Where the evidence is strongly conflicting, especial weight
attaches to the findings of a trial court whose judges saw and
heard the witnesses.
Applying this principle, the Court holds, with the court below,
that the evidence does not sustain the charges of unlawful
restraint of interstate commerce in shoe machinery, and monopoly
thereof, in the formation and conduct of the United Shoe Machinery
Company.
In determining whether a combination restrains interstate
commerce injuriously to the public, the foremost inquiry is whether
the interests brought together were competitive.
Where machines were patented and, though used collectively in
the making of a single product, were so far distinct in their
functions that they were practically noncompetitive, a common
control over their manufacture and use
held not obnoxious
to the Anti-Trust Act.
Statements in notices to shareholders and in an agency contract,
made by participants in a combination, explaining its object,
held not to establish unlawful intent in view of the
evidence of what was done, publicity of the statements when made,
lapse of time, and inaction of the government.
Lapse of time, changes of condition due to it and to the
progress of the art, the development of high industrial efficiency,
difficulty or impossibility of restoring antecedent conditions, and
injurious effects that would follow the attempt to grant the relief
prayed are matters to be considered in determining from conflicting
evidence whether a combination should be dissolved.
Unconnected purchases of certain businesses with patent rights,
made by the Company after its formation, are
held, on
conflicting evidence, not to have been intended, nor to have had
the effect, of restraining competition illegally, or to have
brought it obnoxious power. Generally, one has the right to
purchase patents for the protection
Page 247 U. S. 33
or improvement of his own inventions and business and for the
prevention of patent litigation, and such purchases should not be
adjudged to have stifled competition unduly upon speculative
estimates of the potential competitive power of new and untried
inventions.
Upon similar considerations, certain contracts for assignment of
future inventions are also held legitimate.
The charge that the Shoe Machinery Company's power has been
oppressively used is not sustained.
The patent Law gives the patentee the right to exclude others
from the use of his invention, absolutely or upon terms. The
exertion of this right within the field of the patent law is not an
offense against the Anti-Trust Act.
The principle, announced in recent cases, that, when a patented
article is sold, it passes beyond the patent monopoly has no
application where there is no conveyance of title, but a
bona
fide lease of the article.
In a suit to set aside leases of patented machines upon the
ground that they exceed the rights of the lessor as patent owner
and operate to produce results obnoxious to the Anti-Trust Act,
semble that the lessees may be necessary parties.
Defendant supplied its sets of patented machines to shoe
manufacturers on a royalty basis under a system of leases of a
uniform term of 17 years, with conditions for use of each machine
to full capacity; for leasing others of lessor as more work became
available; for use to exclusion of, and forbidding use on work
coming from, machines not so leased; requiring lessee to obtain
certain supplies from lessor only; permitting lessor, for breach of
condition in any lease, to forfeit it and all others, and requiring
lessee thereupon to return machines and pay a charge.
Held:
(1) Upon the evidence, that the leases were entered into by the
lessees voluntarily and without coercion, and that their legality
must be determined apart from a general charge of illegal dominancy
by the corporation which the evidence failed to sustain.
(2) Upon the evidence, that the purpose of the system was to
make the sets of machinery available to customers on easy terms and
promote their efficient and productive operation in connection with
an accessory service furnished by the company, and insure adequate
royalty returns.
(3) That the conditions were within the lessor's patent rights,
and not violative of the Anti-Trust Act.
222 F. 349 affirmed.
Suit to dissolve an asserted combination and conspiracy between
certain companies, makers or dealers in boot and
Page 247 U. S. 34
shoe machinery and the officers of the companies; also to have
declared illegal and canceled certain leases and agreements charged
to be the means of the combination and conspiracy whereby, through
control over the manufacturers of boots and shoes, competition has
been prevented, inventive genius subjected to the designs of the
combiners and conspirators, and auxiliary machines and accessories
controlled and made subsidiary.
The charges are met with denials, with justification that the
conduct which is asserted to be illegal was in promotion of trade,
in natural development of business and in strict compliance with
modern trade progress -- indeed, that there was simply the fusion
of independent and noncompeting businesses, each differing from the
other, and the combination of various elements of machinery covered
by United States patents, and all of it relating to the same art
and the same school of manufactures. And that the leases and
agreements were but the exercise of patent rights, wholly legal and
indeed necessary.
These contentions are displayed in a bill which occupies 46
pages of the record and an answer of equal volume.
The statute of limitations is also pleaded in defense, the
greater part of the acts charged being alleged to have taken place
more than 6 years before the filing of the petition.
Three judges sat in the case, who heard the testimony in open
court. Upon its completion and consideration, a decree was entered
dismissing the bill. Each judge rendered an opinion exhibiting the
case from a different angle, and the opinions, taken together,
display all the phases of the case and the considerations and
issues involved. 222 F. 349.
Page 247 U. S. 35
MR. JUSTICE McKENNA, after stating the case as above, delivered
the opinion of the Court.
The charge of the bill is that defendants, not being satisfied
with the monopoly of their patents and determined to extend it,
conceived the idea of acquiring the ownership or control of all
concerns engaged in the manufacture of all kinds of shoe machinery.
This purpose was achieved, it is charged, and a monopoly acquired,
and commerce, interstate and foreign, restrained by the union of
competing companies and the acquisition of others. And that leases
were exacted which completed and assured the control and monopoly
thus acquired.
But this charge of comprehensive trade dominance was modified in
the course of the trial. The government disclaimed the assertion of
such extensive culpability and confined its contention to machinery
adapted to the bottoming of shoes (attaching soles to uppers),
machines called clicking machines (cutting-out machines), and
eyeletting machines (sufficiently indicated by name), and
Page 247 U. S. 36
declared that, if the bill did not so limit the actual monopoly,
counsel would agree so to limit it.
Of course, we agree with the government that defendants cannot
be discharged from all guilt merely because they leave open some
branches of the business to the enterprise of others, or, as the
government puts it, "that a limited field is as yet open to
competition." But, in view of the large design attributed to the
defendants and the illustration of what it is contended they
accomplished, it would be interesting, if not instructive, to be
told when their large scheme was abandoned or broke down, even
though it may now be said to be an unimportant detail, since the
trial court has decided that neither the greater nor lesser scheme
was established by the evidence.
The conclusion, however, is contested, and in description of
what is now contended, the government says that
"the end which avowedly was sought by the organizers of the
United Company was 'the control in one corporation, both in the
United States and in foreign countries, of the efficient types of
shoe machinery.'"
And further, after stating the business of defendants to be that
"of supplying machines used in the manufacture of shoes," and the
restraint of interstate and foreign commerce in certain of the
machines, it is said:
"The subject matter of the action therefore is the effect of the
things done by the defendants upon the trade between manufacturers
of machines used in the manufacture of shoes and the manufacturers
of shoes."
And in further display of the interest which attaches to the
issues, it is said: "Shoes are made in every part of the Union"
and
"it is obvious that supplying important machines for such an
industry must be an exceedingly important part of the interstate
trade and commerce of the United States."
And there are contentions as to the dominance achieved. Indeed,
it is asserted somewhat fervidly that the United Company "is
absolute monarch of the industry," and
Page 247 U. S. 37
that "no competitor can exist unless, for its own pleasure or
policy, it withholds its destroying hand."
There are opposing contentions no less fervidly urged. There is
denial of the purpose attributed to the defendants or the
possession or exercise of baleful power, and the insistence that
the United Company is a union of noncompeting businesses conducted
under letters patent, effecting through the resources thus acquired
greater economics in manufacture and greater efficiency of
machinery and "in other ways perfecting the shoemaker's art" --
advantages not engrossed by the company, but inuring to its patrons
and through them to the wearers of their product, a finished
shoe.
In final answer to the charge of the government, the
comprehensive declaration is that the shoe machinery industry is
not one open to everybody on equal terms. It is one of patents. And
the company's power, if it have power, is not that of combination,
but the power of the superiority of its inventions -- the effect
and demonstrated supremacy of its mechanical instrumentalities.
The contentions could not well be more antagonistic, upon each
of which there was conflicting testimony, and the important fact is
to be borne in mind that it was given in open court (except as to
certain contentions about patents, their scope and validity).
[
Footnote 1] The fact justifies
deference
Page 247 U. S. 38
to the findings of the trial court.
Adamson v.
Gilliland, 242 U. S. 350,
242 U. S. 353.
There are two accusations against the defendants. One is that,
at the very outset, they combined competing companies and
subsequently acquired others, § 1 of the Act of 1890 [
Footnote 2] being thereby offended. The
other is a monopolization of the trade in violation of § 2 of
that act. And it is charged, as we have said, that certain leases
and license agreements are the instruments which consummate both
offenses.
The offense of combination was committed, it is contended,
February 7, 1899, at which time seven shoe machinery companies were
consolidated into the United Shoe Machinery Company of New Jersey,
a corporation organized for that purpose. The companies were: The
Goodyear Shoe Machinery Company, the International Goodyear Shoe
Machinery Company, Consolidated & McKay Lasting Machine
Company, McKay Shoe Machinery Company, Davey Pegging Machine
Company, Eppler Welt Machine
Page 247 U. S. 39
Company and the International Eppler Welt Machine Company. The
last two companies were acquired by the new company after its
formation, but they may be regarded as constituent companies. The
businesses of these companies were conveyed to the new company, the
businesses being those of manufacturing, selling and leasing and
dealing in shoe machinery, including patents of the United States
and other countries. [
Footnote
3] A more
Page 247 U. S. 40
particular distinction we do not deem it necessary to make.
The first question is, were the companies in competition? It
confronts us at the outset; all other considerations are dependent
upon it. As an element in the answer to it, we must revert to the
admission that the charge of combination is only as to machinery
for bottoming shoes -- that is, the uniting of the sole to the
upper -- an operation which might be called "simple" if the
complexity of this record did not contradict it and if we were not
told that the letters patent covering the machinery for the
operation are too great in number for explanation or enumeration.
It is said that, on certain classes of shoes, over 100 different
operations are performed by different machines. And the government
has taken pains to tell us how far "the mysteries of the
shoemaker's art and the variations between different methods of
making shoes" are outside of the understanding of the purchaser of
them. To him, it is said, "shoes are shoes, except as they differ
in appearance, comfort, wearing qualities, and price." But, to the
manufacturer, distinctions multiply and to the production of a shoe
a complete line of machinery is necessary. Indeed, the government
makes the mystery of the art and the necessity of the
instrumentalities, in part, the basis of its argument.
Page 247 U. S. 41
We are therefore admonished at once of the complexity of the
case and the maze of mechanical technicalities into which we should
be plunged in estimating the evidence if we had not the guidance of
the opinions of the judges of the trial court. The court found, as
we have said, that the companies were not in competition at the
time of their union in the United Company, and based the finding
not only upon the testimony of witnesses but the uses of the
machines of the respective companies and their methods of
operation. The testimony was conflicting, it is true, and different
judgments might be formed upon it, but, from an examination of the
record, we cannot pronounce that of the trial court to be wrong.
Indeed, it seems to us to be supported by the better reason. We
should risk misunderstanding and error if we should attempt to pick
out that which makes against it and disregard that which makes for
it and judge of witnesses from their reported words as against
their living presence, the advantage which the trial court had.
The government, however, urges two circumstances which it
contends corroborate its oral testimony and against which it
asserts that "literal denials of specific intent to restrain trade
are of no significance." But there was more than literal denials.
