1. A trader does not violate the Sherman Act by simply refusing
to sell his goods or by withholding them from those who do not sell
them at the resale prices he fixes, but he may not, by contracts or
combinations express or implied, unduly hinder or obstruct the free
and natural flows of interstate commerce. P.
257 U. S.
452.
2. The public policy evinced in the Sherman Act is to be
considered in determining what are "unfair methods of competition"
within the Federal Trade Commission Act. P.
257 U. S.
453.
3. A plan of merchandising, in interstate trade which has a
dangerous tendency unduly to hinder competition or to create
monopoly the Federal Trade Commission has authority to order
suppressed. P.
257 U. S.
454.
4. The respondent manufacturer, for the purpose of maintaining
resale prices fixed by itself, declined to sell its products to
jobbers, wholesalers, or retailers who did not observe them or who
sold to other dealers who failed to do so, and, to enforce this
policy, obtained,
Page 257 U. S. 442
by the cooperation of it customers and through it agents and
salesmen, and by marking and tracing the cases of its good, the
names of dealers who cut the prices or who sold to others who did
so, and enrolled them as undesirable customers to whom it did not
sell until they gave satisfactory assurances of their purpose to
conform in the future. By these means, it was enabled to suppress
competition in the disposition of it products after it had old them
by preventing all who did not conform to the resale price from
obtaining more goods, although there was no contract for fixing,
maintaining or enforcing the resale prices.
Held that
these or any other equivalent cooperative means should be enjoined,
upon an order of the Federal Trade Commission, as an unfair method
of competition. P.
257 U. S.
454.
264 F. 885 reversed.
Certiorari to review a judgment of the circuit court of appeals
setting aside an order of the Federal Trade Commission.
Page 257 U. S. 443
MR. JUSTICE DAY delivered the opinion of the Court.
This case is here upon a writ of certiorari to the United States
Circuit Court of Appeals for the Second Circuit, which court set
aside an order of the Federal Trade Commission requiring the
Beech-Nut Packing Company, a corporation engaged in the manufacture
and sale of food and other products throughout the United States,
to
Page 257 U. S. 444
cease and desist from carrying out a plan of resale of its
products.
* Beech-Nut
Packing Co. v. Federal Trade Commission, 264 F. 885.
The Commission condemned the plan as an unfair method of
competition within the meaning of § 5 of the Federal Trade
Commission Act. 38 Stat. 719.
In the original complaint, it was charged that, in order to
accomplish the illegal purpose intended, the Beech-Nut Company
required its purchasers to agree to maintain or resell such
products at standard selling prices, and that, for the purpose of
maintaining such standard resale prices and for the purpose of
inducing and compelling its customers to maintain and keep such
standard prices, the company refused to sell its products to
customers and dealers who would not agree to maintain such
specified standard resale prices, and who did not resell such
products at the specified standard selling prices fixed and
determined by the company. By stipulation before trial, the
complaint was amended so as to charge that the Beech-Nut Company
has adopted and enforced a system of fixing and maintaining certain
specified standard prices at which its chewing gum and food
products shall be
Page 257 U. S. 445
resold by purchasers thereof, including jobbers, wholesalers,
and retailers, with the purpose and effect of securing the trade of
such jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers and of enlisting their
active support and cooperation in enlarging the sale of
respondent's products, to the prejudice of its competitors who do
not require and enforce the maintenance of resale prices for their
products, and with the purpose and effect of eliminating
competition in prices among all jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers, respectively, engaged in handling the products
manufactured by the company, thereby depriving such distributors of
their right to sell, and preventing them from selling its products
at such prices as they may deem to be, and as are, adequate and
warranted by their respective selling costs and efficiency, and
with various other effects, and that the company, as a means of
making effective its system of resale prices and of inducing and
compelling its customers and the dealer customers of its customers
to maintain such resale prices, has for more than two years last
past, made it generally known to jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers, respectively, that it required and insisted that they
should sell its products at the resale prices so fixed by it, and
refused to sell to jobbers, wholesalers, or retailers not
maintaining such prices; that the company threatened to and did
refuse to sell to all jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers who
failed to maintain the resale prices so fixed by it, or who sold to
other distributors who failed to maintain such prices; induced or
compelled the jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers, by divers other
means, not only to maintain its resale prices so fixed, but also to
discontinue selling its products to other jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers who did not maintain such resale prices; that the company
caused the diversion of retailer's orders away from jobbers and
wholesalers who did not maintain such resale prices so fixed by it,
or who
Page 257 U. S. 446
had resold its products to other jobbers, wholesalers, or
retailers who had failed to maintain such resale prices, and caused
such orders to be given to other jobbers and wholesalers who had
maintained such resale prices and/or had refused to supply other
jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers failing to maintain such
prices; that the company solicited and secured the cooperation of
wholesalers, jobbers, and retailers in reporting price-cutters, all
in pursuance of its efforts to ascertain the names of all
distributors of its products who had failed to maintain the resale
prices fixed by it, and/or who had resold to other jobbers,
wholesalers, and retailers failing to maintain such prices; that it
entered in card records kept by it the names of all dealers
reported to it, either in this or other ways, as not maintaining
its resale prices or as selling to other distributors not
maintaining such prices, and has taken various measures to prevent
all such dealers from obtaining further shipments of its products
from any source until it has received from them declarations,
promises, assurances, statements, or other similar expressions, to
the effect that in the future such dealers intend to and will sell
such products at the resale prices fixed by the company and will
refrain from selling the same to other jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers failing to maintain such prices; that respondent employed
various other means and methods for the enforcement of its system
of maintaining resale prices.
