An antitrust criminal law may not necessarily be
unconstitutional merely because it throws upon men the risk of
rightly estimating what is an undue restraint of trade, but to
compel a man to guess what the fair market value of commodities
manufactured or sold by him would be under other than existing
conditions is beyond constitutional limits.
The antitrust provision of the Constitution of 1891 and of the
Acts of 1900 and 1906 of Kentucky, as construed by the highest
court of that state, are unconstitutional under the Fourteenth
Amendment as offering no standard of conduct that it is possible to
know in advance and comply with. 147 Ky. 564;
id., 795;
148 Ky. 572, reversed.
The facts, which involve the constitutionality of antitrust
provisions of the constitution and laws of Kentucky, are stated in
the opinion.
Page 234 U. S. 219
MR. JUSTICE HOLMES delivered the opinion of the Court.
The plaintiff in error was prosecuted, convicted, and fined in
three different counties for having entered into an agreement with
other named companies for the purpose of controlling the price of
harvesters, etc., manufactured by them, and of enhancing it above
their real value, and for having so fixed and enhanced the price,
and for having sold their harvesters, etc. at a price in excess of
their real value, in pursuance of the agreement alleged. The
judgments were affirmed by the Court of Appeals. 147 Ky. 564,
id., 144 Ky. 795, 148 Ky. 572. The plaintiff in error
saved its rights under the Fourteenth Amendment and brought the
cases here.
The law of Kentucky in its present form is the result of the
construction of several statutes somewhat far apart in time and of
seemingly contradictory import. It was argued that construction
could not take the place of express language in a statute, and
Louisville &
Nashville
Page 234 U. S. 220
R. Co. v. Central Stock Yards Co., 212 U.
S. 132,
212 U. S. 144,
was cited for the proposition. But the case gives no sanction to
it. The point there was that a defect in a law could not be cured
by precautions in a judgment -- not that what seemed a defect could
not be cured by the construction given to the words by the court
having final authority to declare their intent. We follow the
Kentucky Court of Appeals in taking what they derive from the
legislation of the state as if it were embodied in a single
act.
The history in brief is this: by an act of May 20, 1890,
agreements for the purpose of fixing or limiting the amount or
quantity of any article of merchandise to be produced or
manufactured, mined, bought, or sold, as also combinations by
corporations with others to put the business of the combination
under control with intent to limit, fix, or change the price of
articles of commerce, or in any way to diminish the output of such
articles, were made punishable by fine, imprisonment, or both.
Carroll's Kentucky Statutes §§ 3915-3917. In 1891, a new
Constitution was adopted by the state, by § 198 of which it
was made the duty of the General Assembly
"from time to time, as necessity may require, to enact such laws
as may be necessary to prevent all trusts . . . from combining to
depreciate below its real value any article, or to enhance the cost
of any article above its real value."
This was held not to repeal the earlier statute.
Commonwealth v. International Harvester Co., 131 Ky. 551,
566. But Kentucky grows tobacco, and the farmers were dissatisfied
with the prices that they were able to get, being oppressed, as
they alleged, by a combination of buyers. So, on March 21, 1906, a
statute was enacted that made it lawful for any number of persons
to combine the crops of wheat, tobacco, corn, oats, hay, or other
farm products raised by them for the purpose of obtaining a higher
price than they could get by selling them separately. Session Laws
1906, c. 117, p. 429. And later, by an act of
Page 234 U. S. 221
March 13, 1908, not only was the legality of these
last-mentioned combinations reaffirmed, but they were protected by
injunction, and the sale by or purchase from the owner contrary to
his agreement was punished by a fine.
When the Court of Appeals came to deal with the Act of 1890, the
Constitution of 1891, and the Act of 1906, it reached the
conclusion, which now may be regarded as the established
construction of the three, taken together, that, by interaction and
to avoid questions of constitutionality, they were to be taken to
make any combination for the purpose of controlling prices lawful
unless for the purpose or with the effect of fixing a price that
was greater or less than the real value of the article.
Owen
County Burley Tobacco Society v. Brumback, 128 Ky. 137, 151;
Commonwealth v. International Harvester Co., 131 Ky. 551,
568, 571-573;
International Harvester Co. v. Commonwealth,
137 Ky. 668. The result seems to be that combinations of tobacco
growers are held to do no more than restore an equilibrium that has
been disturbed by a combination of buyers (
Owne County Burley
Tobacco Society v. Brumback, 128 Ky. 137, 152;
Collins v.