There were detailed representation of the condition of the trade
and explanation of the machines convincing, as we have seen, in its
strength and the confirmation it received. Let us, however,
consider the instances upon which the government relies. The most
important of them is a circular letter [
Footnote 4] sent by
Page 247 U. S. 42
the directors of the Goodyear Company to its stockholders which
set forth that great advantages were to be secured by the control
in one corporation of the most efficient types of shoe machinery,
and that the directors and large stockholders had been in
negotiation to accomplish that end, and further that the United
Company would from time to time acquire other shoe machinery
properties either by direct ownership or by purchase of shares of
their stock. Also a like declaration [
Footnote 5] in a contract with its agent in Australia.
Page 247 U. S. 43
The circular and agreement could not, of themselves, give
character to the constituent companies. It is evident, therefore,
that both of them need comment to give them sinister significance,
and the innuendo of the government is that they meant not only that
great competing companies had been united, but that other companies
-- competitors, it may be -- would be acquired. It would be a stout
credulity that could accept this explanation against the
counter-considerations. We cannot put out of mind that, according
to the government, in repeated assertions, the United Company in
1899, twelve years before the suit was brought, jumped into the
field full-panoplied in monopolistic power and started immediately
on its career of dominance and restraint of trade. But, to preclude
the denial of the assertions, it is now said that, in stock
circulars and trade agreements, the company trumpeted its might and
illegal enterprise to two continents. Deliberate guilt -- we say
deliberate guilt, for it is not a question of ignorance or
imbecility -- is usually not so bold. It masks its purpose to hide
it from prevention and penalty. If it may be asserted that the
trade agreement was in secret, certainly the circular letter to the
stockholders committed the scheme to publicity.
We cannot, therefore, accept the explanation of the government.
Its implications discredit it. It implies that there was
governmental supineness for a long time or an extraordinary
oversight of conspicuous, indeed vaunted, criminality. Neither can
be accepted. And we are persuaded that the circular and agreement
were not intended nor regarded to be the avowal, as contended by
the government, of monopoly, achieved or to be achieved, but simply
the business expression and foresight of the advantages which would
result from the concentration in one management of
instrumentalities which, however different, supplement one another
in the creation of a shoe.
We have given the explanation of the government importance
Page 247 U. S. 44
because the government has done so. And we have only answered in
estimation of what the circular and agreement are worth as avowals
of intention. Of course, if the government is right, they are
unimportant circumstances; the demonstration of the United
Company's purpose is complete without them, for the government
contends that the constituent companies were in open competition,
and that their union resulted in the "immediate suppression of the
actual and potential competition" in shoe machinery and the
"creation of an organization of vast resources . . . which gave
it a power to extend and entrench its monopoly which none of its
constituent companies, however successful, could approach."
If this were a fact, it would not need the confirmation of
words.
The second circumstance cited by the government is that, before
the union of the companies, their machines had a flexibility in use
that the testimony of defendants does not now ascribe to them, and
that this was declared in advertisements. We are not disposed to
give much importance to the circumstance. It may be that there was
a certain interchangeability in the described machines, but, in the
opinion of the trial court, there was, notwithstanding, no
practical competition between them. We can add nothing to what
determined its judgment or to the detailed comparison and
explanation of the machines made in its opinions. Indeed, we might
rest this branch of the case on those opinions. They were
considerate of all the elements of the government's contentions and
the opposing contentions, and tested the machines, their sameness
and difference and respective efficiency, by the purposes for which
they were designed by the inventors and employed in the trade and
by the explanations made of them.
In considering the competition of the machines and in estimating
the defendants' acts in uniting the companies,
Page 247 U. S. 45
it is to be observed that the machines were all made "under
letters patent of the United States and other countries," were
owned by the companies, and covered improvements made by the
companies from time to time and embodied in the machines, which
were so far developed that they were in 1899 principally in use by
shoe manufacturers in the kinds of work to which they were
respectively adapted. The patents and the business passed to the
new company, but necessarily were the same in its hand as before.
In other words, the patents did not lose their distinction, nor the
machines their difference, and to dwell upon the percentages of
manufacture is misleading. Of a like situation we said in
United States v. Winslow, 227 U.
S. 202,
227 U. S. 217,
and said of it in answer to the charge against the combination here
involved, that we could
"wee no greater objection to one corporation's manufacturing
seventy percent of three noncompeting groups of patented machines
collectively used for making a single product than to three
corporations making the same proportion of one group each. The
disintegration aimed at by the statute [act of 1890] does not
extend to reducing all manufacture to isolated units of the lowest
degree."
Or, as expressed by one of the judges in the court below,
"The combination was not unlawful so far as it did no more than
put the different groups of noncompeting machines into one control.
. . . It was not unlawful unless, to an extent injurious to the
public interest, it destroyed competition."
And it was held that competition was not destroyed to the
designated extent. Indeed, the court was repelled, as it might well
have been, by the consequences of so holding on account of the
change of conditions, the union of the companies not having been
questioned by the government for twelve years and large investments
having been made not only by the company but by the public.
The lapse of time, indeed, may not condone the offense,
Page 247 U. S. 46
if offense there was. It, however, may call offense in question
and be an element in the refutation of accusations long deferred,
or determine against particular remedies. It is to be remembered
that a dissolution of the offending companies is prayed, and that
each of them be "separated into such parts that no one of them will
constitute a monopoly of the shoe machinery business," or that
receivers be appointed to take possession of them and their assets,
business, and affairs and wind them up and "bring about conditions
in trade and commerce among the states and with foreign countries
in harmony with law." If there be need for this, the difficulties
of achievement should not deter; but the difficulties may admonish
against the need, and demonstrate that the situation may be
remediless or to be redressed at a cost too great. Therefore,
considering the remedy prayed, which is extreme, even in its
mildest demands, we may ask, what of the investments that have been
made during these years of extension and development of the new
company's business? What of the machines that have become obsolete
and the new ones that have been developed? What of the patents that
have expired and the new ones that have not yet run out, and how
distribute them? And what of their effect when distributed? Will
their monopoly cease, or be regarded as an instrument of illegal
purpose and forfeited as a deodand? How pick out from the new
conditions the conditions of 1899 and restore them and the art of
that time and rehabilitate the businesses that are alleged to have
ceased to exist or to have become merged in the United Company? How
from the complexity only thus suggested, not displayed, "bring
about conditions in trade and commerce" in shoe machinery "among
the states and with foreign countries in harmony with law," which
is the ultimate resource of the government for this part of the
case? How radical should the disintegration be? Or should there be
a sale in entirety,
Page 247 U. S. 47
and not in parts? And, if in entirety, will the purchaser get an
immunity that the companies did not have? A sale in entirety would
seem to be absolutely necessary to preserve the works at Beverly.
And yet how can that be done if there be a dissolution of the
company and a distribution of machines? On the other hand, the idea
is repellent that so complete an instrumentality should be
dismantled and its concentration and efficiency lost. It has been
testified that the purpose of the organization was the
consolidating of all the machines in one modern factory and the
standardizing of them. This purpose has been attained. The company
employs there 4,000 men.
There are, however, certain instances of acquisition which may
be said to give confirmation to the charges of the government and
justify the demand for redress at whatever cost or disaster to the
offenders; in other words, demonstrate the purpose of the original
union of the companies, the persistence of that purpose and the
extension of its dominion having the evil consequences depicted by
the government. Upon these instances it would seem unnecessary to
dwell, the companies not being competitive at the time of their
union in the United Company. However, they are made so much of by
the government and are so strongly urged that attention must be
given to them. The most important of them and the one that was
given most prominence in the testimony was that of the plant and
machinery of the Thomas G. Plant Company, a New Jersey corporation,
a manufacturer of shoes, not of machinery, and of the shoe
machinery interest of Thomas G. Plant.
Plant was an inventor of machines of the shoe-bottoming variety,
and had taken out a number of letters patent in the United States
and foreign countries covering the same. There was in the testimony
and is in the argument of counsel dispute as to the efficiency of
the machines of themselves. We say "of themselves" to
distinguish
Page 247 U. S. 48
them from the inventions embodied in them, a necessary
distinction to meet some of the phases of the case. A set was
installed in the Plant Company's factory, of which Plant owned a
majority of the stock. Two other concerns to which they were
offered under inducements refused to accept them. It may be
admitted, as the trial court found, that they had experimental
promise, and it was testified that a number of shoe manufacturers
had concerted to buy them. There were charges of infringements of
the United Company's machines, and Plant was loath to permit an
inspection -- indeed, for a time, refused it. And besides, for
their completion into a set for combined operation, important
machines were necessary which were not yet developed. As they
stood, they were undoubtedly inferior to the machines of the United
Company, and in the state therefore in which the United Company
took them, they were not found capable of use. Nothing was in them
which affords reasonable support for the government's contention
that they were "right at the threshold of extensive competition
with the United Company." But suppose they were. It would only be
conjecture to say that they would cross it, or that their strength
would be formidable if they did. It is in the testimony that they
broke down upon trial, and were supplanted in the Plant factory
where Plant had installed them by the United Company's machines.
And the substitution was not at the dictation of the latter
company. The vice-president of the Plant Company and the general
manager of its factory
Page 247 U. S. 49
testified that satisfactory work could not be done with them on
men's shoes; they broke down even in the manufacture of women's
shoes, to which they were adapted.
It appeared that some of the machines infringed the United
Company's, and in some details the latter infringed the Plant,
machines, and the complexity of rights hence resulting, to which we
shall presently refer, had led to and threatened litigation, to
compose which, it was testified and the trial court found, was a
contributory inducement of the United Company's purchase from
Plant.
The government resists the finding. Its conception is, and to
this all of its contentions are addressed, that the United Company
combined and was intended to combine great competing companies and
to acquire other competing companies. "The United Company
acquired," counsel say, "every company then [when the company was
organized] actively putting out or planning to put out" machinery
adapted to bottoming shoes, and that,
"in the twelve years before the bringing of this action, no
substantial change took place, but rather the monopoly so acquired
was, in some respects, extended and in many respects strengthened
and entrenched."
In the light of this conception and contention, the government
sees and colors all that the United Company has done, all of the
acquisitions it has made, and upon whatever motive made, including
the prevention of patent troubles or the composition of litigation.
And it directly says of the purchase from Plant that it was made at
an overvaluation, and by it Plant was tempted to the bargain, and
the United Company satisfied by getting rid of a competitor.
We get no solution of the purpose of the parties by the price
the United Company paid. [
Footnote
6] We must consider what it was paid for. It is to be
remembered that we are dealing with a transaction which took place
eleven years after the formation of that company, and is to be
judged of by its own circumstances, the incentives of that time.
Plant was eager to sell, and the overtures came from him -- indeed,
he engaged two intermediaries, to one of whom he paid a large
commission. There was necessarily negotiation before the final
meeting of minds. To estimate the bargain to it, the United Company
insisted upon an
Page 247 U. S. 50
inspection of the machines -- that is, to estimate their value,
as it was testified, "to the advancing of the art of shoemaking."
[
Footnote 7] Plant refused at
first, as we have said, but later yielded, and, after inspection,
the purchase was consummated. Indeed, there were two inspections.
The report on the first was adverse to the purchase. Mr. Winslow,
president of the United Company, took part in the second, and we
may quote his testimony, for it is the standpoint of that company
we are now considering. His testimony, besides, had confirmation.
He believed, he testified, that he had a broader knowledge of shoe
machinery than anyone else, and he therefore studied the Plant
machines "personally as an expert." He considered them, he said,
from the standpoint of their capacity, the value of the inventions
and the improvements embodied in them, the comparison of their work
with the work of the United Company's machines, and the mechanical
construction of the latter. He further testified that
"Plant had used the Goodyear machines [the United Company's
machines] as a basis for his machines, and made important
improvements and developments."
