1. The evidence supports a finding that a net return of 7
percent was necessary to avoid confiscation, in the fixing of the
appellant company's gas rates by public authority. P.
265 U. S.
405.
2. In determining the amount deductible for accrued depreciation
when valuing the property of a public utility for the purpose of
testing the adequacy of rates during a period already elapsed,
estimates of competent experts based on examination of the plant
subsequent to the depreciation are preferable to averages based on
assumed probabilities. P.
265 U. S.
406.
Page 265 U. S. 404
3. Where depreciation is due partly to physical causes and
partly to obsolescence resulting from improvements in the plant,
the amounts should be found separately if practicable. P.
265 U. S.
406.
4. Ratemaking is not a function of the courts; their duty is to
examine results and uphold the guaranties which inhibit the taking
under any guise of private property for public use without just
compensation. P.
265 U. S.
415.
5. In a suit to enjoin enforcement of rates as confiscatory, a
claim of a public utility for past services cannot be relegated to
the consideration of a state commission in the future when it
adjusts the rates for future years.
Id.
6. Where a gas company acquired patent rights which proved very
valuable in lessening the cost of producing gas, but necessitated
new outlays and rendered parts of the existing plant obsolescent,
held:
(a) That the true value of the patent rights, and not merely the
money actually paid for them, must be allowed for as part of its
property in gauging the adequacy of rates fixed by a city. P.
265 U. S. 41.
(b) As the obsolescence could not have been long anticipated, it
was not imperative, if possible, that the company should have
provided for it out of the revenues of years preceding those in
question.
Id.
(c) To allow only the cash paid for the patent rights, and
nothing for the obsolete property, in arriving at the rate base
resulted in confiscation.
Id.
273 F. 937 reversed.
Appeals from decrees of the district court dismissing the bill
in three suits brought by the appellant company to prevent the
enforcement of ordinances passed by San Francisco in three
successive years, to reduce the price of gas.
Page 265 U. S. 405
MR. JUSTICE McREYNOLDS delivered the opinion of the Court.
Since 1905, appellant has been the sole producer and general
distributor of heating and illuminating gas in the San Francisco
district. By three separate ordinances passed in June of 1913,
1914, and 1915, the board of supervisors directed it to supply such
gas during the fiscal year commencing July 1st thereafter at not
more than 75 cents per 1,000 feet. Claiming that the rate so
prescribed would not yield fair return, appellant brought suits in
July, 1913, 1914, and 1915 to prevent enforcement of the respective
ordinances. Restraining orders issued upon condition that monthly
statements should show each consumer's account, and bond should be
given to secure proper repayments, with interest. The maximum rate
in the schedule thereafter maintained was eighty-five cents per
1,000.
December 15, 1916, the causes were consolidated and referred to
a master. After taking much testimony, he presented an elaborate
report, March 2, 1920, which recommended dismissal of the bills and
repayment of whatever had been collected above the prescribed rate.
The district court affirmed the report and directed an appropriate
decree.
The master found that not less than seven percentum net upon the
value of the property devoted to public use was necessary for a
fair return; also that, if observed, the prescribed rate would have
yielded more than seven percentum -- for 1913-1914, an excess of
$21,402.95; for 1914-1915, $89,446.12, and for 1915-1916,
$171,464.48.
We think the evidence supports the finding that a net return of
seven percentum was necessary in order to avoid confiscation.
The inventory of the many items making up appellant's
manufacturing and distributing plant, with their reproduction
Page 265 U. S. 406
cost new, was agreed upon by the parties. In order to determine
accrued depreciation and ascertain true values during the years
1913-1916, the master applied the "modified sinking fund method."
Concerning this he said: it involves
"an estimate of the lives of the different structural units, and
an annual allowance set aside from the rates received as a reserve
for future replacement on a 5 percent compound interest curve, the
capital basis of return to the owner being depreciated each year in
an amount exactly corresponding with yearly additions to the
reserve. It is assumed that loss of plant units by obsolescence and
inadequacy, as well as by physical decay, can be forecast with
substantial accuracy and provided for in advance of abandonment and
replacement."
Appellant objects to the application of this method, and insists
that depreciation should have been ascertained upon full
consideration of the definite testimony given by competent experts
who examined the structural units, spoke concerning observed
conditions, and made estimates therefrom. As these examinations
were made subsequent to the alleged depreciation for the definite
purpose of ascertaining existing facts, we think the criticism is
not without merit. Facts shown by reliable evidence were preferable
to averages based upon assumed probabilities. When a plant has been
conducted with unusual skill, the owner may justly claim the
consequent benefits. The problem was to ascertain the probable
result of the specified rate if applied under well known past
conditions, not to forecast the probable outcome of a proposed rate
under unknown future conditions.