The case was heard before the Commission upon an agreed
statement of facts, from which, among other things, it found:
The Beech-Nut Packing Company customarily markets its products
principally through jobbers and wholesalers in the grocery, drug,
candy, and tobacco lines, who in turn resell to retailers in these
lines. Such wholesale and retail dealers are selected as desirable
customers because they are known or believed to be of good credit
standing;
Page 257 U. S. 447
who are willing to resell at the resale prices suggested by the
company and who do resell at such prices; are willing to refuse to
sell and who do refuse to sell to jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers who do not resell at the resale prices suggested by the
company, and who do not sell to such jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers, who in other respects are good and satisfactory
merchandisers. Such jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers are
designated by the company as "selected" or "desirable" dealers. In
a few instances, the company also sells "direct" to certain large
retailers who are selected as the jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers. The total number of such dealers handling the products
of the company includes the greater portion of the jobbers,
wholesalers, and retailers, respectively, in the grocery trades,
and a large proportion of the jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers
in the drug, candy, and tobacco trades, respectively, throughout
the United States.
The company has adopted and maintained, and still maintained at
the time complaint was filed by the Commission, in the sale and
distribution of its products a policy known as the "Beech-Nut
policy," and requests the cooperation therein of all dealers
selling the products manufactured by it, dealing with each customer
separately.
In order to secure such cooperation and to carry out the
Beech-Nut policy the company:
Issues circulars, price lists, and letters to the trade
generally showing suggested uniform resale prices, both wholesale
and retail, to be charged for Beech-Nut products.
Requests and insists that the selected jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers sell only to such other jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers as have been and are willing to resell and do resell at
the prices so suggested by the company, and requests and insists
that such jobbers, wholesalers,
Page 257 U. S. 448
and retailers discontinue selling to other jobbers, wholesalers,
and retailers who fail to resell at the prices so suggested by the
company.
Makes it known broadcast to such selected jobbers, wholesalers
and retailers, whether sold "direct" or not, that, if they, or any
of them fail to sell at the resale prices suggested by the company,
it will absolutely refuse to sell further supplies of its product
to them, or any of them, and will also absolutely refuse to sell to
any jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers whatsoever who sell to
other jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers failing to resell at the
prices suggested by the company.
The company, in the carrying out of its policy, has refused and
does refuse to sell its products to practically all such jobbers,
wholesalers, and retailers as do not sell at the prices so
suggested by it. It has refused and does refuse to sell to
practically all such jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers reselling
to other jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers who have failed to
resell at the prices so suggested by it. It has refused and does
refuse to sell to practically all so-called mail-order houses
engaged in interstate commerce, on the ground that such mail-order
houses frequently sell at cut prices, and has refused and does
refuse to sell to practically all jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers who sell its products to such mail-order houses. It has
maintained and does refuse to sell to practically all so-called
price-cutters. It has maintained and does maintain a large force of
so-called specialty salesmen or representatives who call upon the
retail trade and solicit orders therefrom to be filled through
jobbers and wholesalers, which orders are commonly known in the
trade as "turnover orders;" its salesmen, under respondent's
instructions, have refused and do refuse to accept any such
turnover orders to be filled through jobbers and wholesalers who
themselves sell or have sold at less than the suggested resale
prices, or sell or have sold to jobbers,
Page 257 U. S. 449
wholesalers, and retailers who sell or have sold at less than
such suggested resale prices, and in such cases has requested such
retailers to name other jobbers.
