2. The power to require a license for, and to regulate the
conduct of, a business is distinct from the power to fix prices. P.
277 U. S.
358.
3. The fact that a business lends itself peculiarly to the
practice of fraud, extortion, and discrimination may be ground for
regulation, but not for price-fixing. P.
277 U. S.
368.
Page 277 U. S. 351
4. In determining the constitutionality of a state price-fixing
statute, the mere fact that like statutes exist in other states
held not of persuasive force. P.
277 U. S.
359.
103 N.J.L. 708 reversed.
Error to a judgment of the Court of Errors and Appeals of New
Jersey which affirmed a judgment, 4 N.J. Misc.Rep. 623, sustaining
an order of the state Commissioner of Labor refusing Ribnik a
license to conduct an employment agency upon the ground that some
of his proposed fees were too high.
Page 277 U. S. 354
MR. JUSTICE SUTHERLAND delivered the opinion of the Court.
Chapter 227, p. 822, Laws of New Jersey 1918, being an act to
regulate the keeping of employment agencies, requires that every
person operating an employment agency as defined by the statute
must procure a license from the Commissioner of Labor. A penalty is
imposed for failure to do so. The application for such license must
be made in writing to the Commissioner of Labor, and, among other
requirements, the applicant must
"file with the commissioner of labor, for his approval, a
schedule of fees proposed to be charged for any services rendered
to employers seeking employees, and persons seeking employment, and
all charges must conform thereto. The schedule of fees may be
changed only with the approval of the Commissioner of Labor."
The Commissioner of Labor may refuse to issue or may revoke any
license for any good cause shown within the meaning and purpose of
the act.
Plaintiff in error filed with the State Commissioner of Labor a
written application for a license to conduct an employment agency.
All conditions of the statute were complied with, but the
Commissioner rejected the application upon the sole ground that, in
his opinion, the fees proposed to be charged in respect of certain
permanent positions were excessive and unreasonable. This action of
the Commissioner was brought up for review to the supreme court of
the state, and that court, construing the statute as empowering the
Commissioner to fix and limit the charges to be made by the
applicant, nevertheless sustained it as constitutional under the
due process of law clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. 4 N.J.Mis.R.
623. Upon appeal to the state court of errors and appeals, the
judgment was affirmed. 103 N.J.L. 708.
Page 277 U. S. 355
That the state has power to require a license and regulate the
business of an employment agent does not admit of doubt. But the
question here presented is whether the due process of law clause is
contravened by the legislation attempting to confer upon the
Commissioner of Labor power to fix the prices which the employment
agent shall charge for his services. The question calls for an
answer under the last of the three categories set forth by this
Court in
Wolff Co. v. Industrial Court, 262 U.
S. 522,
262 U. S. 535
-- that is to say, has the business in question been devoted to the
public use and an interest in effect granted to the public in that
use? Or, in other words, is the business one "affected with a
public interest" within the meaning of that phrase as heretofore
defined by this Court? As was recently pointed out in
Tyson
& Brother v. Banton, 273 U. S. 418,
273 U. S. 430,
the phrase is not capable of exact definition, but, nevertheless,
under all the decisions of this Court from
Munn v.
Illinois, 94 U. S. 113, it is
the standard by which the validity of price-fixing legislation, in
respect of a business like that here under consideration, must be
tested.
In the
Tyson case, it was said (p.
273 U. S. 430)
that the interest meant was not
"such as arises from the mere fact that the public derives
benefit, accommodation, ease, or enjoyment from the existence or
operation of the business, and while the word has not always been
limited narrowly as strictly denoting 'a right,' that synonym more
nearly than any other expresses the sense in which it is to be
understood."
The business must be such (p.
273 U. S. 434)
"as to justify the conclusion that it has been devoted to a public
use, and its use thereby, in effect, granted to the public." And
again (p.
273 U. S.
438), after reviewing former decisions, it was said
that:
"each of the decisions of this Court upholding governmental
price regulation, aside from cases involving legislation to tide
over temporary emergencies, has turned
Page 277 U. S. 356
upon the existence of conditions, peculiar to the business under
consideration, which bore such a substantial and definite relation
to the public interest as to justify an indulgence of the legal
fiction of a grant by the owner to the public of an interest in the
use."
In
Wolff Co. v. Industrial Court, supra, p.
262 U. S. 537,
it was said:
"It has never been supposed since the adoption of the
Constitution that the business of the butcher, or the baker, the
tailor, the woodchopper, the mining operator, or the miner was
clothed with such a public interest that the price of his product
or his wages could be fixed by state regulation. . . . One does not
devote one's property or business to the public use or clothe it
with a public interest merely because one makes commodities for,
and sells to, the public in the common callings of which those
above mentioned are instances."
In
Adkins v. Children's Hospital, 261 U.
S. 525, this Court had under consideration an act of
Congress fixing minimum wages for women and children in the
District of Columbia. The legislation, so far as it affected women,
was held invalid as contravening the due process of law clause of
the Fifth Amendment because it was an arbitrary interference with
the right to contract in respect of terms of private employment. It
was said (p.
261 U. S. 546)
that, while there was no such thing as absolute freedom of
contract, nevertheless such freedom of contract was the general
rule, and restraint the exception, and that "the exercise of
legislative authority to abridge it can be justified only by the
existence of exceptional circumstances."
