action. For an understanding of
the complainant's position both in its economic and in its legal
aspects, the fact is of critical importance that there has been no
attempt by the board to fix a maximum price in respect of any of
the transactions subject to its regulatory power. What is fixed is
a minimum only. Nonetheless, the competition among dealers is so
keen that, in practice, the legal minimum is the maximum that the
appellant is able to charge. The "spread" between what must be paid
to the producers and what can be collected from the customers is so
small that it
"is insufficient in amount to afford plaintiff a fair return on
the present fair value of the properties devoted by it to its milk
business less depreciation."
This the bill and findings state. They tell us also that the
properties have a value of more than $450,000. They do not tell us
whether the appellant ran its business with reasonable efficiency
when compared with others in its calling. They do not even tell us
whether it was earning a fair return on its investment before the
orders were adopted. The omission is the more significant because,
according to official records, the "spread" has been increased,
instead of being diminished, through the operation of control.
Report of the Milk Control Board, March 1934, pp. 17, 18. [
Footnote 2] For all that appears upon
this record, a change of the minimum prices would avail the
appellant nothing if a corresponding increase or reduction were
allowed to its competitors. It might still be driven to the wall
without the aid of a differential that would neutralize
Page 293 U. S. 170
inequalities of capacity or power. If different minima would
help, the pleading leaves us in the dark as to what those minima
should be. There is no statement that a different selling price
could be fixed with fairness to consumers, or a different
purchasing price with fairness to producers. The appellant's
grievance amounts to this -- that it is operating at a loss, though
other dealers more efficient or economical or better known to the
public may be operating at a profit.
A bill of complaint so uncertain in aim and so meager in
particulars falls short of the standard of candor and precision set
up by our decisions.
Public Service Comm'n v. Great Northern
Utilities Co., 289 U. S. 130,
289 U. S. 136;
Aetna Ins. Co. v. Hyde, 275 U. S. 440,
275 U. S. 447.
True, the appellant is losing money under the orders now in force.
For anything shown in the bill, it was losing money before. For
anything there shown, other dealers at the same prices may now be
earning profits; at all events, they are content, or they would be
led by self-interest to raise the present level. We are unable to
infer from these fragmentary data that there has been anything
perverse or arbitrary in the action of the board. To make the
selling level higher might be unfair to the consumers; to make the
purchasing level lower might bring ruin to producers. The appellant
would have us say that minimum prices must be changed whenever a
particular dealer can show that the effect of the schedule, in its
application to himself, is to deprive him of a profit. This is not
enough to subject administrative rulings to revision by the courts.
If the designation of a minimum price is within the scope of the
police power, expenses or losses made necessary thereby must be
borne as an incident, unless the order goes so far beyond the needs
of the occasion as to be turned into an act of tyranny. Nothing of
the kind is charged. The Fourteenth Amendment does not protect a
business against the hazards of competition.
Page 293 U. S. 171
Public Service Comm'n of Montana v. Great Northern Utilities
Co., supra, at p.
289 U. S. 135.
It is from hazards of that order, and not from restraints of law
capriciously imposed, that the appellant seeks relief. The refuge
from its ills is not in constitutional immunities.
Much is made of a supposed analogy between the plight in which
the appellant finds itself and that of public utilities subjected
to maximum rates that do not yield a fair return. But the analogy,
when scrutinized, is seen to be unreal. A public utility in such
circumstances has no outlet of escape. If it is running its
business with reasonable economy, it must break the law or bleed to
death. But that is not the alternative offered where the law
prescribes a minimum. An outlet is then available to the regulated
business, an outlet that presumably will be utilized whenever use
becomes expedient. If the price is not raised, the reason must be
that efficient operators find that they can get along without a
change. Either that must be so or else, as was pointed out in the
opinion below, the industry will perish. The bill does not suggest
that such a catastrophe is imminent. True, of course, it is that
the weaker members of the group (the marginal operators or even
others above the margin) may find themselves unable to keep pace
with the stronger, but it is their comparative inefficiency, not
tyrannical compulsion, that makes them laggards in the race.
Whether a wise statecraft will favor or condemn this exaltation of
the strong is a matter of legislative policy with which courts are
not concerned. To pass judgment on it, there is need that the field
of vision be expanded to take in all the contestants in the race
for economic welfare, and not some of them only. The small dealer
may suffer, but the small producer may be helped, and an industry
vital to the state thus rescued from extinction. Such, at any rate,
is the theory that animates the statute, if we look to the official
declaration of the purpose
Page 293 U. S. 172
of its framers.
Nebbia v. New York, supra, pp.
291 U. S.
515-516. The question is not for us whether the workings
of the law have verified the theory or disproved it. At least a law
so animated is rescued from the reproach of favoritism for the
powerful to the prejudice of the lowly. If the orders made
thereunder are not arbitrary fiats, the courts will stand
aloof.
The statute (N.Y.Laws 1933, c. 158, § 312(d, f)) contains
provisions whereby a dealer dissatisfied with any administrative
order may be heard in opposition, or may apply to the board
afterwards to modify its ruling. This is an administrative remedy
which, in the one form or the other, the appellant should have
utilized before resorting to a suit.
P. F. Petersen Baking Co.
v. Bryan, 290 U. S. 570,
290 U. S. 575.
There is no statement that it did so.
The decree should be
Affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE SUTHERLAND concurs in the result.
[
Footnote 1]
The Act of 1933 has been amended and continued by Laws of 1934,
c. 126.
[
Footnote 2]
"If a allowances are made for the additional milk which, because
of the tightening up of the classification for Class 1 milk
occurring on February 16, 1934, must be included in Class 1, the
milk dealers' spread at this time is approximately O.12 cents per
quart greater than it was just before the Board was created."
This statement in the report is followed by schedules which
contain supporting data.