The company has reinstated and does reinstate as distributors of
its products jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers previously cut off
or withdrawn from the list of selected jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers for failure to resell at the prices suggested by it, and
for selling to distributors who do not maintain such suggested
resale prices, upon the basis of declarations, assurances,
statements, promises, and similar expressions, as the case may be,
by such distributors, respectively, who satisfy the company that
such distributors will thereafter resell at the prices suggested by
it and will refuse to sell to distributors who do not maintain such
suggested resale prices.
The company has added and does add to its list of new
distributors concerns reported by its representatives as declaring
that they intend to and will resell at the prices suggested by it,
and will refuse to sell to those who do not maintain such suggested
resale prices. It has utilized a system of key numbers or symbols
stamped or marked upon the cases containing the "Beech-Nut brand"
products, thus enabling it, for any purpose whatsoever, to
ascertain the identity of the distributors from whom such products
were purchased, and that repeatedly, when instances of
price-cutting have been reported to it by the selected wholesalers
and retailers or ascertained in other ways, its salesmen and
representatives have been instructed by it to investigate, and
that, in pursuance of these instructions, they have by means of
these key numbers or symbols traced the price-cutters from whom the
goods have been obtained, and have thus ascertained the identity of
such price-cutters, and have also thus traced and ascertained the
identity of distributors from whom price-cutters have purchased
"Beech-Nut brand" products, and has thereafter refused to
Page 257 U. S. 450
supply all such dealers with its products, whether such dealers
were themselves cutting the suggested resale prices or were selling
to dealers cutting the suggested resale prices.
The company has maintained and does maintain card records
containing the names of thousands of jobbing, wholesale, and retail
distributors, including the selected distributors, and in
furtherance of its refusal to sell goods either to distributors
selling at less than the suggested resale prices or to distributors
selling to other distributors selling at less than the suggested
resale prices, has listed upon those cards, bearing the names of
such distributors, the words "Undesirable-Price Cutters," "Do Not
Sell," or "D. N.S.," the abbreviation for "Do Not Sell," or
expressions of a like character, to indicate that the particular
distributor was in the future not to be supplied with respondent's
goods on account of failure to maintain the suggested resale
prices, or on account of failure to discontinue selling to dealers
failing to maintain such suggested resale prices. When the company
has received declarations, assurances, statements, promises, or
similar expressions, as the case may be, by distributors which
satisfy it that such distributors will resell at the prices
suggested by it and discontinue selling to distributors failing to
maintain the resale prices suggested by it, it has issued
instructions to "clear the record," or directions of similar
import, notation of which is made on the cards, and it has
thereafter permitted shipments of its products to be made to such
distributors, and such distributors to whom shipments are thus
allowed to go forward constitute the company's list of so-called
"selected" jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers, and no distributor
is thus listed on such card record as one to whom goods are allowed
to go forward who fails to maintain the resale prices suggested by
it or sells to distributors failing to resell at such suggested
price, and when a jobber,
Page 257 U. S. 451
wholesaler, or retailer is reported as failing to maintain the
suggested resale prices, and has been entered in the card records
as one to whom shipments should not go forward, respondent notifies
those jobbers, wholesalers, and retailers who supply the
distributor, of this fact, and also notifies its specialty
salesmen, and gives similar notices to such jobbers, wholesalers,
and retailers and to its specialty salesmen when reinstatements are
made in its list of "selected" jobbers, wholesalers, and
retailers.
The circuit court of appeals was of opinion that the only
difference between the price-fixing policy condemned as unlawful in
Miles Medical Co. v. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.
S. 373, and the price-fixing plan embodied in the
Beech-Nut policy was that, in the former case, there was an
agreement in writing, while in this case the success or failure of
the plan depended upon a tacit understanding with purchasers and
prospective purchasers. While it expressed its difficulty in seeing
any difference between a written agreement and a tacit
understanding in their effect upon the restraint of trade, it
nevertheless regarded the case as governed by the decision of this
Court in
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.
S. 300, and accordingly held that the Commission had
exceeded its power in making the order appealed from.