The business of securing employment for those seeking work and
employees for those seeking workers is essentially that of a broker
-- that is, of an intermediary. While we do not undertake to say
that there may not be a deeper concern on the part of the public in
the business of an employment agency, that business does not differ
in substantial
Page 277 U. S. 357
character from the business of a real estate broker, ship
broker, merchandise broker or ticket broker. In the
Tyson
case,
supra, we declared unconstitutional an act of the
New York Legislature which sought to fix the price at which theater
tickets should be sold by a ticket broker, and it is not easy to
see how, without disregarding that decision, price-fixing
legislation in respect of other brokers of like character can be
upheld.
An employment agency is essentially a private business. True, it
deals with the public, but so do the druggist, the butcher, the
baker, the grocer, and the apartment or tenement house owner, and
the broker who acts as intermediary between such owner and his
tenants. Of course, anything which substantially interferes with
employment is a matter of public concern, but in the same sense
that interference with the procurement of food and housing and fuel
are of public concern. The public is deeply interested in all these
things. The welfare of its constituent members depends upon them.
The interest of the public in the matter of employment is not
different in quality or character from its interest in the other
things enumerated, but in none of them is the interest that "public
interest" which the law contemplates as the basis for legislative
price control.
Wolff Co. v. Industrial Court, supra, p.
262 U. S. 536.
Under the decisions of this Court, it is no longer fairly open to
question that, at least in the absence of a grave emergency
(
Tyson & Brother v. Banton, supra, pp.
273 U. S. 431,
273 U. S.
437), the fixing of prices for food or clothing, of
house rental or of wages to be paid, whether minimum or maximum, is
beyond the legislative power. And we perceive no reason for
applying a different rule in the case of legislation controlling
prices to be paid for services rendered in securing a place for an
employee or an employee for a place.
Brazee v. Michigan, 241 U. S. 340,
cited by defendant in error, lends no support to the judgment
below. That
Page 277 U. S. 358
case involved the validity of a Michigan statute in respect of
employment agencies. Section 5 of the act attempted to limit the
fees which should be charged. The state supreme court held that the
business was one properly subject to police regulation and control,
but did not rule concerning the validity of § 5. This Court
held that it was within the power of the state to require licenses
for employment agencies and prescribe reasonable regulations to be
enforced by the Commissioner of Labor. But it was said (p.
241 U. S.
344):
"Provisions of § 5 in respect of fees to be demanded or
retained are severable from other portions of the act and, we
think, might be eliminated without destroying it. Their validity
was not passed upon by the supreme court of the state, and has not
been considered by us."
And we since have held definitely that the power to require a
license for and to regulate the conduct of a business is distinct
from the power to fix prices.
"The latter power is not only a more definite and serious
invasion of the rights of property and the freedom of contract, but
its exercise cannot always be justified by circumstances which have
been held to justify legislative regulation of the manner in which
a business shall be carried on."
Tyson & Brother v. Banton, supra, p.
273 U. S. 431.
And see pp.
273 U. S.
440-441.
To urge that extortion, fraud, imposition, discrimination, and
the like have been practiced to some, or to great, extent in
connection with the business here under consideration, or that the
business is one lending itself peculiarly to such evils, is simply
to restate grounds already fully considered by this Court. These
are grounds for regulation, but not for price-fixing, as we have
already definitely decided.
Tyson & Brother v. Banton,
supra, 273 U. S.
442-445.
There are a number of states which have statutes like that now
under consideration, and we are asked to give weight to that
circumstance. It is to be observed, however,
Page 277 U. S. 359
that, with the exception of the decision now under review, none
of these statutes has been judicially considered, except in the
State of California, where the legislation was declared
unconstitutional.
Ex parte Dickey, 144 Cal. 234;
In re
Smith, 193 Cal. 337. And it was said in oral argument, and not
disputed, that, while legislation of this character existed in
several states, generally it was not enforced, in some instances
because the state's Attorney General had advised that the
legislation was unconstitutional. In any event, under all the
circumstances and in the face of our prior decisions, we do not
regard the mere existence in other states of statutory provisions
like the one now under review as entitled to persuasive force.
Judgment reversed.
MR. JUSTICE SANFORD (concurring).
I concur in this result upon the controlling authority of
Tyson v. Banton, 273 U. S. 418,
which, as applied to the question in this case, I am unable to
distinguish.
MR. JUSTICE STONE, dissenting.
The question is whether a state has constitutional power to
require employment agencies to charge only reasonable fees for
their services to those seeking employment. As the case is
presented, we must take it that the New Jersey Commissioner of
Labor was right in holding that Ribnik's list of fees was
unreasonably high.
Under the decisions of this Court, not all price regulation, as
distinguished from other forms of regulation, is forbidden. As
those decisions have been explained, price regulation is within the
constitutional power of a state legislature when the business
concerned is "affected with a public interest." That phrase is not
to be found in the Constitution. Concededly it is incapable of any
precise definition. It has and can have only such meaning as
Page 277 U. S. 360
may be given to it by the decisions of this Court. As I read
those decisions, such regulation is within a state's power whenever
any combination of circumstances seriously curtails the regulative
force of competition, so that buyers or sellers are placed at such
a disadvantage in the bargaining struggle that a legislature might
reasonably anticipate serious consequences to the community as a
whole.
Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113;
Brass v. North Dakota ex rel. Stoeser, 153 U.
S. 391;
German Alliance Insurance Co. v. Lewis,
233 U. S. 389,
233 U. S. 409;
Terminal Taxicab Co. v. Kutz, 241 U.