He indicated one of the improvements in particular, which he
regarded as of the very greatest practical importance, especially
when combined
Page 247 U. S. 51
with a device that the United Company had just developed and
placed in its factories. In a "broad way," he said, the value was
almost incalculable.
But there was an interdependency of values. While the Plant
device had value over that of the United Company's, it was
controlled by the latter, or, as the witness expressed the
situation, "in a broad way, it was a perfect deadlock." In other
words, the United Company had the underlying invention and Plant a
patent for a particular form of operation which was necessarily
subordinate to the other -- a situation familiar in patent law and
contests.
It will be seen, therefore, that there was no other way out of
the deadlock if the inventions were to be used together -- that is,
embodied in one machine, without infringement -- than by ownership
in one hand of all the patents. That plan was adopted, and was the
inducement of the purchase of the Plant inventions by the United
Company. But there was litigation to be composed, as well, and was
composed.
Another witness testified as to the relation of the Plant
patents and those of the United Company, and stated that the
result, if Plant had insisted upon his patent rights and the
company had insisted upon its patent rights, would have been "a
stop in the development of shoe machinery in these lines," and,
continuing, he said:
"We should hardly have dared to go ahead with the improvements
in our machines for fear of not succeeding in our patent
litigation, or of conflicting with such improvements as Plant had
patented. On the other hand, Plant, or any company which he might
form, would have hardly dared to go ahead with the possibility of
these infringement suits. These infringement suits, or a good many
of them, were then pending, and certainly he would have found very
few customers, I think, for his machines."
This, in outline, was the situation that confronted the
Page 247 U. S. 52
parties and induced their transaction, the incentives of each
being as indicated. And they were justifiable incentives, and we
may accept them as an alternative to the contention made by the
government that a violation of law was the impelling motive of the
parties. And we may say that, after the United Company had made the
Plant acquisition, it proceeded to make improvements on the Plant
patents and developed many of them, giving them an efficiency they
did not have before.
There are other acquisitions that are emphasized, among them
that of the stock of the Goddu Sons Metal Company. It was acquired
March, 1899, a month after the United Company was formed and eleven
years before this suit was brought, and the inducement to the
acquisition was to settle the patent troubles that came to the
United Company through one of its constituent companies. The value
obtained was in patents. These were for the metallic variety of
machines, and, according to a witness for defendants, "at that
time, the United Company was putting out commercial machines for
doing the work for which the Goddu machines were intended." And
according to another witness, though not then in a condition to be
placed in the hands of manufacturers, "they were in a state of
development where some of them could have been, without extensive
changes, made operative."
By this testimony the defendants justify the purchase; the
government condemns it. The defendants say that it was in
composition of an inherited litigation, and that patents of value
were obtained by it. To this the government replies in condemnation
that the cost of the settlement of the disputes was excessive,
being $150,000, and the purpose of getting the patents was to
forestall the competition they threatened, and could have
accomplished by their development.
The value of a settlement of a dispute about rights which has
reached litigation or threatens it cannot be
Page 247 U. S. 53
easily or accurately estimated. It depends upon too many
considerations which are not reflected in the price paid. The other
ground of condemnation has strength. As the government says,
quoting Circuit Judge Putnam in another case, neither the letter of
the law nor its purpose "distinguishes between strangling of
commerce which has been born and preventing the birth of a commerce
which does not exist." But there is another view. No one can tell
the strength of the competition that may be in a patent. It may be
more than competition; it may be destruction, and the Anti-Trust
Act surely does not require the acceptance of that or forbid effort
to prevent it. But even if such extreme does not impend, certainly
improvement of business and its efficiency can be striven for
without offense to the law.
United States v. Winslow,
supra.
We may say here of the contention of the government as to the
acquisitions -- and the same comment may be made of most of its
contentions -- that they cast us into speculation for their
estimate, and urge us to decide between well sustained conflicting
opinions and adjudge the defendants guilty of a violation of law.
And this too against the considered judgment of the trial
court.
We see no illegality in the contract with Goddu for assignment
of other inventions he might make, or in like agreement with
others. We content ourselves with this general declaration. An
analysis of the contracts is not feasible, nor are the covenants
measurable. That they are attempts to subject the inventive genius
of the country to the designs of the defendants is too extreme.
They can be seen to have more particular use and to be justified in
the circumstances of the transaction with which they were
connected. Those whom one employs one gives opportunity to (this
was Goddu's case), and may exact that it be used for the employer.
Those who have conveyed to him special machines may be presumed to
have been compensated by their price, and that in either case
Page 247 U. S. 54
there will be such development and use as to make them
competitive is too speculative to justify a judgment.
It is to be noted that the acquisitions in this case were not
coincident in time nor parts of the same transaction. They were
scattered through a period of years, and varied each from the
other, had no dependency, were different an unrelated steps in the
development of the business of defendants. They must hence be
judged separately, not in accumulation.
The above comment is applicable to other acquisitions, said to
be fifty-six in number. It is impossible to review them. A
description of them and wherein the machines acquired were
competitive with the machines of the United Company the government
sets forth in many pages of its brief, and the defendants reply as
circumstantially with opposing delineation and justification. Their
effect is hard to estimate. The removal in some degree of
competition may be charged against some of them, and yet, on the
other hand, the acquisitions may be said to be justified by the
exigencies or conveniences of the situation. Some of them were
merely of accessorial machines; some in composition of patent
troubles; some not connected with the special charge of monopoly to
which the government has limited itself; some the transfer to
defendants of kinds of machines not possessed by them; some of
patented improvements and inventions, aiding or completing the
defendants' machines, tributary therefore to their efficiency. They
give a false impression by their number. They added nothing of
obnoxious power to the United Company nor in any practical or large
sense removed competition.
Defendants charge that the government not only puts an
exaggerated computation upon the acquisitions by defendants, but
gives no credit for or account to their resistance of applications
to buy other and, it is asserted, more important concerns. Their
number is given as seventy-five, all of great use and importance.
The trial court found that the
Page 247 U. S. 55
offers refused were more numerous and several of them were of
concerns more important to the scheme of monopoly charged against
defendants than any of the specified acquisitions. The comment is
justified by the evidence.
We pass by the charge of the government that the United Company,
through its president, threatened destruction to opponents and the
use of his influence in the business world to enforce transfers of
competing concerns and the patents they controlled. The charge and
its denial or explanation were estimated by the trial judges, and
the charge was held not to be established, or of no serious
importance. The court said that, if the declarations could be
called "threats" in view of all the surrounding circumstances
shown, it was not established that any competitor lost a customer
or that anybody was prevented from attempting competition. Besides,
they were isolated instances, separated in time, without relation,
not coordinated acts in a scheme of oppression.
We cannot go into further detail without unduly extending this
opinion. It would be repetition, besides, of what was done
carefully and thoroughly in the opinions of the trial judges. We
sum up with a generalization that the United Company took by its
organization "established businesses already of great value,
possessing great possibilities of development," as said by the
trial court. It was discerned that there was advantage in their
concentration, and the expansion that has hence resulted has been
as much in necessary evolution as by design. At its foundation,
there were certain basic patents and many auxiliary ones. Inventors
-- those connected with and those independent of it -- were
devising and experimenting, and of this the company had to keep
informed. It had to keep up with the mechanical march; to fall back
would have been its destruction. There was growth not only in its
business proper, but in the accessories to it. When it was formed
in 1899, it had no facilities for furnishing findings
Page 247 U. S. 56
and supplies. It was business enterprise or, it may be,
necessity, to acquire them, and their acquisition became what is
called in the case the United Company's "general department," which
handles, it is said, between 150 and 200 different kinds of
machines. The expansion to this and in this was like the expansion
of the department store -- an accumulation not only of necessary
things, but of incidental, supplemental things, auxiliary to the
completion and finish of a boot or shoe. There is a service force
as well, estimated at 6,000 men, to repair immediately breaks or
deterioration without extra charge. And these men are kept at
convenient places to repair machines and replace worn-out parts,
and depots of supplies are maintained. There are also instructors
of operators as well as furnishing of men in emergency. It is in
the testimony that a total of 8,889 operatives were taught in the
year 1911 alone.
The company, indeed, has magnitude, but it is at once the result
and cause of efficiency, and the charge that it has been
oppressively used is not sustained. Patrons are given the benefits
of the improvements made by the company, and new machines are
substituted for the old ones without disproportionate charge. There
has been saving as well in the cost of manufacture of shoes. These
are some of the results of the organization of the United Company.
Others are testified to and the means of their accomplishment; but
time will not permit their statement, and we pass to the
leases.
There was complaint of them, and the government attacks them.
Complaints, however, may be interested lament; but, on the other
hand, they may be the expression of real grievance and demand
redress. And which they are should be considered. To the attacks of
the government, the defendants reply that the leases are the
exercise of their right as patentees, and if there is monopoly in
them, it is the monopoly of the right. It
Page 247 U. S. 57
must, indeed, be said that it is the experience of the world
that the utility of an invention entices to its infringement, but
it would be a perversion of things to facilitate the wrong by a
sacrifice of the right in revulsion from the restraint which the
right authorizes. But, on the other hand, we must not overestimate
the right or give it a sinister effect -- permit it to be a means,
to use the words of the government, "to the building up and
entrenchment" of an "illegal monopoly." We cannot consider the
contentions with the detail that counsel have. We think that their
answer is in the statement of certain general propositions.
Of course there is restraint in a patent. Its strength is in the
restraint, the right to exclude others from the use of the
invention, absolutely or on the terms the patentee chooses to
impose. This strength is the compensation which the law grants for
the exercise of invention. Its exertion within the field covered by
the patent law is not an offense against the Anti-Trust Act. In
other circumstances, it may be, as in
Standard Sanitary Co. v.
United States, 226 U. S. 20, to
which case that at bar has no resemblance.
The question, then, is was the patent right lawfully exerted in
the leases? Were they anything more than the exercise of the patent
monopoly? The word is descriptive and must be used, but it does not
imply oppression. The old instrumentalities exist for all who are
content with them and who care not for the better ones which
inventive genius creates.
The charge of oppression puts out of view many essential things.
We must keep in mind the quality of the right we are considering
and that the inventor gets nothing from the law that he did not
have before and that the only effect of his patent is to restrain
others from dealing with or using its device.
United States v.
Bell Tel. Co., 167 U. S. 224, 229
[argument of counsel -- omitted];
Paper Bag
Patent Case,
Page 247 U. S. 58
210 U. S. 405,
210 U. S. 424;
Motion Picture Co. v. Universal Film Co., 243 U.
S. 502,
243 U. S. 510.
Or, to put it another way, the inventor does not get from the law a
right to a use that he did not have before, but he gets the right
to an exclusive use. Take this from him and you take all that the
law gives him and to secure which the public faith is pledged.
Chief Justice Marshall, in
Grant v.
Raymond, 6 Pet. 218,
31 U. S.
242.
Indeed, we said in the
Paper Bag Patent Case that he
may keep his invention out of use. Therefore, he necessarily has
the power of granting it to some and withholding it from others, a
right of selection of persons and terms. There is, however, a
limitation upon him -- he cannot grant the title and retain the
incidents of it.
Straus v. Victor Talking Machine Co.,
243 U. S. 490;
Bauer & Cie v. O'Donnell, 229 U. S.
1;
Motion Picture Co. v. Universal Film Co.,
supra.
These cases have received review and application in
Boston
Store of Chicago v. American Graphophone Co., 246 U. S.