The
Colgate case was prosecuted under the Sherman
Anti-Trust Act, and came to this Court under the Criminal Appeals
Act. We therein held that this Court must accept the construction
of the indictment as made in the district court, and that, upon
such construction, the only act charged amounted to the exercise of
the right of the trader or manufacturer, engaged in private
business, to exercise his own discretion as to those with whom he
would deal, and to announce the circumstances under which he would
refuse to sell, and that, thus interpreted, no act was charged in
the indictment which amounted to a violation of the Sherman Act
prohibiting monopolies,
Page 257 U. S. 452
contracts, combinations, and conspiracies in restraint of
interstate commerce.
In the subsequent case of
United States v. Schrader's Son,
Inc., 252 U. S. 85, this
Court had occasion to deal with a case under the Criminal Appeals
Act wherein there was a charge that a manufacturer sold to
manufacturers in several states under an agreement to observe
certain resale prices fixed by the vendor -- which we held to be a
violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act. In referring to the
Colgate case, we said:
"The court below misapprehended the meaning and effect of the
opinion and judgment in that cause. We had no intention to overrule
or modify the doctrine of
Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. Park &
Sons Co., [
220 U.S.
373], where the effort was to destroy the dealers' independent
discretion through restrictive agreements. Under the interpretation
adopted by the trial court and necessarily accepted by us, the
indictment failed to charge that Colgate & Co. made agreements,
either express or implied, which undertook to obligate vendees to
observe specified resale prices, and it was treated as alleging
only recognition of the manufacturer's undoubted right to specify
resale prices and refuse to deal with anyone who failed to maintain
the same."
In the still later case of
Frey & Son v. Cudahy Packing
Co., 256 U. S. 208,
wherein this Court again had occasion to consider the subject, it
was said of the previous decisions in
United States v.
Colgate and
United States v. Schrader's Son, Inc.,
supra:
"Apparently the former case was misapprehended. The latter
opinion distinctly stated that the essential agreement,
combination, or conspiracy might be implied from a course of
dealing or other circumstances."
By these decisions, it is settled that in prosecutions under the
Sherman Act a trader is not guilty of violating its terms who
simply refuses to sell to others, and he may withhold his goods
from those who will not sell them at the
Page 257 U. S. 453
prices which he fixes for their resale. He may not, consistently
with the act, go beyond the exercise of this right, and by
contracts or combinations, express or implied, unduly hinder or
obstruct the free and natural flow of commerce in the channels of
interstate trade.
The Sherman Act is not involved here except insofar as it shows
a declaration of public policy to be considered in determining what
are unfair methods of competition, which the Federal Trade
Commission is empowered to condemn and suppress. The case now
before us was begun under the Federal Trade Commission Act, which
was intended to supplement previous antitrust legislation.
See Report, No. 597, of the Senate Committee on Interstate
Commerce, June 13, 1914, 63d Congress, 2nd Session. That act
declares unlawful "unfair methods of competition," and gives the
Commission authority, after hearing, to make orders to compel the
discontinuance of such methods. What shall constitute unfair
methods of competition denounced by the act is left without
specific definition. Congress deemed it better to leave the subject
without precise definition, and to have each case determined upon
its own facts, owing to the multifarious means by which it is
sought to effectuate such schemes. The Commission, in the first
instance, subject to the judicial review provided, has the
determination of practices which come within the scope of the act.
See Report, No. 597, Senate Committee on Interstate
Commerce, June 13, 1914, 63d Congress, 2nd Session.
Of the Federal Trade Commission Act, we said, in
Federal
Trade Commission v. Gratz, 253 U. S. 421,
253 U. S.
427:
"The words 'unfair method of competition' are not defined by the
statute, and their exact meaning is in dispute. It is for the
courts, not the Commission, ultimately to determine as matter of
law what they include. They are clearly inapplicable to practices
never heretofore regarded as opposed to good morals because
characterized by deception,
Page 257 U. S. 454
bad faith, fraud, or oppression, or as against public policy
because of their dangerous tendency unduly to hinder competition or
create monopoly. The act was certainly not intended to fetter free
and fair competition as commonly understood and practiced by
honorable opponents in trade."
If the "Beech-Nut system of merchandising" is against public
policy because of "its dangerous tendency unduly to hinder
competition or to create monopoly," it was within the power of the
Commission to make an order forbidding its continuation. We have
already seen to what extent the declaration of public policy
contained in the Sherman Act permits a trader to go. The facts
found show that the Beech-Nut system goes far beyond the simple
refusal to sell goods to persons who will not sell at stated
prices, which in the
Colgate case was held to be within
the legal right of the producer.
