The business of insurance is so far affected with a public
interest as to justify legislative regulation of its rates.
A public interest can exist in a business, such as insurance,
distinct from a public use of property, and can be the basis of the
power of the legislature to regulate the personal contracts
involved in such business.
Where a business such as insurance is affected by a public use,
it is the business that is the fundamental thing; property is but
the instrument of such business.
Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113;
Budd v. New York, 143 U. S. 517;
Brass v. North Dakota, 153 U. S. 391,
demonstrate that a business, by circumstances and its nature, may
rise from private to public concern and consequently become subject
to governmental regulation, and the business of insurance falls
within this principle.
The fact that a contract for insurance is one for indemnity and
is personal does not preclude regulation.
A general conception of the lawmaking bodies of the country that
a business requires governmental regulation is not accidental, and
cannot exist without cause.
What makes for the general welfare is matter of legislative
judgment, and judicial review is limited to power, and excludes
policy.
The liberty of contract guaranteed by the Fourteenth Amendment
is not more intimately involved in price regulation than in other
proper forms of regulation of business and property affected by a
public use, and so
held as to the regulation of rates of
fire insurance.
The inactivity of a governmental power, no matter how prolonged,
does not militate against its legality when exercised.
United
States v. Delaware & Hudson Co., 213 U.
S. 366.
Whether rate regulation is necessary in regard to a particular
business affected by a public use, such as insurance, is matter for
legislative
Page 233 U. S. 390
judgment. This Court can only determine whether the legislature
has the power to enact it.
A discrimination is not invalid under the equal protection
provision of the Fourteenth Amendment if not so arbitrary as to be
beyond the wide discretion that a legislature may exercise, and so
held as to a classification exempting farmers' mutual
insurance companies doing only a farm business from the operation
of an act regulating rates of insurance.
A legislative classification may rest on narrow distinctions.
Legislation is addressed to evils as they appear, and even degrees
of evil may determine its exercise.
Ozan Lumber Co. v. Union
National Bank, 207 U. S. 251.
The Kansas statute of 1909, so far as it provides for regulating
rates of fire insurance, is not unconstitutional under the
Fourteenth Amendment as depriving insurance companies of their
property without due process of law, as abridging the liberty of
contract, or as denying companies charging regular premiums the
equal protection of the law by excepting farmers' mutual insurance
companies from its operation.
Bill in equity to restrain the enforcement of the provisions of
an act of the State of Kansas entitled, "An Act Relating to Fire
Insurance, and to Provide for the Regulation and Control of Rates
of Premium Thereon, and to Prevent Discriminations Therein." Chap.
152 of the Session Laws of 1909.
The grounds of the bill are that the act offends the
Constitution of the state and of the United States.
A summary of the requirements of the act is as follows:
Sec. 1. Every fire insurance company shall file with the
superintendent of insurance general basis schedules showing the
rates on all risks insurable by such company in the state, and all
the conditions which affect the rates or the value of the insurance
to the assured.
Sec. 2. No change shall be made in the schedules except after
ten days' notice to the superintendent, which notice shall state
the changes proposed and the time when they
Page 233 U. S. 391
shall go into effect. The superintendent may allow changes upon
less notice.
Sec. 3. When the superintendent shall determine any rate is
excessive or unreasonably high, or not adequate to the safety or
soundness of the company, he is authorized to direct the company to
publish and file a higher or lower rate, which shall be
commensurate with the character of the risk; but in every case the
rate shall be reasonable.
Sec. 4. No company shall engage or participate in insurance on
property located in the state until the schedules of rates be
filed, nor write insurance at a different rate than the rate named
in the schedules, or refund or remit in any manner or by any device
any portion of the rates; or extend to any insured or other person
any privileges, inducements, or concessions except as specified in
the schedules.
Sec. 5. Any company making insurance where no rate has been
filed shall, within thirty days after entering into such contract,
file with the superintendent a schedule of such property, showing
the rate and such information as he may require. The schedule shall
conform to the general basis of schedules, and shall constitute the
permanent rate of the company.