Counsel do not insist that the estimated accrued depreciation is
"grossly excessive" if confined to the result of physical causes.
But they do maintain that the master should have ascertained and
stated what depreciation was due to such causes and how much
followed obsolescence
Page 265 U. S. 407
resulting from the introduction of certain patented inventions,
and we think such a finding should have been made unless some
undisclosed reason prevented. The claim is that, in order to lower
cost of production, it became necessary to abandon certain valuable
property under conditions not reasonably susceptible of
anticipation. The material and relevant facts ought to be
disclosed.
The objection to the report most seriously urged is that, in his
estimate of total value, the master failed properly to appraise
certain patent rights through which manufacturing costs had been
greatly reduced; also that he failed to make proper allowances for
the successful use of such rights. This objection is well taken.
The following excerpts from the master's long and rather involved
report disclose the contested points with the relevant facts and
indicate his conclusions:
"The company contends that its plant capital, as a basis of
earnings, should suffer no deduction because of supposed
depreciation due to age, but only, if at all, by the amount of
'deferred maintenance.' And where, as here, there have been
abandonments of large units due to obsolescence, the loss should be
reimbursed by amortization over a period of years after, rather
than before, the replacement, this amortization being effected by
dividing the economics resulting from new machines and processes
between owner and consumer, thus allowing a partial reduction in
the rate. . . ."
"Until this case, it had not occurred to me that, so far as
theory is concerned, reimbursement of the owner could take place
after abandonment. It would not seem fair if it involved a raise of
rates. Physical depreciation, for example, if an accumulation is
necessary to provide for replacement, ought to be provided
beforehand from the rates of users of the service which caused the
machine to wear out. But where replacement is made on account of
obsolescence or inadequacy and economy is effected in
Page 265 U. S. 408
costs, that economy can with fairness be devoted to
reimbursement for the replacement cost, the rates remaining
unchanged. I know of no well considered method to meet this
reimbursement after the fact. The installments would have to
include interest on the unpaid principal, and capital would thus
not be depreciated for purposes of return. An estimate of the
period of amortization would not have to be made if all economics
of the new machine were devoted to the amortization; it would work
itself out. If the economics were shared with the ratepayer, as
plaintiff here suggests, the period should not extend beyond the
estimated life of the new machine, a plan which is subject to the
objection on the grounds of uncertainty common to all such
estimates. . . ."
"But where, as here, and as is generally the case, there is
nothing to show what, if any, consideration has been given the
question of depreciation methods by the state authorities, or
anything beyond a bare schedule of rates to be charged, then the
court must determine the proper methods by its own independent
judgment. I have tried to make it clear that, in the usual case,
the modified sinking fund method would seem most applicable.
Notwithstanding this, in cases where it had not been the practice
to accumulate a reserve, and where the cost of replacements has
shown itself to be a fairly uniform amount, or a fairly uniform
percentage of income or of capital, then there is no objection in
sound reasoning, nor, as I believe, in the law as laid down, why
the court should not adopt a replacement method in determining
proper costs of production, and in such event it would rate at
replacement cost new to determine the owner's reasonable return and
include actual average replacement requirements in the yearly
costs, without reserves. Or it might figure on a reserve for part
of the plant, and a replacement method for the balance apparently
adapted to it. Conceivably, also, the court might amortize the loss
by obsolescence
Page 265 U. S. 409
after abandonment had taken place, as plaintiff urges here. But
I imagine that any court will feel the same hesitation in so doing
that I feel here, for it involves reimbursement as to structures no
longer in the inventory of units in service, and is without
precedent except where the rate fixing body has laid it down as a
proper policy. . . ."
"Mr. E. C. Jones, chief gas engineer of plaintiff, also
testified that the plant was worth cost new less only the deferred
maintenance and the amount of abandonments immediately in prospect.
He estimates the amount of this deduction at $828,916.41 (Exhibit
43), or 6.3 percent of his appraisement at $13,066,201.55 (Exhibit
3). His estimate includes no consideration of approaching
obsolescence; it does include replacement reasonably in view due to
physical deterioration and to ordinary inadequacy. . . ."