The system here disclosed necessarily constitutes a scheme which
restrains the natural flow of commerce and the freedom of
competition in the channels of interstate trade which it has been
the purpose of all the Anti-Trust Acts to maintain. In its
practical operation, it necessarily constrains the trader, if he
would have the products of the Beech-Nut Company, to maintain the
prices "suggested" by it. If he fails so to do, he is subject to be
reported to the company either by special agents, numerous and
active in that behalf, or by dealers whose aid is enlisted in
maintaining the system and the prices fixed by it. Furthermore, he
is enrolled upon a list known as "Undesirable-Price Cutters," to
whom goods are not to be sold, and who are only to be reinstated as
one whose record is "clear" and to whom sales may be made upon his
giving satisfactory assurance that he will not resell the goods of
the company except at the prices suggested by it, and will refuse
to sell to distributors who do not maintain such prices.
Page 257 U. S. 455
From this course of conduct, a court may infer -- indeed, cannot
escape the conclusion -- that competition among retail distributors
is practically suppressed, for all who would deal in the company's
products are constrained to sell at the suggested prices. Jobbers
and wholesale dealers who would supply the trade may not get the
goods of the company if they sell to those who do not observe the
prices indicated or who are on the company's list of undesirables
until they are restored to favor by satisfactory assurances of
future compliance with the company's schedules of resale prices.
Nor is the inference overcome by the conclusion stated in the
Commission's findings that the merchandising conduct of the company
does not constitute a contract or contracts whereby resale prices
are fixed, maintained, or enforced. The specific facts found show
suppression of the freedom of competition by methods in which the
company secures the cooperation of its distributors and customers,
which are quite as effectual as agreements express or implied
intended to accomplish the same purpose. By these methods, the
company, although selling its products at prices satisfactory to
it, is enabled to prevent competition in their subsequent
disposition by preventing all who do not sell at resale prices
fixed by it from obtaining its goods.
Under the facts established, we have no doubt of the authority
and power of the Commission to order a discontinuance of practices
in trading, such as are embodied in the system of the Beech-Nut
Company.
We are, however, of opinion that the order of the Commission is
too broad. The order should have required the company to cease and
desist from carrying into effect its so-called Beech-Nut policy by
cooperative methods in which the respondent and its distributors,
customers, and agents undertake to prevent others from obtaining
the company's products at less than the prices designated by
Page 257 U. S. 456
it -- (1) by the practice of reporting the names of dealers who
do not observe such resale prices; (2) by causing dealers to be
enrolled upon lists or undesirable purchasers who are not to be
supplied with the products of the company unless and until they
have given satisfactory assurances of their purpose to maintain
such designated prices in the future; (3) by employing salesmen or
agents to assist in such plan by reporting dealers who do not
observe such resale prices, and giving orders of purchase only to
such jobbers and wholesalers as sell at the suggested prices and
refusing to give such orders to dealers who sell at less than such
prices, or who sell to others who sell at less than such prices;
(4) by utilizing numbers and symbols marked upon cases containing
their products with a view to ascertaining the names of dealers who
sell the company's products at less than the suggested prices, or
who sell to others who sell at less than such prices in order to
prevent such dealers from obtaining the products of the company; or
(5) by utilizing any other equivalent cooperative means of
accomplishing the maintenance of prices fixed by the company.
The judgment of the circuit court of appeals is reversed, and
the cause remanded to that court, with instructions to enter
judgment in conformity with this opinion.
Reversed.
*
"Now therefore it is ordered that respondent, the Beech-Nut
Packing Company, its officers, directors, agents, servants, and
employees cease and desist from directly or indirectly
recommending, requiring, or by any means bringing about the resale
of Beech-Nut products by distributors, whether at wholesale or
retail according to any system of prices fixed or established by
respondent, and more particularly by any or all of the following
means:"
"1. Refusing to sell to any such distributors because of their
failure to adhere to any such system of resale prices."
"2. Refusing to sell to any such distributors because of their
having resold respondent's said products to other distributors who
have failed to adhere to any such system of resale prices."
"3. Securing or seeking to secure the cooperation of its
distributors in maintaining or enforcing any such system of resale
prices."
"4. Carrying out or causing others to carry out a resale price
maintenance policy by any other means."
MR. JUSTICE HOLMES dissenting.