8. The principle of them was expressed to be that, where
an article has been sold, it passes beyond the monopoly given by
the patent, and conditions cannot be imposed upon it. Leases are
not of this character; they do not convey the title. It is not
contended, nor could it be, that in this case they are a disguise
for something else, artifices to convey the machinery and yet keep
it subject to the patent right and its exercise. It therefore
follows that conditions may be imposed by them.
It is not certain that the government denies this or means to
assert anything more than that the patent right is exercised in
oppression, assisting, indeed consummating, a scheme of monopoly
begun by the formation of the United Company, prosecuted in the
various ways to which we have referred, and completed by the leases
and their clauses.
It is difficult to represent the contentions of the
government
Page 247 U. S. 59
without under-coloring them or over-coloring them. There is one
that the leases are invalid in and of themselves; there is another
that "ultimately, of course, it is upon the lease forms themselves
and their apparent and necessary effect upon competition that the
United States relies." The first contention the government leaves
very much to assertion, and defendants charge that it was not made
in the trial court; the second contention is necessary to assign to
the leases an obnoxious quality in the hands of the United Company
which they did not have in the hands of the constituent companies.
The distinction would seem to be not material of itself, and the
important consideration is not what the leases were in some other
relation, but what they are in their present relation and to what
purpose are they being rightfully or wrongfully, or can they be
rightfully or wrongfully, used or enforced? To this inquiry we
shall now address ourselves.
The first objection made to the leases is that they are
unchangeable by the lessee -- he "has no right," it is urged, to
demand either the cancellation or modification of an existing one.
The objection is not definite or measurable. It is probably but a
representation of what is deemed the severity of the leases, for,
of course, a contract is a restraint upon option, and can be
enforced. This power is its efficacy, and indicates its obligation.
And further, it is of no consequence that the leases cover all of
the machines of the United Company if they are an exercise of the
patent rights. Whether they are is the broad question in the case,
and its disposition will dispose of all minor and dependent
ones.
What, then, do the leases accomplish? They have clauses called
"tying" clauses, so called because, it is said, they tie the use of
the machine leased to the use of machines not covered by the
particular lease. Their result is, the government asserts,
"to make it in effect a
Page 247 U. S. 60
condition of the lease that the lessee shall not use the
machines of competitors to supply a need for additional machines of
the kind leased or for machines of other important though wholly
different types."
And it is urged:
"In addition to those clauses, there are certain other clauses
which have a similar effect upon the freedom of the lessees' choice
of machines. They give to the tying clauses their maximum effect as
destroyers of the possibility of competition with the
defendants."
It is charged that "the objectionable clauses are interrelated,
and operate together with cumulative effect;" that "they are
unlawful both as integral and effective parts of an unlawful whole
and, for the most part, in and of themselves." And it is further
charged that
"it is, however, in their combined effect as a system of
leasing, used and insisted upon by a corporation dominant in its
field, that the full extent of their illegality is to be
perceived."
This, however, is assertion, and relies for its foundation upon
the assumption of an illegal dominance by the United Company that
has been found not to exist. This element therefore must be put to
one side, and the leases regarded in and of themselves and by the
incentives that induced their execution, and to a suit seeking
their dissolution it may well be contended that the lessees are
necessary parties, certainly so far as existing leases are
concerned. But the contention of the government goes farther, and
asserts that its purpose and object justify the absence of the
lessees from the case. Indeed, the government takes merit to itself
in relieving them of a thraldom. "The rights of the lessees," it is
said, "are not touched except to preserve them." But a lessee may
like his situation, may have deliberately chosen it, and may not
care for any interposition, benevolent or otherwise.
Finally the government, in possible opposition to both lessor
and lessee, asserts that "no one has the right to
Page 247 U. S. 61
say that the unlawful conduct of another shall be permitted to
continue because he has an interest in it." Perhaps not. But there
may be dispute as to the character of the conduct, and its
illegality cannot be conceded to mere assertion and the consequent
assumption of a destroying power.
However, let us consider the clauses from the standpoint of the
government's contentions, and determine if they transcend the
rights given to patentees. The clauses are: (1) one that prescribes
a uniform term of 17 years. The result of this is, the government
says,
"that, during that long period, no replacement of a machine so
leased by a better machine of defendants or others, no change in
the form of the lease or avoidance of any of its requirements, is
open to the lessee except with the defendants' consent and upon
their terms."
To this it is replied that the leases of the constituent
companies ran for indefinite periods, and, besides, new patents
were constantly taken out, and to these the criticism of the
government does not apply. And again, the term was assurance to the
lessee as well as lessor, and, as defendants' counsel suggest,
there is analogy in the term to that of a building lease which may.
under the hazard of circumstances. turn out to be or not to be
advantageous. Of this there are two recent examples in this Court.
Filene's Sons Co. v. Weed, 245 U.
S. 597, and
Gardner v. Butler & Co.,
245 U. S. 603.
Indeed, we may say of all the clauses, without a minute analysis
and discussion of them, that they were simply bargains, based on
patent rights and the conditions upon which those rights were
granted. (2) The "additional machines" clause, which provides that,
in case the lessee has more work than can be performed by the
machine leased, he will lease additional machinery to perform the
work, and that, if the lessee does not do so, the lessor may cancel
the lease if he so elect, and any other lease of machinery of the
same kind then in
Page 247 U. S. 62
force between them. This clause, we shall presently see, was
discontinued in 1907, and was not in use when this suit was
brought. (3) An "exclusive use" clause requiring the lessee of
particular machinery to use it exclusively and the auxiliary
machines which aid or supplement it, and for failure to do so,
lessor may at his option terminate forthwith in writing any or all
leases or licenses of the particular machines and accessorial
machines, and they shall become revested in the lessor. This clause
only requires an election of use between the United Company's
machines and those of other makers. If the election be of the
latter, the lessor may terminate the lease and resume his machines.
(4) A prohibitive clause. This clause provides that the particular
machine leased shall not be used in the preparation or manufacture
of shoes, etc., upon which work is done by any machine not held by
the lessee under lease from the lessor. (5) The right to terminate
all leases clause. This clause does not need much explanation. Its
name expresses its purpose. It gives the lessor the right, in
default of the performance of the conditions of the particular
lease, not only to cancel that lease, but all other leases, and
requires a delivery of the leased machinery to the lessor at
Beverly, Massachusetts, complete and in good order, reasonable wear
and tear alone excepted. (6) The full capacity clause. Its name
expresses its purpose. It requires the leased machinery to be used
to its full capacity upon the work to which it is applicable. This
clause was in the lease of the Consolidated Company prior to the
formation of the United Company. Its purpose is to secure the
royalty which is based on the amount of use of the machine. It does
not require the use of any particular machine or the use of other
machines. It merely requires that the particular machine that is
installed shall be used if the lessee have work for it. Without it,
defendants say that, as lessors, they would have no assurance of
compensation for their machine. (7) A
Page 247 U. S. 63
charge upon the return of the machinery leased is required. This
needs no comment or further notice. (8) The leases of metallic
machinery provide for the purchase from the lessor of certain
fastening material. This clause and the next, which provides for
the payment of royalties, are mere makeweights, and not of special
materiality.
The evil potency ascribed to the leases (we use the word as
inclusive of the clauses, and we do not think it necessary to
distinguish them according to their application to particular
machines) by the government is their asserted coercion of shoe
makers and machinery makers. They limit the freedom of the first,
it is contended, and by that limitation preclude the competition of
the second with the defendants. In other words, the use of the
machines of the United Company is compelled as against the use of
machines of other manufacturers, resulting in the restraint of the
trade of the latter. To this charge all other charges are
subsidiary, and the restraint is said to have been the initial
conception of the company, and the purpose of its organization. The
evidence disproves this. As we have seen, the leasing of their
respective machines was the practice of the constituent companies
before their union, and they were substantially the same after
union as before -- in instances, better. There was a difference as
to the prohibitive clause. After the union, it related to machines
of all of the companies. And the testimony also shows that the
advantage of the leases was and is that manufacturers of not large
means were able to obtain machinery which they were without capital
to buy. They helped, indeed, the big and the little. One
manufacturer whose output was 5,000 pairs of shoes a day testified
that if his company had been compelled to buy outright the
machinery necessary to equip its factory, it could not have
developed as it had.
Page 247 U. S. 64
And sets of machines are necessary to the equipment of a
factory, and their best results are obtained when used in proper
relation. This relation, indeed, the necessary coordination of the
machines, was shown pictorially by a number of views in the court
below, as well as testified to by witnesses. And there is great
economic advantage, it was testified, in the accessory service
furnished by the United Company for the reason that
"the regularity and continuous operation of the machines is
dependent upon what may be termed instantaneous service. . . . This
factor of service is at the very basis of the successful operation
of a shoe factory. The work is planned to travel from one room to
another in fixed quantities. So many pair go in in the morning, so
many pair come out at night. The operatives are dependent upon that
work traveling along regularly to them. The breakdown of some of
these machines will in many of the factories block the entire flow
of the work."
This was the testimony of the president of the United Company,
and it received corroboration from a witness for the United States
who said:
"The margin of profit in making shoes is such that it is very
essential that our machinery should work smoothly and regularly and
with continuity, and economics in the manufacture of shoes often
make the difference between a successful manufacturer and one who
is not successful. One of the most important economics is to have
our machinery work with continuity and with the highest efficiency
and turn out our product with the utmost regularity day after day,
just as we want to get it so that there won't be any hitch anywhere
in the flow of our product through our factory."
The witness gave praise to the excellence of the machines of the
United Company. This excellence and the described service the
leases secured to the lessees and secured at the same time rights
to the lessors. And the leases are strictly a reservation of the
use of the machines, a right
Page 247 U. S. 65
recognized in
Bauer & Cie v. O'Donnell, Straus v. Victor
Talking Machine Co., and
Motion Picture Co. v. Universal
Film Co., supra. We must assume they were entered into by the
lessees upon a calculation of their value -- the efficiency of the
machines balanced against the restrictions upon and conditions of
their use. The lessees had the alternative of the choice of other
machines, for other machines were sold side by side with those the
leases covered. This, we think, is put out of view.
Let us guard against confusion, and not confound things which
must be kept in distinction. A patentee is given rights to his
device, but he is given no power to force it on the world. If the
world buy it or use it, the world will do so upon a voluntary
judgment of its utility, demonstrated, it may be, at great cost to
the patentee. If its price be too high, whether in dollars or
conditions, the world will refuse it; if it be worth the price,
whether of dollars or conditions, the world will seek it. To say
that the world is not recompensed for the price it pays is to
attack the policy of the law, is to defy experience, and to declare
that the objects of inventive genius all around us have contributed
nothing to the advancement of mankind. This comment is applicable
here. We cannot accept, therefore, the contention of the
government. We see nothing else in the circumstances of the parties
than that which moves and may move the transactions of men.
We may say further, in answer to the criticism of the leases,
that relaxations of them were granted by "riders," and that forms
other than the restrictive were open to the shoe manufacturers,
distinguished in the testimony by the term "independent." They do
not contain the prohibitive clause, but do contain the other
clauses and require an initial payment. Comparison is made of the
independent form and the other forms by witnesses and various
judgments are expressed. The government sees nothing in any of them
but the restraints upon the freedom
Page 247 U. S. 66
of business, and regards the independent form as only slightly
relaxing what counsel implies is the slavery of the others. The
defendants contend that they are the simple exercise of a property
right, the mutuality of agreement based on definite and valuable
considerations. And it was testified that the machines in the
United Company's general department have always been open to sale
or lease. It is further said that the additional machine clauses
were removed from all leases of the company as early as 1907, and
they were not in use and did not represent its policy at the time
of bringing this suit. But leases with that clause are outstanding,
the government replies.