S. 252;
Block v. Hirsh, 256 U.
S. 135;
Marcus Brown Co. v. Feldman,
256 U. S. 170;
Levy Leasing Co. v. Siegel, 258 U.
S. 242;
see also Knoxville Iron Co. v.
Harbison, 183 U. S. 13;
McLean v. Arkansas, 211 U. S. 539;
Mutual Loan Co. v. Martell, 222 U.
S. 225;
Frisbie v. United States, 157 U.
S. 160. The price regulation may embrace businesses
"which, though not public at their inception, may be fairly said
to have risen to be such and have become subject in consequence to
some government regulation."
Wolff Co. v. Industrial Court, 262 U.
S. 522,
262 U. S. 535.
The use by the public generally of the specific thing or business
affected is not the test. The nature of the service rendered, the
exorbitance of the charges, and the arbitrary control to which the
public may be subjected without regulation are elements to be
considered in determining whether the "public interest" exists.
Wolff Co. v. Industrial Court, supra, 262 U. S. 538.
The economic disadvantage of a class and the attempt to ameliorate
its condition may alone be sufficient to give rise to the "public
interest" and to justify the regulation of contracts with its
members (
Knoxville Iron Co. v. Harbison, supra; McLean v.
Arkansas, supra; Mutual Loan Co. v. Martell, supra), and
obviously circumstances may so change in point of time or so differ
in space as to clothe a business with such an interest which at
other
Page 277 U. S. 361
times or in other places would be a matter purely of private
concern.
Block v. Hirsh, supra, 256 U. S.
155.
I cannot say
a priori that the business of employment
agencies in New Jersey lacks the requisite "public interest." We
are judicially aware that the problem of unemployment is of grave
public concern; that the conduct of the employment agency business
bears an important relationship to that larger problem and affects
vitally the lives of great numbers of the population, not only in
New Jersey, but throughout the United States; that employment
agencies, admittedly subject to regulation in other respects
(
Brazee v. Michigan, 241 U. S. 340),
and in fact very generally regulated, deal with a necessitous
class, the members of which are often dependent on them for
opportunity to earn a livelihood, are not free to move from place
to place, and are often under exceptional economic compulsion to
accept such terms as the agencies offer. We are not judicially
ignorant of what all human experience teaches -- that those so
situated are peculiarly the prey of the unscrupulous and designing.
In
Adams v. Tanner, 244 U. S. 590, a
statute of Washington which in effect attempted to abolish the
business was held unconstitutional because employment agencies were
deemed not "inherently immoral or dangerous to public welfare,"
but, as was there emphasized, capable, under regulation, of being
conducted in a useful and honest manner. But it was not questioned
that the business was subject to grave abuses, involving frauds and
impositions upon a peculiarly helpless class, among which the
exaction of exorbitant fees was perhaps the least offensive. The
Supreme Court of New Jersey, in an opinion in the present case
which was adopted by the Court of Errors and Appeals, said:
"It is common knowledge that an employment agency is a business
dealing with a great body of our population, native and foreign
born, which is
Page 277 U. S. 362
susceptible to imposition, deception, and immoral influences. .
. ."
In dealing with the question of power to require reasonable
prices in this particular business, we should remember what was
specifically pointed out by the court in
Tyson v. Banton,
273 U. S. 418,
273 U. S. 438,
that whether a business is affected with a "public interest" turns
"upon the existence of conditions, peculiar to the business under
consideration." In the respects mentioned, or most of them, and in
others to be pointed out, it seems to me that there is a marked
difference between the character of this business and that of real
estate brokers, ship brokers, merchandise brokers, and, more than
all, of ticket brokers, who were involved in
Tyson v. Banton,
supra. There, the attempt was made to limit the advance which
brokers might charge over box office prices for theater tickets, an
expedient adopted to break up their monopolistic control of a
luxury, not a necessity. Those affected by the practices of the
ticket brokers constituted a relatively small part of the
population within a comparatively small area of the State of New
York. They were not necessitous. The consequences of the fraud and
extortion practiced upon them were not visited upon the community
as a whole in any such manner as are fraud and imposition practiced
upon workers seeking employment. Here, the effort is made, as in
Knoxville Iron Co. v. Harbison, supra, McLean v. Arkansas,
supra, Mutual Loan Co. v. Martell, supra, and
Erie R. Co.
v. Williams, 233 U. S. 685,
first, to protect from abuses a class unable to protect itself, for
whose welfare the police power has often been allowed broad play,
and second, to mitigate the evils which unemployment brings upon
the community as a whole.
Some presumption should be indulged that the New Jersey
Legislature had an adequate knowledge of such local conditions as
the circumstances of those seeking employment,
Page 277 U. S. 363
the number and distribution of employment agencies, the local
efficacy of competition, the prevalent practices with respect to
fees. On this deserved respect for the judgment of the local
lawmaker depends, of course, the presumption in favor of
constitutionality, for the validity of a regulation turns "upon the
existence of conditions, peculiar to the business under
consideration."
Tyson v. Banton, supra, 273 U. S. 438.
Moreover, we should not, when the matter is not clear, oppose our
notion of the seriousness of the problem or the necessity of the
legislation to that of local tribunals.
"This Court, by an unbroken line of decisions from Chief Justice
Marshall to the present day, has steadily adhered to the rule that
every possible presumption is in favor of the validity of an act of
Congress until overcome beyond rational doubt."