"I have referred several times to plaintiff's contention that
obsolescence should be amortized after, rather than before,
abandonment of a unit of plant. Specifically applied, it is urged
that, when it is seen that Martin station or other obsolete
generator has been superseded by new Jones generators, using the
improved Jones process for oil gas, the demonstrated economics
thereby effected are justly to be devoted to reimbursing the
company for the loss of capital occasioned by the obsolescence,
continuing each year until the loss is made good, with interest. On
this settled program, the new generator would, of course, be rated
for return at replacement cost new at all times. To give the
consumer a part of the advantages of the improvement, the company
proposes that only half of the very considerable economics of
operation shall be devoted to its reimbursement. Many advantages
are urged for this plan: that it throws upon the consumer, who has
the benefit of the new equipment in the shape of reduced charges,
the burden of the loss by supersession of equipment
Page 265 U. S. 410
otherwise in good condition; that it avoids the defect that is
inherent in a system of setting aside reserves in advance of
abandonment -- namely, that, while the life of a depreciable unit
is difficult enough to estimate when physical decay alone is
considered, it is practically impossible to forecast when we
consider that obsolescence and inadequacy, which usually account
for abandonments in a gas manufacturing plant, follow no rules as
to time of their operation; that, finally, progress in service is
promoted by giving a gas company an incentive to improvement of its
machinery and its processes in the shape of increased profits. It
must be admitted that, if replacement of an old machine has not
been sufficiently provided for by reserves in advance, a company
will naturally defer installing a new machine, and so progress is
halted. It is, furthermore, true that the application of the usual
formula, fair return on fair present value of the plant in service,
gives to the consumer all the advantages of economics in operating
costs, which plainly is not entire justice. The city's counsel
agrees (Argument 451) that, if obsolescence had occurred suddenly,
with no opportunity to create reserves for replacement, the loss
should be amortized after abandonment; but he denies that the facts
here conform to the hypothesis. . . ."
"Mr. E. C. Jones, chief gas engineer of plaintiff, and his son,
Mr. Leon B. Jones, assistant gas engineer, on an application filed
May 23, 1912, were, on March 10, 1914, granted United States
Letters Patent for an improved apparatus for manufacturing oil gas,
and on October 19, 1915, on an application also filed May 23, 1912,
were granted letters for the process. On November 30, 1915, they
granted to plaintiff the exclusive right to use the process, and to
make and use, but not to sell, the apparatus, together with future
improvements in either process or apparatus made during the lives
of the patents, the rights granted being transferable, but
restricted as to place
Page 265 U. S. 411
to a number of named counties in Northern and Central
California. Despite the late date of the grant, plaintiff's
beneficial right covered the period in suit, for the prior
installation of generators embodying the Jones patents at the
Metropolitan and the Potrero stations, with the patentees' consent,
conferred an implied license to use them during their life in the
San Francisco district; but this license was not exclusive. The
contract underlying the grants (Exhibit 61) recited that the
company had permitted the patentees to use its plant and facilities
for experimentation and commercial demonstration of their
inventions, had expended in alterations in its Metropolitan plant a
sum exceeding $100,000, and also had expended in erecting two new
gas generators at the Potrero station embodying the inventions a
sum exceeding $215,000, that continued operation of all said new or
altered apparatus under the patentees' direction had demonstrated
the great utility and value of the inventions and that they could
be utilized 'to the great pecuniary advantage' of the plaintiff
company, that the company had allowed the patentees to exhibit the
apparatus to many persons interested in gas manufacture in this
country and Europe as a demonstration of the utility and value of
their inventions, and that the patentees regarded the privilege of
future such exhibitions as of great value to them. It was then
agreed that, for the grants first above referred to, the company
would pay the patentees the sum of $46,066.67, and would allow full
opportunity for future exhibition of the generators, and so
forth."
"The question is at what figures these rights of the company
shall be taken into the rating base. It seems to be agreed that the
amount actually paid in 1915 is already represented in the amount
hitherto added as additions and betterments."