There are obvious limits of propriety to the persistent
expression of opinions that do not command the agreement of the
Court. But as this case presents a somewhat new field -- the
determination of what is unfair competition within the meaning of
the Federal Trade Commission Act -- I venture a few words to
explain my dissent. I will not recur to fundamental questions. The
ground on
Page 257 U. S. 457
which the respondent is held guilty is that its conduct has a
dangerous tendency unduly to hinder competition or to create
monopoly. It is enough to say that this I cannot understand. So far
as the Sherman Act is concerned, I had supposed that its policy was
aimed against attempts to create a monopoly in the doers of the
condemned act or to hinder competition with them. Of course, there
can be nothing of that sort here. The respondent already has the
monopoly of its own goods with the full assent of the law, and no
one can compete with it with regard to those goods, which are the
only ones concerned. It seems obvious that the respondent is not
creating a monopoly in them for anyone else, although I see nothing
to hinder its doing so by conveying them all to one single vendee.
The worst that can be said, so far as I see, is that it hinders
competition among those who purchase from it. But it seems to me
that the very foundation of the policy of the law to keep
competition open is that the subject matter of the competition
would be open to all but for the hindrance complained of. I cannot
see what that policy has to do with a subject matter that comes
from a single hand that is admitted to be free to shut as closely
as it will. And, to come back to the words of the statute, I cannot
see how it is unfair competition to say to those to whom the
respondent sells and to the world, you can have my goods only on
the terms that I propose when the existence of any competition in
dealing with them depends upon the respondent's will. I see no
wrong in so doing, and, if I did, I should not think it a wrong
within the possible scope of the word unfair. Many unfair devices
have been exposed in suits under the Sherman Act, but to whom the
respondent's conduct is unfair I do not understand.
MR. JUSTICE McKENNA and MR. JUSTICE BRANDEIS concur in this
opinion.
Page 257 U. S. 458
MR. JUSTICE McREYNOLDS dissenting.
With regret, I dissent from the opinion and judgment of the
Court.
This matter was submitted to the Commission upon an agreed
statement of facts, the twelfth clause of which -- the last but one
-- declares:
"12. That the merchandising conduct of respondent heretofore
defined and as herein involved does not constitute a contract or
contracts whereby resale prices are fixed, maintained, and
enforced."
Of course, the Packing Company entered into this stipulation
relying upon the quoted clause, and I am not at liberty either to
disregard it or to minimize the plain import of its words. It is
not a mere conclusion of the Commission, but a definite and
essential admission of record upon which the company rested, and
without which I must conclude a different case might have been
presented.
There is no question of monopoly. Acting alone, respondent
certainly had the clear right freely to select its customers -- to
refuse to deal when and as it saw fit -- and to announce that
future sales would be limited to those whose conduct met with its
approval.
United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.
S. 300;
United States v. Schrader's Son, Inc.,
252 U. S. 85;
Frey & Son v. Cudahy Packing Co., 256 U.
S. 208.
If the solemn stipulation did not expressly negative the
existence of contracts amongst the parties to maintain prices, I
should think the detailed facts sufficient to support a finding
that there were such agreements. But, starting with that plain
negation, I can find no adequate ground for condemning the
respondent.
The very order which the court below is now directed to enter
conflicts with the stipulation between the parties by
presupposing
"methods of cooperation between respondent and the distributors
of its products, especially the cooperative methods by which the
respondent and the
Page 257 U. S. 459
distributors of its products undertake to prevent others from
obtaining such products at less than the prices fixed by
respondent, [by] the cooperation of customers in reporting the
names of dealers who do not observe such resale prices with the
view to prevent their obtaining the products of the Beech-nut
Company thereafter."
How can there be methods of cooperation, cooperative methods, an
undertaking to prevent others, or the cooperation of customers with
a view to prevent others, when the existence of the essential
contracts is definitely excluded?
Having the undoubted right to sell to whom it will, why should
respondent be enjoined from writing down the names of dealers
regarded as undesirable customers? Nor does there appear to be any
wrong in maintaining special salesmen who turn over orders to
selected wholesalers and who honestly investigate and report to
their principal the treatment accorded its products by dealers.
Finally, as respondent may freely select customers, how can injury
result from marks on packages which enable it to trace their
movements? The privilege to sell or not to sell at will surely
involves the right by open and honest means to ascertain what
selected customers do with goods voluntarily sold to them.
Under the circumstances disclosed, constraint upon the freedom
of merchants can only result from withholding trade relations or
threatening so to do. These, when acting alone, respondent may
assume or decline at pleasure, there being neither monopoly nor
attempt to monopolize. And the exercise of this right does not
become an unfair method of competition merely because some dealers
cannot obtain goods which they desire, and others may be deterred
from selling at reduced prices. If a manufacturer should limit his
customers to consumers, he would thereby destroy competition among
dealers, but neither they nor the public could complain.