Adkins v. Children's Hospital, 261 U.
S. 525,
261 U. S. 544.
And the enactments of state legislatures are entitled to no less
respect. If, therefore, our consideration of the general conditions
surrounding employment agencies, which it was thought in
Brazee
v. Michigan, supra, made them subject to regulation, was to go
no further than that of the Court, I should still have supposed
that plaintiff in error had not sustained the burden which rests on
him to show that this law is unconstitutional.
Erie R. Co. v.
Williams, supra. But even if the presumption is not to be
indulged, and the burden no longer to be cast on him who attacks
the constitutionality of a law, we need not close our eyes to
available data throwing light on the problem with which the
legislature had to deal.
See Muller v. Oregon,
208 U. S. 412,
208 U. S.
420-421;
McLean v. Arkansas, supra,
211 U. S.
549.
For 30 years or more, the evils found to be connected with the
business of employment agencies in the United States have been the
subject of repeated investigations, official and unofficial, and of
extensive public comment. They have been the primary reason for
the
Page 277 U. S. 364
establishment of public employment offices in the various
states. [
Footnote 1]
Quite apart from the other evils laid at the door of the private
agencies, [
Footnote 2] the data
supplied by these investigations and reports afford a substantial
basis for the conclusion of the New Jersey Legislature that the
business is peculiarly subject to abuses relating to fee charging,
and
Page 277 U. S. 365
that, for the correction of these, the restriction to a
reasonable maximum charge is the only effective remedy. These data,
to be gathered from numerous independent and public investigations,
may be briefly summarized as follows:
First. They show that the agencies, left to themselves,
very generally charge extortionate fees. The Commission on
Industrial Relations, created by Act of August 23, 1912, c. 351, 37
Stat. 415, reported to Congress at a time when prices were
materially lower than today:
"Fees are often charged out of all proportion to the service
rendered. We know of cases where $5, $9, $10, and even $16 a piece
has been paid for jobs at common labor. In one city, the fees paid
by scrubwomen is at the rate of $24 a year for their poorly paid
work. [
Footnote 3]"
Exorbitant fees are taken for merely registering the applicants,
no effort whatever being made to find them work. [
Footnote 4] To stimulate
Page 277 U. S. 366
the payment of such fees, the agencies advertise for classes of
laborers for whom no jobs are available. [
Footnote 5] According to the Massachusetts Commission
to Investigate Employment Offices, the ordinary forces of
competition seem powerless to prevent or remedy this situation,
because but little capital is required to open an office, and
because the clients of the agencies are constantly new. [
Footnote 6]
Second. These data show that the fees charged are often
discriminatory. It is made known in slack season that but few jobs
are available, and that to these will be referred the applicants
who tender the larger "extra fees"
Page 277 U. S. 367
or "presents." [
Footnote 7]
There is ground for the belief that this is a particular danger in
New Jersey, for a large proportion of its agencies specialize in
employees for hotels and resorts, where the positions are seasonal
and temporary. [
Footnote 8] The
whole supply of labor must, at the beginning and again at the end
of the season, search for new positions at the same time.
Third. Fee-splitting has been a recurrent subject of
complaint. It
"is frequently practiced, part of the fee charged to the worker
being paid over by the private employment agent to the employer or
his foreman. This practice is closely akin to job selling by
foremen and superintendents. . . . Both 'fee splitting' and 'job
selling' result in short-time employment and frequent discharges,
for each time a job is filled, a new fee is 'split,' or a fresh
price exacted. The resultant wastage from accelerated labor
turn-over, from extortionate and multiplied fees, from
demoralization of workers, from unemployment and irregularity of
employment, is incalculably great. "
Page 277 U. S. 368
Public Employment Offices in the United States, U.S. Bureau of
Labor Statistics Bulletin No. 241 (1918) p. 6. [
Footnote 9] While their fees are unregulated, the
private agencies are free to charge those seeking employment enough
to cover both the charge for their service and the gratuity paid to
the foreman or employer. A legislature would certainly not be
unreasonable in concluding that the fixing of a reasonable maximum
fee was the appropriate and only effective method of assuring
private agencies fair compensation while preventing them from
abuses of this character.
Fourth. It is reported that at times of widespread
unemployment the private agencies are known to raise their fees out
of all proportion to the reasonable value of their services.
[
Footnote 10] There is a
public interest at such times in
Page 277 U. S. 369
bringing about a prompt readjustment of the labor supply to
industry's need for labor. The additional barrier to a quick
readjustment created by the agencies' raising of their rates
affects that interest adversely. The establishment of a reasonable
maximum rate [
Footnote 11]
is well calculated to obviate the abuse.
Fifth. Finally, it is pointed out that the private
agencies charge the employee and do not charge the employer for a
service that is rendered to both. The convenience of being
furnished with employees is similar to that of being directed to a
position, but less effort is required to collect compensation for
the whole service from the employee alone. His necessities are
normally greater. His bargaining power is normally weaker. The
setting of a maximum fee need not mean -- in New Jersey, does not
mean -- that an absolute limit is placed on the agency's return.
The agency may still charge the employer in addition for such
service as is rendered to him. [
Footnote 12] The establishment of reasonable fees is
thus, in one aspect, merely a method of
Page 277 U. S. 370
providing that the patrons of the agency shall be required to
pay only for the service rendered to them.
Legislation for the correction of these and other evils has been
general throughout the United States. [
Footnote 13] Among the earliest comprehensive schemes
for that purpose was the Act of June 19, 1906, c. 3438, 34 Stat.