"The presentation of plaintiff's case in the form approved by
its counsel does not primarily involve the giving
Page 265 U. S. 412
of a value to these patent rights. Counsel, in argument, stated
in substance that the evidence as to their value seemed to involve
such enormous sums that he preferred the more conservative course
of giving them consideration in his conception of the proper
treatment of losses by obsolescence. It will be remembered that his
argument was that no new invention would be installed by a man of
business unless its savings were available to him to recoup losses
of capital abandoned to make way for it, that the patent monopoly
would enable him to compel a price adequate for his recoupment, and
that, in a proceeding like this, it was equitable to divide the
savings with the consumer and apply the company's share to
reimbursement of the loss by abandonment, meanwhile rating the new
property at value new. I have said that there was strength of
reason in this plan, but that it involved a matter of
administrative policy that was primarily for the state's regulatory
body. I have not followed this plan for this reason, and for the
further reason that it appeared obsolescence could have been
foreseen and provided for, and apparently had been provided for.
This means that the question of value of the rights must be now
considered."
"The evidence is not very full on the part of plaintiff. And due
perhaps to plaintiff's position as to obsolescence, there was
little cross-examination by the city, and no contrary evidence.
With oil at 68 1/2 cents a barrel to plaintiff during the years
1912-16, Mr. Bridges estimates the savings under the Jones process
at 2 1/2 cents a thousand feet of gas manufactured. (Exhibit 62.)
In Table X of his supplemental argument, Mr. Bosley estimates the
savings shown by the evidence at 2+ cents for the first two years
and over 4 cents for the year 1915-16, or, in sum total,
$103,530.39 for 1913-14, $132,419.45 for 1914-15, and $258,557.81
for 1915-16. A just criticism of these estimates is that they give
no influence to the
Page 265 U. S. 413
economics due to larger production. Mr. Britton, general manager
of plaintiff, speaking of results attained in 1916-17, testifies
that the new Jones generators effected a saving of two gallons of
oil per thousand feet of gas and over one cent a thousand in labor
costs of manufacture. (Tr. 2248 seq.) Projecting the savings over
the 16 remaining years of the letters patent, he computes the
aggregate savings at $7,630,300. (Tr. 2251.) Mr. Vincent computes
the present worth on June 30, 1916, of these future savings at
$4,203,300. (Exhibit 67.) While apparently the estimates are made
on conservative bases, it is, of course, true that forecasts like
this are full of uncertainties -- for example, oil may rise to a
price prohibitive for gas consumption on the present scale, or
other intentions or even substitutes for gas may diminish the value
of the Jones patent."
"There is no doubt that these patents are property, and of great
value. It is also true, I think, that justice demands that the
utility company should profit in some substantial proportion by the
economics brought about by its ability in management or its
improvements in methods of manufacture. There is no good reason why
the consumers should get all the advantages that are the fruit of
the genius of these inventors. If, by the terms of their
employment, Mr. Jones and his son had been bound to assign their
patents to plaintiff without further compensation, and had done so,
the city could not justly claim that the company should have no
part of the savings effected. The patents would have to be valued.
But, in view of the fact that the company and the patentees,
dealing presumably at arms' length, have reached a figure of about
$46,000 as the value of exclusive rights throughout Northern
California, I am as much embarrassed as was plaintiff's counsel in
concluding that, in San Francisco alone, the rights are to be
valued for purposes of return at $4,000,000 or any substantial
Page 265 U. S. 414
fraction of that sum. And how are we to compare in value the
full rights obtained by express grant in 1915 and the restricted
rights arising by implied license in the prior years? In view of
the state of the evidence, it seems to me better to pass the whole
matter for future consideration in connection with the rates of
later years, when the state commission can pass on it with full
evidence before it. On the record before me, I do not see my way
clear to add any figure to the rating base on account of these
patent rights. . . ."
"Objections Nos. 8, 9 and 10 have to do with the valuation of
plaintiff's rights under the Jones patents. Plaintiff is incorrect
in stating that the master failed to find the present value of the
patent rights. These were allowed in capital value as stated, page
85, at $46,066.67, the amount paid the grantors in 1915. If the
plaintiff had paid the inventors, say $500,000, or other
considerable sum, for these patent rights, there is no reason to
doubt that this figure would have been accepted as the valuation
for purposes of return. It is not my view that a valuation must
follow cost, although it is more apt to do so where the purchase
was recently made. I have stated as fully as I could the reasons
why I could not find the immensely greater figure which plaintiff
claims. Briefly, the evidence was entirely too speculative. There
is, after all, in such a policy no particular restriction to
enterprise in denying to stockholders the fruits of valuable
inventions, because the stockholders do not function in the
direction of enterprise. The way to reward enterprise is to pay
large sums to inventors, but that is not the question here. In a
supplementary argument, counsel asks me to apply here the rule
which prevails in patent accountings, where, when damages cannot be
ascertained by reference to an established royalty, the master is
permitted to determine from all the evidence what would have been a
reasonable royalty. The qualification to this rule is, however,
that
Page 265 U. S. 415
the master must have some evidence upon which his mind can work
and rely, and that is to a large degree lacking here, save insofar
as it is given by the amount of the purchase price. The objections
named are accordingly overruled."