Sec. 6. The schedules shall be open to the inspection of the
public, and each local agent shall have and exhibit to the public
copies thereof relative to all risks upon which he is authorized to
write insurance.
Sec. 7. No company shall, directly or indirectly, by any special
rate or by any device, charge or receive from any person a
different rate of compensation for insurance than it charges or
receives from any other person for like insurance or risks of a
like kind and hazard under similar circumstances and conditions in
the state. Any company violating this provision shall be deemed
guilty of unjust discrimination, which is declared unlawful.
Sec. 8. The superintendent may, if he finds that any
Page 233 U. S. 392
company, or any officer, agent, or representative thereof has
violated any of the provisions of the act, revoke the license of
such offending company, officer, or agent, but such revocation
shall not affect liability for the violation of any other section
of the act, and provided that any action, decision, or
determination of the superintendent under the provisions of the act
shall be subject to review by the courts of the state as provided
in the act.
Sec. 9. The superintendent shall give notice of any order or
regulation made by him under the act, and any company, or any
person, city, or municipality which shall be interested shall have
the right, within thirty days, to bring an action against the
superintendent in any district court of the state to have the order
or regulation vacated. Issues shall be formed and the controversy
tried and determined as in other cases of a civil nature, and the
court may set aside one or more or any part of any of the
regulations or orders which the court shall find to be
unreasonable, unjust, excessive, or inadequate to compensate the
company writing insurance thereon for the risk assumed by it,
without disturbing others. The order of the superintendent shall
not be suspended or enjoined, but the court may permit the
complaining company to write insurance at the rates which obtained
prior to such order upon the condition that the difference in the
rates shall be deposited with the superintendent to be paid to the
company or to the holders of policies as, on final determination of
the suit, the court may deem just and reasonable. During the
pendency of the suit, no penalties or forfeitures shall attach or
accrue on account of the failure of the complainant to comply with
the order sought to be vacated or modified until the final
determination of the suit. Proceedings in error may be instituted
in the supreme court of the state as in other civil cases, and that
court shall examine the record, including the evidence, and render
such judgment as shall be just and equitable. No action
Page 233 U. S. 393
shall be brought in the United States courts until the remedies
provided by the act shall have been exhausted. If any company
organized under the laws of the state, or authorized to transact
business in a state, shall violate the section, the superintendent
may cancel the authority of the company to transact business in the
state.
Sec. 10. Infractions of the act are declared to be misdemeanors,
and punishable by a fine not exceeding $100 for each offense,
provided that, if the conviction be for an unlawful discrimination,
the punishment may be by a fine or by imprisonment in the county
jail not exceeding ninety days, or by both fine and
imprisonment.
Sec. 11. No person shall be excused from testifying at the trial
of any other person on the ground that the testimony may
incriminate him, but he shall not be prosecuted on account of any
transaction about which he may testify, except for perjury
committed in so testifying,
"provided, that nothing in this act shall affect farmers' mutual
insurance companies, organized and doing business under the laws of
this state and insuring only farm property."
The bill alleged that it was brought by the German Alliance
Insurance Company in behalf of itself and all other companies and
corporations conducting a similar business and similarly situated,
and that Charles W. Barnes was the duly elected Superintendent of
Fire Insurance of the State of Kansas. It alleged the
jurisdictional amount, and that the controversy was one arising
under the Constitution of the United States and of the State of
Kansas. It alleged further the following facts, which we state in
narrative form, omitting those which relate to the constitution of
the state, no assignment of error being based upon them. The
appellant, to which we shall refer as complainant, was incorporated
under the laws of New York as a fire insurance company in 1879, and
immediately entered upon such business, and it has for long periods
of
Page 233 U. S. 394
time conducted the business of fire insurance in Kansas and
other states of the United States.