304, adopted by Congress for the District of Columbia. [
Footnote 14] For numerous
Page 277 U. S. 371
classes of employees (including all domestic servants and farm
help), it regulates (§ 8) not only the fee which may be
charged to the applicant for work, but also the amount that the
agency may receive from the employer. It requires a refund of half
the fee if a fair opportunity for work is not secured in four days,
and a refund of the whole fee and transportation expenses if no
employment of the kind asked was vacant at the place to which the
applicant was directed.
Among the states, 21 have limited the total fees that may be
charged, ten by fixing a stated maximum [
Footnote 15] and eleven by restricting the charge to a
named percentage of the salary earned during some period. [
Footnote 16] In eight states, the
maximum registration fee is fixed by statute, and that fee is
required to be returned if no work is found for the applicant.
[
Footnote 17] In seventeen
states, if no
Page 277 U. S. 372
work is furnished, the agency must return the entire fee
collected. [
Footnote 18]
It is, of course, true that the enactment of a particular type
of legislation, even though general, and a widespread and competent
opinion that it is wise and necessary, do not establish its
constitutionality. But that such legislation has been enacted and
continued in force over considerable periods of time and in widely
separated areas, and is supported by a concurrence of informed
opinion, may not be disregarded in determining, first, whether the
conditions peculiar to the business under consideration make it one
in which, as in insurance companies, there is a paramount public
concern; and, second, whether the regulation adopted is reasonably
calculated to safeguard that interest.
See Muller v. Oregon,
supra, 208 U. S.
420-421;
McLean v. Arkansas, supra.
Examination of the various reports of public bodies and the
legislation referred to can, I think, leave no doubt that the
practices of the private agencies with respect to their fees
presented a problem for legislative consideration different from
any other that this Court has passed on in ruling on the power to
regulate prices, but certainly more akin to that in
Munn v.
Illinois, supra, and
German Alliance Insurance Co. v.
Lewis, supra, than to that in
Tyson v. Banton, supra,
and, unless we are to establish once and for all the rule that only
public utilities may be
Page 277 U. S. 373
regulated as to price, the validity of the statute at hand would
seem to me to be beyond doubt. Certainly it would be difficult to
show a greater necessity for price regulation.
It is said that, if there be abuses in this business, the
business may be regulated, but not by the fixing of reasonable
prices, and that that was decided in
Tyson v. Banton,
supra. So far as the significant facts in that case are
concerned, it bears little resemblance to this one. Ticket brokers
and employment brokers are similar in name; in no other respect do
they seem alike to me. To overcharge a man for the privilege of
hearing the opera is one thing; to control the possibility of his
earning a livelihood would appear to be quite another. And I shall
not stop to argue that the state has a larger interest in seeing
that its workers find employment without being imposed upon, than
in seeing that its citizens are entertained. Here, too, if the
business is subject to regulation, as seems to be admitted, the
regulation which is appropriate and effective is some curtailment
of the exorbitant fees charged and not some other form of control
which would have no tendency to correct the evils aimed at.
I cannot accept as valid the distinction on which the opinion of
the majority seems to me necessarily to depend -- that, granted
constitutional power to regulate, there is any controlling
difference between reasonable regulation of price, if appropriate
to the evil to be remedied, and other forms of appropriate
regulation which curtail liberty of contract or the use and
enjoyment of property. Obviously, even in the case of businesses
affected with a public interest, other control than price
regulation may be appropriate, and price regulation may be so
inappropriate as to be arbitrary or unreasonable, and hence
unconstitutional. To me. it seems equally obvious that the
Constitution does not require us to hold that a business, subject
to every other form of reasonable regulation,
Page 277 U. S. 374
is immune from the requirement of reasonable prices, where that
requirement is the only remedy appropriate to the evils
encountered. In this respect, I can see no difference between a
reasonable regulation of price and a reasonable regulation of the
use of property, which affects its price or economic return. The
privilege of contract and the free use of property are as seriously
cut down in the one case as in the other.
To say that there is constitutional power to regulate a business
or a particular use of property because of the public interest in
the welfare of a class peculiarly affected, and to deny such power
to regulate price for the accomplishment of the same end, when that
alone appears to be an appropriate and effective remedy, is to make
a distinction based on no real economic difference, and for which I
can find no warrant in the Constitution itself nor any
justification in the opinions of this Court.
The price paid for property or services is only one of the terms
in a bargain; the effect on the parties is similar whether the
restriction on the power to contract affects the price, or the
goods or services sold. Apart from the cases involving the historic
public callings, immemorially subject to the closest regulation,
this Court has sustained regulations of the price in cases where
the legislature fixed the charges which grain elevators,
Brass
v. Stoeser, supra; Budd v. New York, 143 U.
S. 517, and insurance companies might make,
German
Alliance Insurance Co. v. Lewis, supra; or required miners to
be paid per ton of coal unscreened instead of screened,
McLean
v. Arkansas, supra; Rail Coal Co. v. Ohio Industrial
Commission, 236 U. S. 338; or
required employers who paid their men in store orders to redeem
them in cash,
Knoxville Iron Co. v. Harbison, supra; Dayton
Coal Co. v. Barton, 183 U. S. 23;
Keokee Coke Co. v. Taylor, 234 U.