Obviously, under the theory accepted below, appellant worsened
its situation for ratemaking purposes when it reduced the cost of
manufacturing gas. Introduction of successful patented inventions
enabled the public authorities to lower the rate base and gather
all the benefits. The operating plant, made capable of producing
gas at smaller cost, was declared less valuable than before. The
result indicates error somewhere, either in theory or application
of principle.
Obsolescence of one or more stations and perhaps other property
theretofore of great value (possibly $800,000) followed
installation of the patents, but the remaining plant plus the
patents gave better results. As an operating unit, the new
combination had greater value than the old; but the court below
disregarded the demonstrated worth of the element which wrought
this change.
The obsolescence in question did not result from ordinary use
and wear. Certainly it could not have been long anticipated -- the
patents were of recent conception; to provide for it out of
previous revenues was not imperative, if possible. Former consumers
were not beneficiaries; only subsequent ones could be
advantaged.
Our concern is with confiscation. Ratemaking is no function of
the courts; their duty is to inquire concerning results and uphold
the guaranties which inhibit the taking of private property for
public use without just compensation under any guise. We may not
therefore relegate appellant's claim for past services to the
future consideration of the state commission, as the master
suggests. After adopting the reduced costs of manufacture for
estimating net returns, the court gave no proper
Page 265 U. S. 416
valuation to the inventions which caused the reduction, and
thereby permitted property to be taken without just compensation.
The amount of money actually paid to the inventors was not the
proper measure of worth. Experience had demonstrated a much higher
one, and to obtain the benefit of their use, appellant sacrificed
much.
Installation of the inventions necessitated new outlay of money
and abandonment of property theretofore valuable -- both were
necessary in order that the cost of manufacture might be reduced.
If appellant's permissible profits depend upon the lowered costs
and it is denied adequate return upon property which made the
reduction possible, or recompense for the obsolescence, successful
efforts to improve the service will prove extremely disadvantageous
to it.
Whether, under the peculiar circumstances here presented, the
rate base should be fixed by adding to the agreed inventory some
fair valuation of the patent rights, or whether prompt recoupment
should be allowed for the obsolescence caused by their
introduction, or whether appellant should be saved from actual
ultimate loss by some other feasible method we will not undertake
to determine upon the present record. To the end that the issues
may be reconsidered in view of this opinion, the decree below is
reversed, and the cause remanded for such further proceedings as
the circumstances require, including another reference to the
master if deemed advisable.
Reversed.
MR. JUSTICE HOLMES, dissenting.
I am of opinion that the decree should be affirmed on the main
point for reasons that will be stated by my Brother BRANDEIS.
MR. JUSTICE BRANDEIS, dissenting.
These cases were tried together. Each challenges as confiscatory
an ordinance of the city of San Francisco
Page 265 U. S. 417
fixing, for a single year, the price to be charged for gas. The
rule of
Smyth v. Ames, 169 U. S. 466, was
applied. The evidence, in condensed form, comes before us in a
record of 943 pages. The master's original and supplemental reports
occupy 131 pages. The master and the court found the rates to be
compensatory. Three errors are assigned by the company which relate
to depreciation. The facts applicable to the several years differ
in part, but the same questions are presented in each. It will tend
to clarity to discuss these with reference to the facts of No. 34,
which involves the rate for the year beginning July 1, 1913.
First. The depreciation charge allowed for that year
for the plant as a whole was $348,853. The company does not
complain that this allowance is too small, if treated as an
allowance for merely physical observed depreciation. Its claim is
that an improved process, which had been introduced at the San
Francisco works in 1912 resulted in a saving, during the year
1913-14, of $103,530 in oil and labor; that, in 1913, it had become
certain that this process would later render obsolete certain parts
of the plant (called stations) which were in use throughout that
year, and that, for the purpose of meeting this expected loss in
capital through later abandonment of stations, the savings effected
by the new process should have been charged against the earnings,
and credited to a special depreciation reserve. If, as suggested
below, the company's contention is that only one-half of the
savings should be credited to this special depreciation reserve,
the action of the district court on this ground is obviously free
from objection. For in fact there was included in the year's
depreciation charge, for obsolescence of these stations, $64,962,
which is more than one-half of the year's savings. But its claim
here is that the whole of the savings of the year 1913-14 should
have been so applied, and that therefore the balance thereof,
namely, $38,568, should
Page 265 U. S. 418
also have been included in this special depreciation charge.