However, we need not dwell further upon the leases. It
approaches declamation to say that the lessees were coerced to
their making. And, as we have said, there was benefit to the
lessee. It is easy to say that the leases are against the policy of
the law. But when one tries to be definite, one comes back to the
rights and obligations of the parties. There is no question in the
case of the use of circumstances to compel or restrain; the leases
are simply bargains, not different from others, moved upon
calculated considerations, and, whether provident or improvident,
are entitled nevertheless to the sanctions of the law. We have said
this, indeed, with iteration, but sometimes propositions which have
become postulates have to be justified to meet objections, which,
if they do not deny their existence, tend to bring them into
question.
Besides, it is impossible to believe, and the court below
refused to find, that the great business of the United Shoe
Machinery Company has been built up by the coercion of its
customers and that its machinery has been installed in most of the
large factories of the country by the exercise of power, even that
of patents. The installations could have had no other incentive
than the excellence of the machines and the advantage of their use,
the conditions
Page 247 U. S. 67
imposed having adequate compensation and not offensive to the
letter or the policy of the law.
Decree affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE McREYNOLDS and MR. JUSTICE BRANDEIS took no part in
the consideration and decision of the case.
[
Footnote 1]
During the trial, a discussion came up about patents. The
presiding judge intimated that the court did not desire to take up
the patents themselves, but would send them to an examiner. It was
stated by counsel in the case that the matter was important. But
the court made a distinction between a "patent question" and a
"patent controversy" -- good faith being an element of the latter
-- and stated that the latter would not be included in the hearing
before the examiner, but would be heard in open court. The court
then ordered the taking of testimony of both parties before the
examiner as to that section of the bill which charged an unlawful
extension of the patents to perpetuate their monopoly at the
expense of boot and shoe manufacturers and to use them to acquire a
complete monopoly of all kinds of shoe machinery. The examination
took place, and it was the usual battle of experts, and the
conflicts are recorded in a volume of more than eight hundred
pages. Their ultimate test, however, and the effect of the patents
is the testimony delivered in open court.
[
Footnote 2]
"Section 1. Every contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce, among
the several states, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to
be illegal. Every person who shall make any such contract, or
engage in any such combination or conspiracy, shall be deemed
guilty of a misdemeanor, and, on conviction thereof, shall be
punished by fine not exceeding five thousand dollars, or by
imprisonment not exceeding one year, or by both said punishments,
in the discretion of the court."
"Section 2. Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to
monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or
persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the
several states, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of
a misdemeanor, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by
fine not exceeding five thousand dollars, or by imprisonment not
exceeding one year, or by both said punishments, in the discretion
of the court."
[
Footnote 3]
There is apparent confusion in the brief of the government. In
one place, it is stated that the United Company was the
consolidation of the businesses and properties of seven companies
which were taken over as going concerns, to-wit: Goodyear Shoe
Machinery Company, International Goodyear Machinery Company,
Consolidated & McKay Lasting Machine Company, McKay Shoe
Machinery Company, Davey Pegging Machine Company, Eppler Welt
Machine Company, and International Eppler Welt Machine Company.
In another place, the organization of the United Company is
stated to be the merger of four companies -- Goodyear Company,
Consolidated & McKay Company, Eppler Company, and the McKay
Shoe Machinery Company -- and resulted in the immediate suppression
of competition between those companies and dominating "to the point
of practical exclusion the important field of supplying the
principal and essential machines necessary in the manufacture of
shoes."
However, in the conclusion of the government's brief, it
contends that it has established
"that there existed vigorous competition between three of the
companies merged in the organization of the United Company, and
that the fourth company, which at any moment might have become a
competitor, was taken in for the purpose and with the effect of
furthering the unlawful scheme of the combination thus brought into
being."
The fourth company referred to is no doubt the McKay Shoe
Machinery Company.
The immediate results were, it is contended --
"(1) The suppression of the actual and of the potential
competition in lasting machines theretofore existing between the
Consolidated & McKay Company and the Goodyear Shoe Machinery
Company. It created a monopoly in lasting machines."
"(2) The suppression of the actual and of the potential
competition between the Goodyear Shoe Machinery Company and the
Eppler Welt Machine Company. It created a monopoly of welting and
outsole stitching machinery."
"(3) The absolute prevention of future competition between the
McKay Shoe Machinery Company, the Goodyear Shoe Machinery Company,
the Eppler Welt Machine Company, and the Consolidated & McKay
Company."
"(4) The creation of an absolute and complete monopoly in
lasting, pegging, welting, outsole stitching, heeling, and metallic
fastening machines."
"(5) The creation of an organization with vast resources whose
control of many different types of machines necessary to the shoe
manufacturing industry gave it a power to extend and entrench its
monopoly which none of its constituent companies, however
successful, could approach."
[
Footnote 4]
Plaintiff's Exhibit 152.
"
To the Stockholders of Goodyear Machinery
Company:"
"Boston, Mass. Feb. 8, 1899"
"The great advantages to be secured by the control in one
corporation, both in the United States and in foreign countries, of
the efficient types of shoe machinery have been for several years
recognized by the officers of the principal shoe machinery
companies. For more than a year, your directors and large
shareholders have been in negotiation to accomplish this end."
"After a thorough investigation of the financial condition and
the business of the shoe machinery companies named below, the
organization of a corporation has been effected under the laws of
the State of New Jersey, to be known as United Shoes Machinery
Company."
"The United Shoe Machinery Company has already contracted for
more than a majority of the capital stock of Goodyear Shoe
Machinery Company, Consolidated & McKay Lasting Machine
Company, McKay Shoe Machinery Company, Goodyear Shoe Machinery
Company of Canada, International Welt Machine Company, Davey
Pegging Machine Company, besides stocks in other shoe-machinery
companies, letters patent, and other property."
"The United Company will also from time to time acquire other
shoe machinery properties either by direct ownership or by purchase
of shares of their stock."
[
Footnote 5]
Plaintiff's Exhibit 189.
"Whereas, the United Company have acquired control of the boot
and shoe and leather working machinery made by the following named
corporations doing business in said Boston, namely:"
"Goodyear Shoe Machinery Company, Consolidated & McKay
Lasting Machine Company, Eppler Welt Machine Company, Goddu Metal
Fastening Company, Gordon Staple Lasting and Tacking Company, Davey
Pegging Machine Company, Gem Flexible Insole Company, Boot &
Shoe Sole Laying Company, and contemplated acquiring the control or
other lines of boot and shoe and leather working machinery, and
boot and shoe findings, except leather, linings, lasts, and
finished boots and shoes. . . ."
[
Footnote 6]
The price was $3,000,000 in cash and $1,500,000 in common stock
of the United Company at par, the market value of which was
$3,000,000.
[
Footnote 7]
Mr. Winslow gave the following explanation or his purpose in the
Plant purchase, as stated in conversations with Mr. Plant:
"I always declined to have anything to do not only with buying,
but considering his propositions without a full and complete right
to examine his machinery, determine the value of the inventions --
the patents that he had -- and Mr. Plant knew that my position all
the time at every interview was that I was not interested in what
it cost him to get them up, whether much or little. My entire and
only interest was whether those patents could be made of benefit to
our customers and the trade. If they could be of benefit, if they
were of large benefit, and the trade ought to have them, I should
be very glad to buy them and embody them in our machines for what I
thought they were worth, irrespective of what they had cost him --
but I would not pay a cent more for them."
MR. JUSTICE DAY dissenting.
I concur with the opinion of MR. JUSTICE CLARKE as to the
character of the combination here involved.
There are provisions in the so-called leases attacked in this
case which, in my view, are so clearly within the condemnation of
the Sherman Anti-Trust Act that the further enforcement of them and
the making of new leases of like character should be enjoined. The
far-reaching character of a decision sustaining a leasing system
such as the defendant has developed and uses justifies a statement
of the reasons which impel me to this conclusion.
As to the suggestion that the lessees are not parties to this
proceeding, and therefore no decree can be had as to them, it seems
to me this is not a case of want of indispensable or even necessary
parties because of their absence such as should prevent the court
from proceeding to a decree to enjoin the United Shoe Machinery
Company from the further enforcement of these features of the
leases and the making of similar contracts hereafter. If these
leases are in violation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act, the makers
of them may be proceeded against, and a decree rendered which shall
effectually preclude them from further contracts of this sort,
without the presence of the lessees if it could be assumed that any
of them should desire to be heard in advocacy of the retention of
these prohibitive and restrictive features.
The object of this proceeding is to enjoin in equity further
Page 247 U. S. 68
violation of a criminal statute, not to determine title or
property rights of the defendant. It is sufficient as to the
doctrine of indispensable parties to refer to
Shields v.
Barrow, 17 How. 130, and the cases collected in the
discussion of the subject in
Waterman v. Canal Bank,
215 U. S. 33,
215 U. S. 48.
There is no reason in this case why the court may not so shape its
relief as to reserve the rights of persons not before it, if that
should be necessary.
The questions involved in the aspect of the case now under
consideration are two-fold. First, are certain provisions of these
lease agreements of themselves considered within the terms of the
Sherman Anti-Trust Act? Second, are such agreements to be held
immune from the requirements of the act because of the fact that
much, perhaps all, the machinery of the United Shoe Machinery
Company is made and leased under letters patent issued by the
United States? Of these questions in their order.
1. It clearly appears from the record that the United Shoe
Machinery Company dominates the trade in certain kinds of shoe
machinery furnished to manufacturers all over the country, which
machinery is essential to the successful prosecution of the
business of manufacturing shoes. It has many customers to whom it
supplies these machines under leases, and such customers are
required to accept the terms of these instruments or go without the
machines. The leases are made for a uniform term of seventeen
years, and not now considering the conditions of payment for the
use of the machines and other terms usual and legal in their
nature, they contain certain other features which may be summarized
in the requirements: (1) The lessee shall not use the machinery, or
any part thereof, in the manufacture or preparation of welted
boots, shoes, or other footwear which has not had certain
operations performed upon it by other machines leased from the
lessor. This is called the prohibitive clause. (2)
Page 247 U. S. 69
If at any time the lessee shall fail or cease to use exclusively
lasting machinery held by him under lease from the lessor, or fail
or cease to use exclusively tacking mechanisms and appliances held
by him under lease from the lessor, etc., the lessor may, at its
option, terminate any or all leases or licenses of lasting
machines, etc., then existing between the lessor and the lessee,
and the right of possession shall thereupon vest in the lessor.
This is called the exclusive use clause. (3) In case the lessee has
work of the kind which can be performed by the machines belonging
to the metallic department of the lessor in excess of the capacity
of the metallic machinery which he has under lease from the lessor,
then the lessee shall either take from the lessor sufficient
additional machinery to perform the work, or, failing so to do, the
lessor may cancel the lease forthwith, or any other lease of
metallic machinery then in force between the parties. This is
called the additional machines clause. (4) The lessee shall obtain
from the lessor exclusively, at such prices as it may establish,
all the fastening material needed in operating the leased machines.
(6) The lessee shall, at the election of the lessor, suffer a
termination of all leases which he may have and the removal of all
machines leased by him from the defendants in the event of any
violation of any term of any one of the leases.
From familiar decisions of this Court it may be said to be now
well settled that the Sherman Anti-Trust Act condemns all
combinations and contracts the effect of which is to unduly
restrain the free and natural flow of interstate commerce or which
monopolize or tend to monopolize such trade or commerce in whole or
in part. While the act does not reach normal contracts sanctioned
by law and sustained by usage, it does reach any and all means and
devices by which the purposes of the act to protect the freedom of
interstate commerce may be thwarted and monopolies promoted and
created.