S. 224; or fixed the fees chargeable by attorneys
appearing for injured employees before workmen's compensation
commissions,
Page 277 U. S. 375
Yeiser v. Dysart, 267 U. S. 540; or
fixed the rate of pay for overtime work,
Bunting v.
Oregon, 243 U. S. 426; or
fixed the time within which the services of employees must be paid
for,
Erie R. Co. v. Williams, supra; or established
maximum rents,
Block v. Hirsh, 256 U.
S. 135;
Marcus Brown Co. v. Feldman,
256 U. S. 170; or
fixed the maximum rate of interest chargeable on loans,
Griffith v. Connecticut, 218 U. S. 563. It
has sustained restrictions on the other element in the bargain
where legislatures have established maximum hours of labor for men,
Holden v. Hardy, 169 U. S. 366; or
for women,
Muller v. Oregon, 208 U.
S. 412;
Hawley v. Walker, 232 U.S. 718;
Riley v. Massachusetts, 232 U. S. 671;
Miller v. Wilson, 236 U. S. 373;
Bosley v. McLaughlin, 236 U. S. 385; or
prohibited the payment of wages in advance,
Patterson v. Bark
Eudora, 190 U. S. 169;
Strathearn S.S. Co. v. Dillon, 252 U.
S. 348; or required loaves of bread to be of a certain
size,
Schmidinger v. Chicago, 226 U.
S. 578. In each of these cases, the police power of the
state was held broad enough to warrant an interference with free
bargaining in cases where, despite the competition that ordinarily
attends that freedom, serious evils persisted.
Similar evils are now observed in the conduct of employment
agencies. I see no reason why a state may not resort to the same
remedy. There may be reasonable differences of opinion as to the
wisdom of the solution here attempted. These I would be the first
to admit. But a choice between them involves a step from the
judicial to the legislative field.
Erie R. Co. v. Williams,
supra, 233 U. S. 699;
German Alliance Ins. Co. v. Lewis, supra; Munn v. Illinois,
supra, 94 U. S. 132.
That choice should be left where, it seems to me, it was left by
the Constitution -- to the states and to Congress.
MR. JUSTICE HOLMES and MR. JUSTICE BRANDEIS join in this
dissent.
[
Footnote 1]
As early as 1912, free employment offices were maintained by at
least 15 states -- Colorado, Connecticut, Illinois, Indiana,
Kansas, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Minnesota, Missouri,
Ohio, Oklahoma, Rhode Island, West Virginia, and Wisconsin -- and
by municipalities in California, Montana, New Jersey, and
Washington. The State of New York had maintained an office in New
York City as early as 1896, and, in Nebraska, a statute providing
for an office had been passed, but no appropriation had been made
for its maintenance.
See Statistics of Unemployment and
the Work of Employment Offices, U.S. Bur. of Labor, Bull. No. 109,
pp. 35, 36. The authors of the inquiry conducted for the Russell
Sage Foundation reported:
"One conclusion drawn from [our] findings has been that we must
have public bureaus to take the place of the private fee-charging
agencies -- that is, insofar as people are informed on the question
and have expressed their sentiments, most of them appeared
convinced that we should have public employment bureaus because of
the abuses of some fee-charging agencies quite regardless of other
considerations. In addition, however, the feeling has been growing
that this service in the nature of the case should be free, and
that the very fact of fee-charging carries with it a dangerous
temptation to abuse and fraud."
Public Employment Offices, Harrison and Others (1924) p. 5.
Compare Report of New Jersey Bureau of Statistics of Labor
and Industries, 1893, pp. 73-78.
[
Footnote 2]
The numerous governmental reports on the undesirable practices
of the agencies, other than those relating to fee charging and
therefore not directly material here, are summarized in the opinion
of MR. JUSTICE BRANDEIS in
Adams v. Tanner, 244 U.
S. 590,
244 U. S.
597-616.
See also Public Employment Exchanges,
Report of City Club of New York, 1914; Labor Exchanges, J. B.
Andrews, 63d Cong.3d Sess. Sen.Doc. No. 956; Free Public Employment
Offices, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bulletin No. 68, pp. 1-6;
Proceedings, Ninth Annual Convention, Association of governmental
Labor Officials, 1923, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics No. 323, pp.
71, 72.
[
Footnote 3]
Report of Commission on Industrial Relations, 64th Cong. 1st
Sess. Sen.Doc. No. 415, vol. I, p. 109.
See also vol. II,
pp. 1168, 1169; Monthly Labor Review, Bureau of Labor Statistics,
October, 1922, p. 15. In California during 1920, the average fee
charged by clerical agencies was 30 percent of the first month's
wages. Report of California Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1919-1920.
See Report of Massachusetts Commission on Immigration,
1914, pp. 38-47.
[
Footnote 4]
Employment Bureaus, Willoughby, Monographs on American Social
Economics, No. VI, U.S. Commission to the Paris Exposition of 1900,
pp. 3, 4. See Report of Illinois Free Employment Offices, 1900,
passim; id., 1907, p. 71; Pennsylvania Dept. of Labor and
Industry, Bulletin, 1920, vol. 7, No. 5, pp. 7-15; Report of Iowa
Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1890, pp. 217-240; Report of New York
Industrial Commissioner, 1922, p. 23; Proceedings, American
Association of Public Employment Officers, 1913, 1914, 1915, U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Bulletin No.192, pp. 79, 80; Hearings
on H.R. 16130 before House Committee on Labor, 63d Cong.2d Sess.