[
Footnote 1]
The sum ($348,853) allowed as the depreciation charge for the
year 1913-14 was nearly 3 percent of the then reproduction cost new
of the whole plant, other than land. The master and the court found
as facts that none of the plant was abandoned during that year,
that the change in the process of manufacture was not
revolutionary, that, in view of the history of the art, such change
or improvements, and resulting obsolescence of parts of the plants,
should have been foreseen, that in fact there had been accumulated
during the four years preceding 1912, as a general reserve for
depreciation, the sum of $2,116,433.95, that this reserve had been
charged off by the company to surplus in November, 1911, and that,
but for this fact, it would have been available to meet the loss of
capital which occurred later through the abandonment of
stations.
This alleged error does not present any question of law. Whether
more of the savings of the year 1913-14 due to the introduction of
the new process should have been allowed as a special depreciation
charge for the obsolescence then known to be accruing is clearly a
question of fact. T here is much conflict in the theories on
which
Page 265 U. S. 419
depreciation should be figured. [
Footnote 2] There was doubt when the obsolescence would
culminate, and what would be its extent. There was conflict in the
evidence as to the rate to be deemed a fair return. Whether a
return of 7 percent is the proper test of a compensatory rate must
obviously depend in part upon whether the return includes any of
the risk of obsolescence. [
Footnote
3] I cannot say that the master and the court erred in their
conclusion of fact that, all things considered, the depreciation
charge allowed was adequate. The same is true of the depreciation
charges allowed for the years 1914 and 1915. [
Footnote 4]
Page 265 U. S. 420
Second. As an alternative to allowing a larger
depreciation charge out of the year's savings through the improved
process and apparatus, the company urges that the rate base should
have been increased by adding thereto the value of the right to use
the new process at the San Francisco works. [
Footnote 5] The court apparently adopted this view
of the law. It ruled that the company was entitled to a return upon
the then value (as part of the rate base) of the right to use the
inventions. It differed from the company only in the estimate of
the value. The company's experts declared that the value of this
right might be ascertained by capitalizing the average annual
savings expected to be effected thereby. So calculated, the value
is $4,203,300. The court found specifically that it could not
accept estimated savings as a measure of value; among other
reasons, because the amount of savings was dependent in large
measure upon the price of crude oil, and that this price fluctuates
largely from time to time. It included in the rate base for 1913-14
the value of the gas generators (at the Metropolitan plant) which
had been reconstructed so as to embody the inventions, and found
that there was in
Page 265 U. S. 421
the record no evidence on which it could give to the right to
use the inventions a greater value than was allowed. So far as
concerns the year 1913-14, the question is merely whether, on the
evidence in the record, the value of the reconstructed generators
(including, of course, the right to use them) was too small.
[
Footnote 6] It appeared that,
for the right to use the inventions, nothing was paid either during
the year 1913-14 or during the year 1914-15, and that, for the
exclusive right to use them both in San Francisco and throughout a
number of counties in Northern California, the company paid to the
inventors, in November, 1915, $46,066.68. I cannot say that the
master and the district court erred in the finding of fact by which
they valued this item for that year, or in the value assigned to
the right in fixing the rate base for either of the two following
years. [
Footnote 7] This
alternative contention of the company presents, obviously, no
question of law.
Third. The reproduction cost new of the manufacturing
and distributing plant, other than land, was found to be
$12,794,008; the accrued depreciation, $1,518,390
Page 265 U. S. 422
(as of June 30, 1914). Thus, the property was found to be worth
88.1 percent of its then reproduction cost. The company contends
that the accrued depreciation should have been set at $828,916.41,
so that the plant was worth 93.7 percent of its then reproduction
cost. The master employed the "compound interest" or "modified
sinking fund" method of estimating accrued depreciation. The plant
is in part very old. The depreciation found is but a small
percentage of the reproduction cost. The evidence bearing upon the
amount to be deducted for accrued depreciation occupies 232 pages
of the record. The discussion thereof in the master's report
occupies 39 pages. There was a conflict of evidence.
No question of law is presented by this assignment of error.