Commonwealth, 141 Ky. 564), whereas, if prices rise after a
combination of manufacturers, it very nearly is presumed that the
advance is above the real value, and that there is a crime.
International Harvester Co. v. Commonwealth, 144 Ky. 403,
410-411.
The plaintiff in error contends that the law as construed offers
no standard of conduct that it is possible to know. To meet this in
the present and earlier cases, the real value is declared to be
"the market value under fair competition, and under normal market
conditions." 147 Ky. 566.
Commonwealth v. International
Harvester Co., 131 Ky. 551, 576;
International Harvester
Co. v. Commonwealth, 137
Page 234 U. S. 222
Ky. 668, 677-678. We have to consider whether, in application,
this is more than an illusory form of words, when, nine years after
it was incorporated, a combination invited by the law is required
to guess at its peril what its product would have sold for if the
combination had not existed and nothing else violently affecting
values had occurred. It seems that, since 1902, the price of the
machinery sold by the plaintiff in error has risen from 10 to 15
percent. The testimony on its behalf showed that, meantime, the
cost of materials used had increased from 20 to 25 percent and
labor 27 1/2 percent. Whatever doubt there may be about the exact
figures, we hardly suppose the fact of a rise to be denied. But, in
order to reach what is called the real value -- a price from which
all effects of the combination are to be eliminated -- the
plaintiff in error is told that it cannot avail itself of the rise
in materials, because it was able to get them cheaper through one
of the subsidiary companies of the combination, and that the saving
through the combination more than offset all the rise in cost.
This perhaps more plainly concerns the justice of the law in its
bearing upon the plaintiff in error, when compared with its
operation upon tobacco raisers who are said to have doubled or
trebled their prices, than on the constitutional question proposed.
But it also concerns that, for it shows how impossible it is to
think away the principal facts of the case as it exists, and say
what would have been the price in an imaginary world. Value is the
effect in exchange of the relative social desire for compared
objects expressed in terms of a common denominator. It is a fact,
and generally is more or less easy to ascertain. But what it would
be with such increase of a never extinguished competition as it
might be guessed would have existed had the combination not been
made, with exclusion of the actual effect of other abnormal
influences, and, it would seem, with exclusion also of any
increased
Page 234 U. S. 223
efficiency in the machines, but with inclusion of the effect of
the combination so far as it was economically beneficial to itself
and the community, is a problem that no human ingenuity could
solve. The reason is not the general uncertainties of a jury trial,
but that the elements necessary to determine the imaginary ideal
are uncertain both in nature and degree of effect to the acutest
commercial mind. The very community, the intensity of whose wish
relatively to its other competing desires determines the price that
it would give, has to be supposed differently organized and subject
to other influences than those under which its acts. It is easy to
put simple cases, but the one before us is at least as complex as
we have supposed, and the law must be judged by it. In our opinion,
it cannot stand.
We regard this decision as consistent with
Nash v. United
States, 229 U. S. 373,
229 U. S. 377,
in which it was held that a criminal law is not unconstitutional
merely because it throws upon men the risk of rightly estimating a
matter of degree -- what is an undue restraint of trade. That deals
with the actual, not with an imaginary, condition other than the
facts. It goes no further than to recognize that, as with
negligence, between the two extremes of the obviously illegal and
the plainly lawful, there is a gradual approach, and that the
complexity of life makes it impossible to draw a line in advance
without an artificial simplification that would be unjust. The
conditions are as permanent as anything human, and a great body of
precedents on the civil side, coupled with familiar practice, make
it comparatively easy for common sense to keep to what is safe. But
if business is to go on, men must unite to do it, and must sell
their wares. To compel them to guess, on peril of indictment, what
the community would have given for them if the continually changing
conditions were other than they are, to an uncertain extent; to
divine prophetically what the reaction of only partially
determinate
Page 234 U. S. 224
facts would be upon the imaginations and desires of purchasers,
is to exact gifts that mankind does not possess.
Judgments reversed.
MR. JUSTICE McKENNA and MR. JUSTICE PITNEY dissent.