Part I; Hearings on S. 688, S. 1442, H.R. 4305, before Joint
Committees on Labor, 66th Cong. 1st Sess. Part I.
In Public Employment Offices in the United States, U.S. Bureau
of Labor Statistics, Bull. No. 241 (1918) p. 6, it is declared:
"If the private employment agencies had been conducted with
ordinary honesty and efficiency, the striving for a greater degree
of justice to the worker would not have been able to make any
headway against the accepted doctrine of individualism, which
assumes that privately conducted businesses are always preferable
to publicly conducted businesses. The irregularities and abuses of
the private employment agencies, however, became too notorious to
be overlooked."
"The charges usually preferred against private employment
agencies concern the fees exacted, the practices in referring
applicants to jobs, and the places where the employment agencies
are frequently located. Fees for registration were, and still are,
charged by many private employment agencies, although these
agencies make no effort to render any service in return for the
fee. If the registered applicant makes a complaint, he is asked to
pay an extra fee on the promise of getting first consideration. The
fees charged are oftentimes exorbitant."
[
Footnote 5]
Employment Bureaus, Willoughby,
supra, pp. 3-4. The Act
of June 19, 1906, c. 3438, 34 Stat. 304, 307, enacted by Congress
for the District of Columbia, requires (§ 8) a refund of
one-half the fee, if a fair opportunity for employment is not
secured within four days, and provides that
"the whole fee and any sums paid by the applicant for
transportation in going to and returning from such employer shall
be refunded within four days of demand if no employment of the kind
applied for was vacant at the place to which the applicant was
directed."
[
Footnote 6]
Report of Mass. Commission to Investigate Employment Offices
(1911) p. 15.
[
Footnote 7]
Statistics of Unemployment and the Work of Employment Offices,
U.S. Bureau of Labor Bulletin, No. 109, p. 36.
[
Footnote 8]
In 1920, 30 out of the 92 agencies in the state were of that
type. Report of New Jersey Dept. of Labor, 1921, pp. 59, 60.
Legislation enacted in New Jersey in 1907, which left the
regulation of employment agencies to the municipalities, was found
in practice to be ineffective because of the laxity of local
enforcement. Report of New Jersey Commission of Immigration, 1914,
pp. 57-66.
During a labor shortage, the private agencies in New Jersey have
been found to use a different device to stimulate fees
artificially. After the war, many of the women drawn by it into
industry failed to return to domestic work. In the consequent
shortage of domestics, the agencies encouraged women to change
jobs, collecting a new fee at each change. Report of New Jersey,
Dept. of Labor, 1919, pp. 144-146. Section 9 of the act provided by
Congress for the District of Columbia,
supra,
provides:
"That no such person [
i.e., licensed employment agent]
shall induce or attempt to induce any domestic employee to leave
his employment with a view to obtaining other employment through
such agency."
[
Footnote 9]
This practice has been reported as prevalent in railroad
building, where it is known as the "three gang system" -- at any
one time, there is one gang, just discharged, on its way home;
another at work, but on the point of being dismissed; a third,
hired by the agency and on its way to the job.
See Public
Employment Offices, Harrison and Others,
supra, p. 550.
Compare Report of U.S. Bureau of Immigration, 1907, pp.
70, 71;
id., 1911, pp. 121, 122; Report of U.S.
Immigration Commission, 61st Cong.3d Sess. Sen.Doc. No. 747, vol.
II, pp. 321, 391-408, 443-449.
The congressional act passed for the District of Columbia,
supra, provides (§ 8):
"No such licensed person shall divide fees with contractors or
their agents or other employers or any one in their employ to whom
applicants for employment are sent."
[
Footnote 10]
"In the summer, when employment is plentiful, the fees are as
low as 25 cents, and men are even referred to work free of charge.
But this must necessarily be made up in winter, when work is
scarce. At such times, when men need work most badly, the private
employment offices put up their fees, and keep the unemployed from
going to work until they can pay $2, $3, $5, and even $10 and more
for their jobs. This necessity of paying for the privilege of going
to work, and paying more the more urgently the job is needed, not
only keeps people unnecessarily unemployed, but seems foreign to
the spirit of American freedom and opportunity."
Report of Commission on Industrial Relations, 64th Cong. 1st
Sess. Sen.Doc. No. 415, vol. I. p. 110.
[
Footnote 11]
The usual practice of the legislatures is, of course, not to fix
one fee to be charged, regardless of the type of position
furnished, but to group employment offices according to their
classes of clients, and promulgate different fee schedules for the
different groups.
See Report of Massachusetts Commission
to Investigate Employment Offices, 1911, pp. 26-28.
[
Footnote 12]
Some agencies have already done so. Report of Massachusetts
Commission to Investigate Employment Offices, 1911, p. 29.
Compare Report of Commission on Industrial Relations, 64th
Cong. 1st Sess. Sen.Doc. No. 415, vol. I, p. 110. The act of
Congress to regulate agencies in the District of Columbia limited
the fee which the agencies might charge employers, as well as that
chargeable to those seeking positions. Act of June 19, 1906, c.
3438, § 8, 34 Stat. 304, 307. In Massachusetts, the
municipalities were empowered by statute to regulate the fees of
the agencies. Rev.Laws Mass.1902, c. 102; Acts Mass.1920, c. 216.
In December, 1920, the ordinances in force in Boston permitted
domestic and common labor agencies to collect, both from the
employer and the employee, only 25 percent of the first week's
wages. U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Monthly Labor Review,
October, 1922, p. 7. In Oklahoma, fees may not be collected both
from the employer and the employee, but the amount the employee may
be charged is limited to a percentage of his first month's salary.