[
Footnote 8] The company's
objection is not to the particular method selected, but that, in
applying it, the master included as depreciation what is called
theoretical inadequacy and obsolescence. Whether he did is a
question of fact. The city denies that the reduction in value made
by the master on account of accrued depreciation includes any sum
representing expected loss through future abandonment of the
stations. It is clear that, if any deduction was made on account of
the probable abandonment of the stations, the obsolescence thus
provided for was not theoretical. The new process had been
introduced two years before the date as of which the valuation was
made. On the facts then known, it was expected that the stations
would have to be abandoned in the
Page 265 U. S. 423
near future. Because it was to be expected (and was not
theoretical), the company contended that to offset it, more of the
year's savings should have been charged against the income of that
year. I cannot say that the master and the court erred in their
findings of fact as to the amount of accrued depreciation.
This litigation has already extended over 11 years. The record
discloses that the cases were presented below by competent counsel
with the aid of competent experts, and that they received careful
consideration by an able master and an able trial judge. Counsel,
master, and court have throughout endeavored to apply the rule of
Smyth v. Ames, 169 U. S. 466. It
was not shown that the rule has in any respect been departed from.
This Court harbors a doubt whether, in applying it, some injustice
may not have been done to the company. Is it probable that a nearer
approach to justice as between the parties will be attained by a
continuation of the effort to apply the same rule? To me it seems
that the doubt is inherent in the rule itself. It can be overcome
only by substituting some other rule for that found to be
unworkable. Such other lies near at hand, and it is consistent with
the Constitution.
It was settled by
Knoxville v. Knoxville Water Co.,
212 U. S. 1, that
every public utility must, at its peril, provide an adequate amount
to cover depreciation. A depreciation charge resembles a life
insurance premium. The depreciation reserve, to which it is
credited, supplies insurance for the plant against its inevitable
decadence, as the life insurance reserve supplies the fund to meet
the agreed value of the lost human life. To determine what the
amount of the annual life insurance premium should be is a much
simpler task than to determine the proper depreciation charge. For
life insurance is a cooperative undertaking. The premium to be
fixed is not that required by the probable duration of the life of
a
Page 265 U. S. 424
single insured individual, but that required by the average
expectancy of life of men or women of the given age. Moreover, for
human lives, mortality tables have been constructed which embody
the results of large experience and long study. By their use, the
required premium may be fixed with an approximation to accuracy.
But, despite the relative simplicity of the problem, it was found
that the variables leave so wide a margin for error that premiums
fixed in accordance with mortality tables work serious injustice
either to the insurer or to the insured. Although the purpose was
to charge only the appropriate premium, the transaction resulted
sometimes in bankruptcy of the insurer, sometimes in his securing
profits which seemed extortionate, and, rarely in his receiving
only the intended fair compensation for the service rendered.
Because every attempt to approximate more nearly the amount of
required premium proved futile, justice was sought by another
route. Ultimately, strictly mutual insurance was adopted. Under it,
the premium charged is made clearly ample, and the part thereof
which proves not to have been needed inures in some form to the
benefit of him who paid it.
Compare Penn Mutual Life Insurance
Co. v. Lederer, 252 U. S. 523,
252 U. S.
524-525.
Legal science can solve the problem of the just depreciation
charge for public utilities in a similar manner. Under the rule
which fixes the rate base at the amount prudently invested, the
inevitable errors incident to fixing the year's depreciation charge
do not result in injustice either to the utility or to the
community. If, when plant must be replaced, the amount set aside
for depreciation proves to have been inadequate, and investment of
new capital is required, the utility is permitted to earn the
annual cost of the new capital. If, on the other hand, the amount
set aside for depreciation proves to have been excessive, the
income from the surplus reserve
Page 265 U. S. 425
operates as a credit to reduce the current capital charge which
the rates must earn. If a new device is adopted which involves
additional investment (to buy a new plant or a patent right), the
company's investment, on which the return must be paid, is
increased by that amount. If the new device does not involve new
investment, but the innovation involves increased current payments
(like royalties for use of a process), the additional disbursement
is borne by the community as an operating expense. The cost of a
scrapped plant is carried as part of the investment on which a
return must be paid unless and until it has been retired, that is
fully paid for, out of the depreciation reserve. Thus, justice both
to the owners of the utility and to the public is assured.