United States v.
American
Page 247 U. S. 70
Tobacco Co., 221 U. S. 106,
221 U. S. 179;
United States v. St. Louis Terminal, 224 U.
S. 383;
United States v. Reading Co,
226 U. S. 324;
United States v. Patten, 226 U. S. 525;
Eastern states Lumber Assn. v. United States, 234 U.
S. 600. That these lease restrictions tend to prevent
the free flow of interstate commerce, and the natural course of its
activities, and at least tend to monopolize an important trade in
interstate commerce, seems apparent from a mere statement of their
terms, having in mind their natural and necessary effect.
For the seventeen-year term for which all the leases are drawn,
the lessees, upon failure to use exclusively the defendant's
machines for lasting shoes, or upon failure to purchase needed
additional machines from the lessor, or to buy certain supplies
from the lessor at prices to be fixed by it, are subject to the
right of the lessor to terminate all the leases held by the
offending lessee and to take possession of the machines, to the
utter destruction of the lessee's business. The necessary effect of
these prohibitive provisions, in view of the dominating control of
the business by the lessor, is to prevent the lessee from using
other similar machines, however advantageous to him it may be to do
so, unless he is willing to incur the peril of losing machinery
essential to his business. It likewise so curtails the field of
free customers as to keep others from manufacturing such machinery.
* Whenever a
newmachine
Page 247 U. S. 71
is acquired by the lessee for the period of seventeen years (the
full life of a patent under the statutes of the United States), the
chain is forged anew which binds him to the use of the lessor's
machines, to the practical exclusion of all others.
Nor is the situation changed by the fact that so-called
independent leases are offered to manufacturers. These leases
require the payment of considerable additional charges, and embrace
terms which lead the shoe manufacturers to choose the prohibitive
and restrictive forms of leases, rather than to accept others.
Moreover, the questions in this case are to be tried upon the
effect of the leases actually made, and for years to remain in
force. When it is considered that these results may be obtained in
the conduct of a great business industry by this system of "tying"
contracts, the necessary effect to restrain the freedom of
commerce, and the attempt to effect monopolization, seems to me to
be established.
2. The stress of the argument on behalf of the company is rested
upon the fact that it is the owner of letters patent issued by the
United States, and that, within the monopoly created by such
patents, it has the right to make and enforce such contracts as are
herein involved. At an
Page 247 U. S. 72
early day, this Court, speaking by its Chief Justice,
declared:
"The franchise which the patent grants consists altogether in
the right to exclude everyone from making, using, or vending the
thing patented, without the permission of the patentee. This is all
that he obtains by the patent."
Bloomer v.
McQuewan, 14 How. 539. The extent and nature of
rights secured by letters patent have been the subject of recent
consideration in this Court, and the definition, just quoted, has
been approved and applied.
Bauer v. O'Donnell,
229 U. S. 1;
Straus v. Victor Talking Machine Co., 243 U.
S. 490;
Motion Picture Co. v. Universal Film
Co., 243 U. S. 502;
Boston Store of Chicago v. American Graphophone Co.,
246 U. S. 8.
When this case was tried in the district court,
Henry v.
Dick, 224 U. S. 1, was the
law of this Court. In that case, a mimeograph, made under letters
patent, was sold for less than its full value, with a license
agreement limiting its use to certain unpatented articles belonging
to the patentee. Such use was held to be within the exclusive right
secured by the lessor's patent. In
Motion Picture Co. v.
Universal Film Co., supra, it was sought to extend the
doctrine of that case so as to protect a license agreement
evidenced by notice attached to the machine so as to limit the
purchaser to the use of certain films, and to restrict the
purchaser to other terms to be fixed by the owner of the patent at
his discretion. But such extended scope of patent rights was
denied, and it was again held that the patentee received from the
law no more than the exclusive right to make, use, and sell his
invention.
It is said, however, that the series of cases beginning with
Bauer v. O'Donnell, supra, and ending with
Boston
Store of Chicago v. American Graphophone Co., supra, decided
at this term, hold no more than that a patentee may not sell an
article covered by his letters patent, receive his price therefor,
and then undertake to impose a restriction upon the price at which
resales of the patented article may
Page 247 U. S. 73
be made. A reading of those cases shows that the nature and
extent of the right to grant to others the use of an invention was
fully discussed, and its limitations defined.
In the
Motion Picture case, the right of a patentee to
place restrictions upon the use of a patented machine, and to limit
its use by a purchaser, or purchaser's lessee, to terms stated in
the license agreement, was considered. This Court held that such
limitations as were there involved upon the use of patented
machines were not within the scope of the patent. It was upon the
expanded right to use an invention that the
Button Fastener
Case, 77 F. 288, and
Henry v. Dick, 224 U. S.
1, were rested; both cases were overruled in the
Motion Picture Company case. In the latter case, it was
specifically held that, while the patentee might withhold his
invention from public use, yet if he consented to its use by
himself or others, he was limited to the use described in the
claims of his patent, and that there was nothing in the statute
which extended his right to control the patented invention by
prescribing the use of machines, materials, and supplies not
covered by the patent. In view of the full discussion of the
question in the series of cases already referred to, it is
unnecessary to pursue it further.
Under the system of leasing, now before us, the patentee not
only undertakes to grant the use of the machines covered by the
letters patent, but to dictate the supplies with which they shall
be used; to compel their surrender if the machine of another is
used; to prevent their use except with other machinery furnished by
the patentee; to extend the monopoly of the invention beyond the 17
years allowed by the statute; to lease the use of the invention
only upon terms which permit the lessor to forfeit the patent
license, and to terminate, if he chooses, all similar leases to use
the machines of the lessor. And these extraordinary claims of right
are made under the grant of the patent which gives to the inventor
the exclusive
Page 247 U. S. 74
right to make, use, and sell his invention, and nothing more. In
my opinion, such extended power and authority are not consistent
with the act as the same has been construed in every case dealing
with the subject beginning with the decision in
Bauer v.
O'Donnell. To sustain such provisions, it seems to me, amounts
to an authority to holders of patented inventions, under the guise
of leasing the use of patented machinery, to exercise the right to
make combinations necessarily and unduly restraining the freedom of
trade, and, by virtue of the patent grant, to build up monopolies
in direct violation of the Sherman Act.
True it is that there is embraced in the patent grant the right
or privilege to make licenses and agreements covering the use of
the machines patented so long as such agreements are not in
themselves unlawful. But the right to make restrictions is
controlled by the general principles of law, and, because he is at
liberty to make them, the patentee may not make contracts in
themselves illegal, and certainly is not authorized to make
contracts in violation of other statutes of the United States. That
rights granted under a patent do not authorize the making of
contracts in restraint of trade, or monopolizing or tending to
monopolize trade and commerce in violation of the Sherman Act, was
held by this Court in
Standard Manufacturing Co. v. United
States, 226 U. S. 20.
In
Straus v. American Publishing Co., 231 U.
S. 222, contracts, otherwise clearly within the terms of
the Sherman Act, were claimed to be justified because of rights
secured under the copyright laws of the United States. Quoting and
following the decision in the
Standard Manufacturing
Company case, this Court said:
"So, in the present case, it cannot be successfully contended
that the monopoly of a copyright is in this respect any more
extensive than that secured under the patent law. No more than the
patent statute was the copyright act intended
Page 247 U. S. 75
to authorize agreements in unlawful restraint of trade and
tending to monopoly, in violation of the specific terms of the
Sherman law, which is broadly designed to reach all combinations in
unlawful restraint of trade and tending because of the agreements
or combinations entered into to build up and perpetuate monopolies.
. . ."
The patent statute and the Sherman Act are each valid laws of
the United States. While a patentee should be protected in the
exercise of rights secured to the inventor under the patent system
enacted into the laws of the United States, there is nothing in the
Act which gives the patentee a license to violate other statutes of
the United States, and certainly not the one now under
consideration. In my opinion, the restrictive and prohibitive
clauses of these leases are within the Sherman Act, as they are
clearly in restraint of interstate trade and tend to monopolize in
the sense that those terms have been defined in the decisions of
this Court. That some of the leases were in existence when the
United Shoe Machinery Company was formed affords no protection as
against the exercise of the power of Congress in the passage of the
Sherman Act.
Louisville & Nashville R. Co. v. Mottley,
219 U. S. 467,
219 U. S. 480.
I think that a decree should be entered as prayed for, and I
therefore dissent from the opinion and judgment of the court.
MR. JUSTICE PITNEY and MR. JUSTICE CLARKE concur in this
dissent.
* The Judiciary Committee of the House of Representatives, when
considering the Clayton Bill (38 Stat. 730), said of such
provisions:
"Where the concern making these contracts is already great and
powerful, such as the United Shoe Machinery Company, . . . the
exclusive or 'tying' contract made with local dealers becomes one
of the greatest agencies and instrumentalities of monopoly ever
devised by the brain of man. It completely shuts out competitors
not only from trade in which they are already engaged, but from the
opportunities to build up trade in any community where these great
and powerful conditions are appearing under this system and
practice. By this method and practice, the Shoe Machinery Company
has built up a monopoly that owns and controls the entire machinery
now being used by all great manufacturing houses of the United
States. No independent manufacturer of shoe machines has the
slightest opportunity to build up any considerable trade in this
country while this condition obtains. If the manufacturer who is
using machines of the Shoe Machinery Company were to purchase and
place a machine manufactured by an independent company in his
establishment, the Shoe Machinery Company could, under its
contracts, withdraw all their machinery from the establishment and
thereby wreck the business of the manufacturer."
Report of Committee, p. 13.
A statute of Massachusetts forbidding patentees from making
leases in effect like those here involved was sustained as
constitutional by the Supreme Judicial Court of Massachusetts in
193 Mass. 605.
MR. JUSTICE CLARKE, dissenting.
A plain history of just what the parties did at and after the
time the United Shoe Machinery Company was organized in February,
1899, compiled almost exclusively from the testimony of the two
leaders in the organization and from documentary evidence, will be
the best statement
Page 247 U. S. 76
I can make of the reasons other than those stated in the
dissenting opinion by MR. JUSTICE DAY, which render it impossible
for me to concur in the opinion and judgment of the Court in this
case.
I fully agree with the customary practice of giving great weight
to the conclusions of trial judges as to questions of fact involved
when the value of the testimony depends upon the appearance and
manner of the witnesses when testifying, but the reason for this
rule ceases when the evidence is in writing, or consists chiefly,
as it does in this case, of purchases of property, the significance
of which lies in the fact of the purchase, rather than in the
manner of making it.
Obviously, the attaching of the sole of a shoe to the upper is
the difficult and dominating operation in the manufacture of shoes
by machinery, and early in the trial, the charge of the government
in the case, by stipulation in open court, became, that the
consolidation was formed for the purpose of monopolizing interstate
trade or commerce in machinery adapted to that purpose, the
"bottoming of shoes," in violation of both the first and second
sections of the Anti-Trust Act of 1890.
Before the merger, the Goodyear Shoe Machinery Company
(hereinafter designated the Goodyear Company) was engaged in
manufacturing and leasing to shoe manufacturers two principal and
sixteen auxiliary machines, the latter being used in preparing the
materials of the operation of the former. The two principal
machines were used for sewing the sole to the upper, and were known
as the Goodyear welt and turn shoe machine and the Goodyear outsole
rapid lock stitch machine. With these machines, the Goodyear welt,
a popular and largely used shoe, was manufactured. This company
also manufactured a specially designed lasting machine used in
making Goodyear welt shoes.