Acts Okl.1917, c. 181.
[
Footnote 13]
Thirty-nine states have enacted statutes regulating or taxing
private employment agencies; only Alabama, Arizona, Delaware,
Florida, Mississippi, North Dakota, New Mexico, South Carolina, and
Vermont are without state laws on the subject, and in some of
these, the agencies are taxed by municipalities.
See U.S.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Monthly Labor Review, October, 1922, p.
1; Acts N.C.1925, c. 127. In Canada, the agencies are subject to
rigorous regulation, including the fixing of their charges.
Employment Agencies Act, May 1, 1914, Provincial Act 4 Geo. V, c.
38.
See Report of Ontario Commission on Unemployment,
1916, pp. 41, 121-123; Report of Trades and Labor Branch, Dept. of
Public Works, Province of Ontario, 1917, pp. 88-91; Lescohier, The
Labor Market (1919) pp. 150-153.
General systems of regulation, with such provisions as the
requirement of bonds, the publication and filing of fee schedules,
the payment of license fees, etc., but without limitation of the
fees that may be charged applicants, are in force in Alabama,
Gen.Laws 1923, No. 181; Florida, Rev.Gen.Stat. 1920, § 888;
Georgia, Code 1926, § 2158(32)B; Kentucky, Stat. 1903, §
3011; Louisiana, Stat. (Wolff, 1920) pp. 1100-1102; Maryland,
Annot.Code (Bagby 1924) Art. 56, § 232; Minnesota, Gen.Stat.
1923, §§ 4246, 4247; New Hampshire, Pub.Laws 1928, c.
179; Washington, Code (Pierce, 1919) § 8876; West Virginia,
Code (Barnes, 1923) c. 32, §§ 1, 109. An Idaho statute
purports to abolish private agencies. Comp.Stat. Idaho 1919,
§§ 2297, 2308-2310. A similar statute, Wash.Laws (1915)1,
was declared unconstitutional in
Adams v. Tanner,
244 U. S. 590.
[
Footnote 14]
The rates legally chargeable were increased by Act of February
20, 1909, c. 166, 35 Stat. 641, which left the other material
provisions of the original act unchanged.
[
Footnote 15]
Comp.Laws Colo. (1921), § 4296; R.S. Me. (1916), c. 42, as
amended by Laws (1917), c. 139; Gen.Laws Mass. (1921), c. 140,
§§ 41-46, 202-205 (operating under these sections, the
municipalities fix the rates, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics,
Monthly Labor Review, October, 1922, p. 7); Rev.Codes Mont. (1921),
§§ 4157-4172; Gen.Code Ohio (1926), §§ 886-897;
Pa.Stat. (1920), §§ 10130-10164; Gen.Laws R.I. (1923), c.
51, § 18; Acts S.D. (1919), c.190; Rev.Civ.Stat. Tex. (1925),
Tit. 83, c. 13; Stat. Wis. (1927), c. 105.
[
Footnote 16]
Gen.Laws Cal. (Hillyer, Supp. 1921-1925) c. 102, § 11 1/2;
Labor Laws Conn. (Revision of 1920) §§ 2333-2337; Burns
Annot.Stat. Ind. (1914), §§ 7131a-7131i, as amended by
Acts (1921), p. 263; Acts Iowa (1925), c. 39; Acts Mich. (1925),
No. 255; Comp.Stat. Neb. (1922), § 7734; General Business Law
N.Y. § 185; Pub.Laws N.C. (1925), c. 127; Comp.Stat. Okl.
(1921), §§ 7184-7207; Olson Or.Laws (1920), Tit. 38, c.
10; Comp.Laws Utah (1917), §§ 2440-2458, 3076(6), as
amended by Laws (1919), c. 130, and Laws (1921), cc. 48, 49.
[
Footnote 17]
Acts Ark. (1917), No. 11; Comp.Laws Colo. (1921), § 4296;
Cahill's R.S. Ill. (1927), c. 48, § 79 (fee limited, but not
returnable); R.S. Kan. (1923), 44-407; R.S. Mo. (1919), §
5761; Comp.Stat. Neb. (1922), §§ 7720, 7734; Code Va.
(1924), § 1803, Comp.Stat. Wyo. (1920), § 3468.
[
Footnote 18]
Stat. Cal. (1913), c. 282; Stat.Cal. (1915), c. 551; Stat.Cal.
(1923), c. 413; Cahill's R.S. Ill. (1927), c. 48, § 79 ($2 may
be retained as a registration fee); Code Iowa (1924), § 1546
(a small fixed sum may, however, be retained as a registration
fee); Acts Kan. (1911), c. 187; Gen.Laws Mass. (1921), c. 140
(under municipal regulations); R.S. Me. (1916), c. 42; R.S. Mo.
(1919), §§ 6751-6755; Rev.Codes Mont. (1921), §
4164; Rev.Laws Nev. (1919), p. 2783, § 10; General Business
Law N.Y. § 186; Comp.Stat.Okl. (1921), § 7185; Olson
Or.Laws (1920), Tit. 38, c. 10, § 6730; Pa.Stat. (1920),
§ 10142; Acts S.D. (1919), c.190; Acts Tenn. (1917), c. 78;
Code Va. (1924), § 1803; Comp.Stat. Wyo. (1920), §
3468.