The business of fire insurance, as conducted by it, consists of
making indemnity contracts against direct loss or damage by fire
for a consideration paid, known as a premium; that the rate or
premium is the amount charged for each $100 of indemnity. The
property which is the subject of insurance is ordinarily known and
designated as the risk. Complainant issues indemnity contracts or
fire insurance policies covering all kinds and descriptions of
improvements upon real estate and the contents thereof, and all
kinds and descriptions of personal property, and also farm houses,
barns, and granaries and their contents. The rate of premium varies
with the kind of property covered, its physical characteristics and
situation, its exposure, the presence or absence of fire
protection, and many other causes.
The establishment of the basis rate for the premium to be
charged is a matter of technical and mathematical deduction from
the experience of all fire insurance companies, covering a long
period of years, and, territorially, the whole civilized world. To
make such deduction it is necessary not only to be in possession of
the compiled statistics of fire insurance business, but also to be
skilled in the mathematical "theory of probabilities" and in the
"law of large numbers" so as to be able to apply with technical
accuracy such laws and such data, and that no one not specially
trained as an insurance statistician is competent to make such
deductions.
A theoretically correct basis rate, having thus been arrived at,
is subject to variation according to the risk, whether in town or
country, and, if in the former, according to the class of town or
city in which it is situated. The classification of towns and
cities depends upon water supply, fire protection, and general
physical conditions. In addition to ascertaining the individual
risk, if a building,
Page 233 U. S. 395
the size, material of which, and the manner in which it is
constructed, the character of the occupancy, and the character of
the occupancy and construction of adjacent buildings, also the
character of the contents of the buildings, and the manner in which
they are stored, and the precautions used to detect and prevent
fires are necessary to be ascertained.
Complainant and others engaged in the insurance business employ
a large number of men skilled as inspectors to report upon
individual risks, and it is impossible to fix and adjust a
reasonable rate of premium for each and every individual risk
without the information so obtained and having the same applied by
experts. And such training and information are necessary to
determine whether a basic rate or actual rate, as applied to any
particular risk, is or is not reasonable, and the respondent is not
possessed of the requisite information or special training
necessary to qualify for such determination, and any conclusion to
which he might come would be a mere guess or arbitrary
determination, and the provisions of the act can only be properly
administered, in any event, by the employment by the state of a
corps of inspectors and experts specially trained in the business
of fixing rates of fire insurance.
The complainant has complied with all of the laws of the state,
and has received the regular license or authorization of the state
to transact the business of fire insurance therein.
It conducts its business by means of resident agents, of which
it has seventy-two directly employed; it has a large and valuable
established business, to secure which it has expended a large sum
of money, and to be compelled to give up its business would result
in irreparable damage and injury to it. A large number of the fire
insurance policies issued by complainant are written upon farm
buildings and their contents, and, in writing such business,
Page 233 U. S. 396
it comes into direct competition with various farmers' mutual
insurance companies organized and doing business under the laws of
the state and insuring only farm property.
The business of fire insurance is purely and exclusively a
private business, and may be transacted by private persons in their
individual capacity, or by unincorporated or incorporated
companies; that the amount of indemnity and the premium is a matter
of private negotiation and agreement, and the act of the
Legislature of the State of Kansas attempts to regulate the
business insofar as the fixing of the rate of premium is concerned,
and in the attempted regulation distinguishes between fire
insurance companies and individuals and partnerships, and thereby
denies to complainant and other companies the equal protection of
the law, contrary to the Fourteenth Amendment to the Constitution
of the United States, and is therefore unconstitutional and
void.
Under the laws of Kansas, mutual fire insurance companies may be
organized, that such companies having a guaranteed fund of $25,000
may do business on a cash basis and accept premiums in cash, and
that such premium measures the total liability of the insured under
the policy, either to the company or to its creditors; that, by the
eleventh section of the act under review, it is provided
"that nothing in this act shall affect farmers' mutual insurance
companies organized and doing business under the laws of this state
and insuring only farm property."
The complainant and many other companies insure farm property
and come into direct competition with farmers' mutual companies of
the character specified, and the act of the legislature in
excepting the latter companies deprives complainant of the equal
protection of the laws, and is therefore repugnant to the
Fourteenth Amendment of the Constitution of the United States and
is unconstitutional and void.