[
Footnote 1]
In this connection, the confiscatory character of the rate
rests, according to the test applied, upon the allowance or
disallowance of a much smaller sum. For master and court have found
that the earnings of the year 1913-14 exceeded 7 percent upon the
rate base by more than $21,000. An additional allowance for
depreciation of $17,000 would therefore (even on the theory
contended for by the company) have rendered the rate compensatory
on a 7 percent basis. Moreover, a 6 percent rate was sustained in
Stanislaus County v. San Joaquin & Kings River Canal &
Irrigation Co., 192 U. S. 201
(1904),
Knoxville v. Knoxville Water Co., 212 U. S.
1 (1909), and
Cedar Rapids Gaslight Co. v. Cedar
Rapids, 223 U. S. 655.
[
Footnote 2]
The wide differences between engineers as to the proper method
to be pursued is well known.
See Southwestern Bell Telephone
Co. v. Public Service Commission, 262 U.
S. 276,
262 U. S.
294.
[
Footnote 3]
See Gerard C. Henderson, Railway Valuation and the
Courts, 33 Harv.L.Rev. 902, 916, 922, 923; John Bauer, Valuation of
Public Utility Properties, 30 Pol.Sci.Q. 254, 275; R.S. Hale,
Physical Valuation of Public Utilities, 45 Engineering Mag. 161,
163.
[
Footnote 4]
Appellant contends here that, due to the new method of
manufacture, property of which the reproduction cost was
$844,355.74 would become obsolete, that the total depreciation
allowance covering this property for the three years was only
$275,096, and that the difference -- called net loss to the
appellant -- should be amortized by applying the savings to be
effected by the new method of manufacture. But the first
abandonment of stations occurred at the end of June, 1915. The
estimated loss on the Martin station, then abandoned, was $237,651.
No further supersession occurred during the period of litigation.
There was merely the prediction made at the trial by the company's
experts that the Independent station would be abandoned in
December, 1918, and the Potrero plant in December, 1920. Moreover,
for the year 1914-15, the depreciation charge allowed was $372,680.
Included in this amount is $68,198, directly attributable to loss
caused by abandonments. The alleged savings from the new process
for that period was $132,419. Thus, the amount allowed exceeded the
one-half of the year's saving which was suggested below as the
proper measure of the appropriate charge. The increase in
depreciation charge contended for here is $64,221. But the earnings
for this year exceeded 7 percent on the rate base by more than
$89,000, leaving a difference more than sufficient to cover this
claim. The year 1915-16 can be similarly disposed of. The
depreciation charge allowed was $380,519. The alleged savings from
the new process for that year was estimated at $258,557. The
increase in depreciation charge contended for here is $208,319. But
one-half of the year's savings is $129,279, and the earnings for
the year exceeded 7 percent on the rate base by $171,464.
[
Footnote 5]
The process and apparatus had been invented by the company's
salaried engineers early in 1912. The cost of experiments were
defrayed by it. The utility of the invention was proved in that
year at its expense, by reconstructing, during that year, two of
its gas generators and making other changes in plant. In this way,
the company acquired an implied license to use the inventions.
Wade v. Metcalf, 129 U. S. 202;
Dable Grain Shovel Co. v. Flint, 137 U. S.
41. It did not acquire an express license until November
30, 1915 -- that is, shortly after the patent for the apparatus was
granted.
[
Footnote 6]
The question is not one of continuing importance to the parties.
Its correctness depends upon the state of the particular record.
Any defect in this record can be avoided in proceedings concerning
the rates for any year after June 30, 1916, and, since October 29,
1917, the gas rates for San Francisco are fixed not by city
officials, but by the state railroad commission.
[
Footnote 7]
The year 1914-15 presents no change in the situation from the
preceding year. For 1915-16, the value of the two new Jones oil gas
generators installed in the Potrero plant at a cost of $241,812.59
is included in the rate base, and as the value of the right to use
the inventions the $46,066.68 paid. For this period, therefore, the
question is merely whether, on the evidence in the record, the
patents should have been valued at a sum in excess of $46,066.68.
But, for both years, only a large undervaluation would affect the
result, as the master and the court found that, during the year
1914-15, the prescribed rate would yield $89,446 in excess of a
seven percent return on the rate base, and for 1915-16, an excess
of $171,464.
[
Footnote 8]
We have no occasion to undertake a legal delimitation of the
function of a depreciation charge, or to define its legal relations
to the depreciation reserves, or to determine whether the loss
through the abandonment of a station in 1915 and that expected to
result from later abandonments might be set off against the
depreciation reserve accumulated shortly before the invention of
the new process.