The Consolidated and McKay Lasting Machine Company
Page 247 U. S. 77
(hereinafter designated as the Consolidated Company) was engaged
in manufacturing and leasing lasting machines of three types.
As the name of the one implies, and as otherwise appears in the
record, each of these two companies had resulted from prior
consolidations of shoe machine manufacturing companies, and they
were the largest organizations of their kind in the country.
The controlling spirit of the Consolidated Company was S.W.
Winslow, and of the Goodyear Company E. P. Howe, who, the record
shows, were keen and masterful men, and they both testify that in
July, 1898, they began the negotiations looking to a uniting of the
interests of the two companies, which culminated in the
organization of the United Shoe Machinery Company in February,
1899. A "harmonious arrangement" or "working agreement" was at
first proposed, but Howe, being a lawyer, would not agree to this,
"because," he says,
"I had a sort of indefinite idea that it might be deemed to be a
combination in restraint of trade. . . . I had an indefinite fear
that, if the two companies remained separate, but, for instance,
had a joint factory and joint branch offices, there might be
something in the way of restraint of trade. I insisted for that
reason that there should be a complete merger and
consolidation."
This idea that the "harmonious arrangement" was unlawful was
doubtless inspired in the mind of Howe by the decision in the
Trans-Missouri Freight Association Case, 166 U.
S. 290, rendered in 1897, and he probably shared a then
not uncommon notion that the holding company and the merger were
devices lawfully available for evading the congressional purpose
expressed in the Anti-Trust Act. But in the
Northern Securities
Case, 193 U. S. 197,
this Court decided in 1904 that the holding company was a futile
device, and in the
American Tobacco Company Case,
221 U. S. 106, it
was decided in 1911 that the merger was also
Page 247 U. S. 78
a mere "subterfuge of form" which the courts would not permit to
shield those who violated the act.
Thus, rejecting the "harmonious agreement" or "understanding" as
unlawful for the purpose of accomplishing the same end in what they
thought a not illegal way, the defendants resorted to the merger
(later on, as we shall see, using also the holding company) and
organized the United Shoe Machinery Company under the laws of New
Jersey, with a capital stock of $25,000,000.
The scope of the declaration of the purposes for which this
corporation was formed, as stated in its articles of incorporation,
is of much significance in determining what the real objective was
at which the persons interested were aiming. It is therein declared
that the company is formed not only "to manufacture, lease and sell
shoe machinery," but also
"to manufacture boots, shoes, and footwear and all articles of
every description that may be produced or manufactured in whole or
in part from leather, rubber, or any other materials or fabrics, .
. . to purchase, lease or otherwise acquire trademarks, tradenames,
copyrights and patent rights . . . , and, with a view to working
and developing the same, to carry on any legal business whatsoever
. . . , whether manufacturing or otherwise, which the corporation
may deem calculated, directly or indirectly, to accomplish these
objects or any of them. . . . To hold, purchase or otherwise
acquire . . . shares of capital stock . . . of any other
corporation or corporations . . . ; to do any or all of the above
things . . . in any part of the world."
As impressive proof of the objects of the incorporators, we
print in the margin some extracts from the certificate of
incorporation of the holding company, the "United Shoe Machinery
Corporation," organized in 1905, by the
Page 247 U. S. 79
men controlling the United Shoe Machinery Company, of 1899.*
Page 247 U. S. 80
And now, thus equipped with apparent legal authority, amply
sufficient, if successfully used, to restrain and monopolize among
the several states the branch of trade and commerce involved, let
us see what the defendants did.
First of all, $4,918,000 of the stock of the new company was
exchanged for all of the capital stock of the Goodyear and
International Goodyear Companies, and $4,432,000 of stock plus
$432,000 in cash was exchanged for all of the capital stock of the
Consolidated Company. By this merger, with fifteen millions of the
capital stock
Page 247 U. S. 81
of the new company still available for other uses, the two
largest manufacturers of lasting machines in the country were
combined, and Winslow testifies that:
"After the formation of the United Company, it was manufacturing
every single lasting machine that was being put out in the
United States except the Seaver machine, and in 1900 we acquired
the Seaver Company."
Next, and immediately, although Winslow testifies that "no word
had been spoken to either the McKay people or the Eppler people
when the charter for the United Company was obtained," the company
purchased the entire capital stock of the McKay Shoe Machinery
Company for five and one-half million dollars of stock of the
United Company. This company, Winslow testifies, was engaged in
manufacturing metallic fastening machines and heeling machines,
"was doing a very large business," and through controlled
subsidiaries was "putting out nearly all the metallic fastening
machines and nearly all the heeling machines that were being made
in the United States."
Thus, confessedly, by this union of these three companies there
were consolidated substantially all of the manufacturers of lasting
machines and of machines for attaching the soles of boots and shoes
to uppers with metallic fastenings and with thread, and in addition
to this the Davey Pegging Machine Company was owned by the
Consolidated Company.
There yet remained only one strong competitor doing business in
this country, the Eppler Welt Machine Company, with an
international subsidiary. Besides the Eppler, there was only one
other welt machine company engaged in business, the Globe, an
unimportant concern which, however, was acquired by the United
Company a little later, in 1901.
Although Winslow and Howe could remember within a small fraction
of a cent just what royalties were paid at any time for the use of
their machines, neither of them
Page 247 U. S. 82
could remember what was paid for the Eppler stock, and both
testified that the records of the company did not show the amount.
But other testimony shows that payment for it, of between $350,000
and $400,000 in cash, was made within a few weeks after the
organization of the United Company, and it was admitted,
significantly, that no inventory was taken at the time of the
purchase of either the McKay or Eppler stock.
That the Goodyear and Eppler machines were sharply competitive
is shown by the testimony of both Winslow and Howe. Winslow
testifies that, just before the consolidation, the Eppler Company
was "manufacturing a welting machine, an outsole stitching machine,
and auxiliary machines," and that the Goodyear Company was making
a
"welting machine, an outsole stitching machine, and auxiliary
machines that performed the same function as the auxiliary machines
of the Eppler Company, and a number in addition."
"Both machines," continues Winslow, "were being used in the
manufacture of men's welt shoes," and "the two welting machines
that were being specially pressed on the market at that time were
the Goodyear machine and the Eppler machine." And Howe
testifies:
"Those two types of shoes were well known in the trade. There
was the Goodyear welt, which was a recognized class shoe. We didn't
know whether the manufacturers would prefer Eppler welts or whether
they would prefer Goodyear welts."
What these two dominating spirits of the enterprise thought of
their work at the stage of its development which we have thus far
described is interesting and illuminating as to their purpose.
Thus, Winslow:
"Immediately after the organization of the company, our welting,
outsole stitching, and lasting machines were doing about all the
welting, outsole stitching, and lasting that was being done in the
United States. "
Page 247 U. S. 83
"Q. And so with your heeling and metallic fastening
machines?"
"A. Not so much the heeling."
And this from Howe: "When the United was formed, I don't
remember that any outside concerns were putting out lasting
machines,"
"and he elsewhere says, on cross-examination that lasting
machines of the Goodyear and Consolidated Companies overlapped in
the work which was done with them and, if this was true, obviously
they must have been competitors in the market."
To this must be added the statements made in circulars sent at
this time to the smaller stockholders of the companies to induce
them to join in the combination. Thus, to stockholders of the
Goodyear Company:
"The great advantages to be secured by the control in one
corporation, both in the United States and in foreign countries, of
the most efficient types of shoe machinery have been for several
years recognized by the officers of the principal large machinery
companies. For more than a year, your directors and large
shareholders have been in negotiation to accomplish this end. After
a thorough investigation of the financial condition of the business
of the shoe machinery companies named below, the organization of a
corporation has been effected under the laws of the State of New
Jersey, to be known as the United Shoe Machinery Company. . . . The
United Shoe Machinery Company has already contracted for more than
a majority of the capital stock of [the companies named other than
the Eppler Company and the Davey Pegging Machine Company], besides
stocks in other machine companies and letters patent."
"The United Company will from time to time acquire other
machinery and property, either by direct ownership or purchase of
shares of their stock."
I cannot share in estimating this circular as simply a naive
expression of unusual business foresight. It was a
Page 247 U. S. 84
confidential circular, boldly phrased, perhaps because its
authors thought that their combination had been given a character
of merger which could withstand government attack, but which this
Court has since repeatedly held is a mere subterfuge of form. The
circular is an accurate description of what had been accomplished
and of what, as we shall see, the evidence in the record shows, was
intended to be done in the future.
It would seem that men who were not bent upon complete monopoly
and control would have been satisfied with the advantages which, we
have thus seen, those in this enterprise clearly held over any
competitors who might remain or who might appear in the future. But
that the man connected with the United Company were not satisfied,
and were determined to make their control as perfect and permanent
as possible, is shown by their further conduct during the first
year of the existence of that company, as follows:
Within a month of the organization of the United Company, on
March 1, 1899, for the sum of $74,800 worth of its capital stock,
it purchased the control of the Goddu Company, which was
manufacturing metallic fastening machines which competed with those
of the absorbed McKay Company, and the six inventors who owned the
stock were bound by the contract of purchase to transfer to the
United Company all inventions relating to shoe machinery which they
jointly or severally might make or have any interest in for a
period of ten years, and they were also bound not to become
interested "directly or indirectly" for a like term "in the
business of making or selling any inventions or improvements
relating in any way to shoe machinery," or relating in any way to
the manufacture of boots and shoes or useful in connection
therewith "without the consent in writing of the United
Company."
On the 16th day of the same month, the company purchased from
Winkle and Phillips the exclusive license
Page 247 U. S. 85
to use the inventions and improvements in sole leveling
machines, described in ten letters patent of the United States and
in patents of Great Britain, France, and Germany, and bound the
inventors to communicate to the United Company all inventions
"which they, or either of them, shall hereafter make" in sole
leveling machines or sole pressing machines. Howe testifies that,
at the time of this purchase, the United Company was making
machines of the kind, but of a different type.
On August 26, 1899, for the sum of $72,000, the company
purchased the business of Timothy Bresnahan, together with the
entire capital stock of the Boston Shoe Tool Company. It employed
Bresnahan as manager for two years and bound him by contract not to
thereafter
"engage in . . . the manufacture of heel trimmings, edge
trimmings, or edge setting machines and tools . . . or of any
machines, tools, or product now [then] made"
by him or by the Boston Shoe Tool Company, and that he would
not
"directly or indirectly aid, assist, or encourage any
competition with the Boston Shoe Tool Company or its business, but
would do everything in his power to promote the interests of the
United Company."
On October 11th of the same year, the company purchased from one
Brewer, for $250 and $5 royalty on each machine which should be
manufactured, his application for letters patent for an improvement
in heel breasting machines, the one machine he had manufactured and
the tools with which he had made it, and it took an assignment from
Brewer "of any and all inventions he may hereafter make relative to
breasting heels on the last."
The attempt made in argument to justify as familiar business
practice such contracts as these, binding inventors from whom
patents and other property were purchased to surrender to the
United Company all of the
Page 247 U. S. 86
fruits of their inventive genius for many years after the
purchase, and often for many years after their employment had
ceased, is disingenuous in the extreme. In a single terse sentence,
this Court has made conclusive answer to such contention,
saying:
"Even if separate elements of such a scheme are lawful, when
they are bound together by a common interest as parts of an
unlawful scheme to monopolize interstate commerce the plan may make
the parts unlawful."
Swift & Co. v. United States, 196 U.
S. 375;
United States v. Reading Co.,
226 U. S. 324.
On January 30, 1900, the company purchased, for the sum of
$38,000, the business and assets, including twenty United States
and foreign patents and 138 lasting machines, of the Seaver Process
Lasting Company. This was the only independent company putting
lasting machines on the market after the combination was formed,
and it removed the last vestige of competition in the lasting
machine business.