Page 233 U. S. 397
The business of fire insurance is private, with which the state
has no right to interfere, and the right to fix by private contract
the rate of premium is a property right of value; the business is
not a monopoly, either legally or actually; it may not be legally
conducted by the national government or by the State of Kansas or
other states under their respective constitutions, and is not a
business included within the functions of government. Neither
complainant nor others engaged in fire insurance receive or enjoy
from the State of Kansas or any government, state or national, any
privilege or immunity not in like manner and to like extent
received and enjoyed by all other persons, partnerships, and
companies, incorporated or unincorporated, respectively, engaged in
the conduct of other lines of private business and enterprises.
Complainant therefore is deprived of one of the incidents of
liberty and of its property without due process of law, in
violation of the Fourteenth Amendment to the Constitution of the
United States.
The act distinguishes between fire insurance companies and other
insurance companies, individuals, and persons, and distinguishes
between insurance and other lines of business, and thereby offends
the equality clause of the Constitution of the United States.
Complainant, under protest, filed the general basis schedules of
its rates as required by the act, which were arrived at by the
process hereinbefore set out. On the 19th of August, 1909,
respondent made a reduction of 12% from the rates as filed and from
the rates filed by other companies, with the proviso that it should
not apply to residence property, churches, schoolhouses, farm
property, or special hazards. The order was to become effective
September 1, 1909. And it was further ordered that, on and after
that date, the exception of churches and dwelling houses should be
eliminated. Complainant notified the superintendent by letter that
it would, under
Page 233 U. S. 398
protest, and reserving the rights which it had under the law,
comply with the provisions of the order.
The risks included in the order, and not excepted therefrom,
comprise all ordinary mercantile risks in the state, and that the
reduction of 12% will result in a rate which is much less than the
cost of carrying the risks.
Respondent is threatening to make further reductions, and it is
proposed to revoke the license of any fire insurance company which
may violate the provisions of the act, even though the rates fixed
by him may be so low as to be confiscatory, and to inflict upon the
officers of the company, including complainant, the penalties
prescribed for such violation, and such companies and complainant,
unless defendant be restrained by injunction, will be obliged to
comply with the requirements of the act to their irreparable damage
and injury.
Complainant finally alleges that it is not its purpose to attack
the orders of respondent on the ground that they were not made in
strict compliance with the provisions of the act, but to have the
act in its entirety declared to be unconstitutional and void for
the reasons alleged, and to have respondent restrained and orders
made by him under the provisions of the act enjoined. And such an
injunction is prayed.
Respondent filed a demurrer stating that he demurred to so much
of the bill as charges the act of the State of Kansas to be
repugnant to the Constitution of Kansas and the Constitution of the
United States. The demurrer was sustained. Subsequently, upon the
bill's being amended, a general demurrer was filed which was also
sustained by the court, and the bill dismissed. Prior, however, to
this action, it having been suggested that the term of office of
Charles W. Barnes as superintendent of insurance had expired, and
that Ike Lewis had succeeded to that office and to all of its
duties and powers, he was made defendant in the place and stead of
Charles W. Barnes.
Page 233 U. S. 404
After stating the case as above, MR. JUSTICE McKENNA delivered
the opinion of the Court.
The specific error complained of is the refusal of the district
court to hold that the act of the State of Kansas is
unconstitutional and void as offending the due process clause of
the Fourteenth Amendment of the Constitution of the United States.
To support this charge of error,
Page 233 U. S. 405
complainant asserts that the business of fire insurance is a
private business, and therefore there is no constitutional power in
a state to fix the rates and charges for services rendered by it.
An exercise of such right, it is contended, is a taking of private
property for a public use. The contention is made in various ways,
and, excluding possible countervailing contentions, it is urged
that the act under review cannot be justified as an exercise of the
police power or of the power of the state to admit foreign
corporations within its borders upon such terms as it may
prescribe, or of any other power possessed by the state; that no
state has the power to impose unconstitutional burdens either upon
private citizens or private corporations engaged in a private
business.