This will suffice. They are typical of fifty-seven purchases
proved to have been made by the United Company prior to the
commencement of this suit; of shoe machinery manufacturing
companies; of boot and shoe manufacturing companies; of patent
rights or applications for such rights, and of the property and
businesses of partnerships and corporations engaged in
manufacturing appliances "calculated," in the language of the
charter of the company, "directly or indirectly, to accomplish the
objects, or any of them, of the corporation," and varying from
sewing machine needles and awls, to tacking machines, to buttons,
brushes and sandpaper. Brewer's $250 application for a patent was
not too small to be overlooked, and we shall see a $6,000,000
purchase was not too great to be made in order to continue, to
extend, and to make secure the complete control over the business
involved which was first attained by the consolidation of the
Good-year and Consolidated Companies
Page 247 U. S. 87
and the purchase of the McKay and Eppler Companies in 1899.
The history of the first year of this company would not be
complete without reference to the fact that the combinations and
purchases made during that year resulted in collecting under one
control many hundreds of patents covering every "shadow of a shade"
of variation in the parts of the many machines used in the
manufacture of shoes, and it must be noticed that, in the month of
December, 1900, the first of the forms of leases were developed and
brought into use which came to be known in the trade as
"iron-clad," and which have been discussed by MR. JUSTICE DAY in a
dissenting opinion in which I cordially concur.
The boot and shoe trade of the country was so restless under
what was regarded and unhesitatingly denounced as a monopoly,
strongly entrenched, that, although the men engaged in that trade
were now utterly dependent upon the United Company for the terms on
which they might continue to do business, at least two groups of
important manufacturers were formed before the commencement of this
suit for the purpose of devising, if possible, some means of
freeing themselves from conditions which they regarded, as the
record abundantly shows, as oppressive and intolerable.
Under the spur of this incentive, it came to pass that a large
manufacturer of shoes, one Plant, of Boston, developed a line of
shoe manufacturing machinery so complete in character that, on May
1, 1910, he cancelled the leases which he held on many machines
owned by the United Company and removed them from his factory, and
advertised his readiness to supply manufacturers with adequate, and
what was termed, "wonder-working shoe machinery."
By Winslow's own story, negotiations for the purchase of Plant's
shoe machinery manufacturing business by the United Company were
entered upon on June 16th,
Page 247 U. S. 88
within two months of the time that he removed their machines
from his factory. These negotiations were interrupted on July 5th,
and on the 28th of the same month four suits were commenced by the
United Company against Plant, two more were commenced on August
11th, two more on August 13th, and two more on September 3rd. These
suits were in part to recover royalties claimed for the use of the
United machines before they were taken out of Plant's factory, and
the rest were to enjoin him from using his own machines, on the
ground that they infringed patents of the United Company.
Whether as a result of this familiar resort to coercive measures
need not be determined, but, on September 22nd at 4 o'clock in the
morning, possibly to anticipate negotiations which were in progress
for the purchase of Plant's property by a group of wealthy shoe
manufacturers, the United Company purchased Plant's shoe machinery
manufacturing business and patents, and also the control which he
owned of the capital stock of a shoe manufacturing company. The
United Company paid for these two properties six millions of
dollars, plus $122,000 for the Stambon property, which Plant
insisted must be purchased as a part of the transaction. This large
sum of money, larger than was paid for either of the original
constituent companies of the consolidation, was not divided in the
contract of sale, but Winslow allots three and one-half millions to
the purchase of the shoe manufacturing company stock and two and
one-half millions to the purchase of the shoe machinery
manufacturing company and patents. Even this division, it will be
observed, allows two and one-half millions of dollars to be paid
for the Plant machinery company property and patents, which it is
now argued were of little value and, at best, were infringements of
patents owned by the United Company. Mr. Winslow, however, thought
better of them, for he says they were "almost invaluable" to his
company.
Page 247 U. S. 89
It is impossible for me to understand how the transaction thus
described in Winslow's own words can fail to convince anyone who
reads or hears the description that the Plant Company was a
formidable competitor, actual and potential, of the United Company,
and that the great sum of money paid to control it was paid to
stifle and restrict competition. Standing alone, it shows the
defendant to be an unmistakable offender against the Anti-Trust
law, but when taken together with the origin of the company and
with the history of the conduct of it, a small but typical part of
which we have described, it seems to me a flagrant and an all but
confessed offender against that law, as it has been repeatedly
interpreted by this Court,
United States v. American Tobacco
Co., 221 U. S. 106,
221 U. S. 179;
United States v. Reading Co., 226 U.
S. 324;
United States v. Patten, 226 U.
S. 525;
Eastern States Retail Lumber Dealers' Assn.
v. United States, 234 U. S. 600, and
against the policy of the law as expressed in the act of
Congress.
I shall add only the convincing statement as to the complete
ascendancy which the combination has attained over the important
branch of the industry of the country selected for its control,
which is shown in the following results tabulated in the brief of
the government from the testimony, and from which all elements
seriously disputed by counsel for defendants have been
excluded:
Manuf'd Manuf'd
Machines in Use in this Country by De- by All
fendants Others
Lasting machines . . . . . . . . . 7,496 7
Standard screw machines. . . . . . 409 None
Pegging machines . . . . . . . . . 146 None
Tacking machines . . . . . . . . . 3,488 6
Welt-sewing machines . . . . . . . 2,527 142
Outsole stitching machines . . . . 2,676 758
Loose-nailing machines . . . . . . 1,835 24
Heeling machines . . . . . . . . . 2,019 17
Page 247 U. S. 90
Further details could not add to the effect of the large outline
we have thus presented. This is not a case to be decided upon the
detailed statements of individuals as to their intentions or upon
refined distinctions as to the application of the patent law. The
design was a large one, comprehensively conceived and boldly
executed. The dominating spirits of the enterprise, with the
advantage of knowing precisely what they wished to accomplish,
rejected a "harmonious arrangement" of their interests as unlawful,
but to accomplish the same end they adopted the scheme of merger
since condemned by this Court as a mere "subterfuge of form."
The trade recognized the combination as a monopoly from the
beginning, and for years struggled in vain to free itself by
organizing competing interests; the Judiciary Committee of the
House of Representatives, when the Clayton bill was under
consideration, reported as the result of its investigations that
the company appeared to be "a monopoly that owns and controls the
entire machinery now being used by all the great shoe manufacturing
houses of the United States," and, with a record before me such as
in outline I have detailed, it is impossible for me to agree that
this now securely entrenched monopoly is an innocent result of
normal business development.
The difficulties of bringing the defendants within the
restraints of the law, which are regarded by the Court as all but
insurmountable, seem unimpressive in the presence of the resolute
manner with which this Court dealt with difficulties quite as
complex and interests vastly greater in the
Northern
Securities, Standard Oil, and
Tobacco Company cases,
supra. In the last named of these cases, it was found
unnecessary, "in order to give effect to the requirements of the
statute," to apply the remedy of restraining the movement of the
products of the combination in interstate commerce, or that of
appointing a receiver for the property of the offender, for
Page 247 U. S. 91
the simple declaration by the Court of its readiness to resort
to either or both of these effective remedies if the conduct of the
parties or the exigencies of the situation should require it,
served in that case, as it would in this, to open the way for
bringing the powerful interests involved into obedience to the
law.
Convinced as I am by a most careful study of this record that
the United Shoe Machinery Company is a combination in restraint of
interstate trade and commerce, that it was designed to and actually
does monopolize a large part of that trade and commerce, and that
it therefore is a continuing violation of both §§ 1 and 2
of the Anti-Trust Act of July 2, 1890, I am obliged to dissent from
the opinion and judgment of the Court.
I am authorized to say that MR. JUSTICE DAY and MR. JUSTICE
PITNEY concur in this dissent.
* The following are excerpts from the articles of incorporation
of the "United Shoe Machinery Corporation," with a capital stock of
$50,000,000, filed May 2, 1905:
"Third. The objects for which the corporation is formed
are:"
"To manufacture, buy, sell, lease, operate, and deal in and with
all kinds of machinery, tools, and implements, and mechanical
devices and contrivances of every name and nature whatsoever, and
especially to manufacture, buy, sell, lease, operate, and deal in
and with all sorts of boot and shoe machinery, lasts, trees, forms,
and every kind of mechanism, contrivance, implement, tool,
material, or thing in any way whatsoever connected with, or useful
in connection with the manufacture of boots, shoes, and footwear,
or the manufacture of leather and rubber goods, or goods made from
materials and fabrics of any description whatsoever, or useful in
connection with the manufacture or operation of any of the
machinery, mechanical devices, or contrivances hereinbefore
mentioned; to produce, prepare and manufacture, buy, sell, and deal
in and with leather and rubber, and materials and fabrics of all
sorts, and the raw materials from which said leather, rubber
materials, or fabrics are produced; to manufacture, buy, sell, and
deal in and with boots, shoes and footwear and all articles and
things of every description that may be produced or manufactured,
in whole or in part, from leather, rubber, or any other materials
or fabrics, and in general to produce, prepare, manufacture, and
deal in and with goods, wares, merchandise, property, materials,
and things of every class and description."
"To carry on the business of manufacturers of and dealers in all
kinds of eyelets, hooks, buttons, studs, nails, wires, rivets,
tacks, metallic and other plates, metallic, wood, and other
fastenings, laces, cloth, linen, tape, and other fabrics, brushes,
abrasive materials, cements, dressings, stains, blackings, and
other requisites for the improvement and treatment of boots and
shoes, threads, elastic material, buttons, and inner soles, and
other articles or substances for protecting feet from damp or heat,
and other articles or substances used in connection with the
manufacture of boots and shoes, corsets, stationery, sails, tents,
clothing, and for analogous purposes, and to carry on the business
of manufacturers of and dealers in all kinds of appliances,
devices, findings, tools, mechanisms, accessories, processes, and
things which may be used or useful in connection with the
manufacture or treatment of any of the above-named articles or
substances. . . ."
"To apply for, obtain, register, purchase, lease, or otherwise
acquire, and to hold, own, use, operate, introduce, sell, assign,
or otherwise dispose of any and all trademarks, tradenames and
distinctive marks, copyrights, patents and patent rights, and all
inventions, improvements and processes used in connection with or
secured under letters patent of the United States or elsewhere, or
otherwise, and to use, exercise, develop, grant licenses in respect
of, or otherwise turn to account any such trademarks, patents,
licenses, concessions, processes and the like, or any such
property, rights, and information so acquired, and, with a view to
the working and development of the same, to carry on any legal
business whatsoever, whether manufacturing or otherwise, which the
corporation may deem calculated, directly or indirectly, to
accomplish these objects or any of them. . . ."
"To purchase, acquire by subscription or otherwise, and to hold
for investment or otherwise, use, sell, assign, transfer, mortgage,
pledge, or otherwise dispose of and to guarantee any shares of
stock, bonds, securities, or other obligations of any other
corporation or association carrying on any business which this
corporation is authorized to carry on. . . ."
"To enter into partnership or into any arrangement for sharing
profits, union of interest, joint adventure, or cooperation with
any person, partnership, association, or corporation carrying on or
engaged in any business which this corporation is authorized to
carry on or engage in. . . ."
"To do all and everything necessary or convenient for the
accomplishment of the purposes, objects, and powers above-mentioned
or incidental thereto, and to conduct its business, or do anything
which it is authorized to do, in every state and in the territories
and colonies of the United States of America and in foreign
countries. . . ."