The basic contention is that the business of insurance is a
natural right, receiving no privilege from the state, is
voluntarily entered into, cannot be compelled, nor can any of its
exercises be compelled; that it concerns personal contracts of
indemnity against certain contingencies merely. Whether such
contracts shall be made at all, it is contended, is a matter of
private negotiation and agreement, and necessarily there must be
freedom in fixing their terms. And "where the right to demand and
receive service does not exist in the public, the correlative right
of regulation as to rates and charges does not exist." Many
elements, it is urged, determine the extending or rejection of
insurance; the hazards are relative, and depend upon many
circumstances upon which there may be different judgments, and
there are personal considerations as well -- "moral hazards," as
they are called.
It is not clear to what extent some of these circumstances are
urged as affecting the power of regulation in the state. It would
seem to be urged that each risk is individual, and no rule of rates
can be formed or applied. The bill asserts the contrary. It in
effect admits that there can be standards and classification of
risks, determined by the
Page 233 U. S. 406
law of averages. Indeed, it is a matter of common knowledge that
rates are fixed and accommodated to those standards and
classifications in pre-arranged schedules, and, granted the rates
may be varied in particular instances, they are sufficiently
definite and applicable as a general and practically constant rule.
They are the product, it is true, of skill and experience, but such
skill and experience a regulating body may have as well as the
creating body. Indeed, an allegation in the original bill that the
superintendent of insurance could not have the requisite technical
and mathematical training to determine whether a basic rate or an
actual rate as applied to any particular risk was or was not
reasonable, and that his conclusion therefore "would be a mere
guess or arbitrary determination," was omitted by an amendment. It
would indeed be a strained contention that the government could not
avail itself, in the exercise of power it might deem wise to exert,
of the skill and knowledge possessed by the world. We may put
aside, therefore, all merely adventitious considerations, and come
to the bare and essential one -- whether a contract of fire
insurance is private, and, as such, has constitutional immunity
from regulation. Or, to state it differently and to express an
antithetical proposition, is the business of insurance so far
affected with a public interest as to justify legislative
regulation of its rates? And we mean a broad and definite public
interest. In some degree, the public interest is concerned in every
transaction between men, the sum of the transactions constituting
the activities of life. But there is something more special than
this -- something of more definite consequence -- which makes the
public interest that justifies regulatory legislation. We can best
explain by examples. The transportation of property -- business of
common carriers -- is obviously of public concern, and its
regulation is an accepted governmental power. The transmission of
intelligence is of cognate character. There are other
Page 233 U. S. 407
utilities which are denominated public, such as the furnishing
of water and light, including in the latter gas and electricity. We
do not hesitate at their regulation, nor of the fixing of the
prices which may be charged for their service. The basis of the
ready concession of the power of regulation is the public interest.
This is not denied, but its application to insurance is so far
denied as not to extend to the fixing of rates. It is said the
state has no power to fix the rates charged to the public by either
corporations or individuals engaged in a private business, and
the
"test of whether the use is public or not is whether a public
trust is imposed upon the property, and whether the public has a
legal right to the use which cannot be denied,"
or, as we have said, quoting counsel, "[w]here the right to
demand and receive service does not exist in the public, the
correlative right of regulation as to rates and charges does not
exist." Cases are cited which, it must be admitted, support the
contention. The distinction is artificial. It is, indeed, but the
assertion that the cited examples embrace all cases of public
interest. The complainant explicitly so contends, urging that the
test it applies excludes the idea that there can be a public
interest which gives the power of regulation, as distinct from a
public use, which, necessarily, it is contended, can only apply to
property, not to personal contracts. The distinction, we think, has
no basis in principle (
Noble State Bank v. Haskell,
219 U. S. 104),
nor has the other contention that the service which cannot be
demanded cannot be regulated.
Munn v. Illinois, 94 U. S. 113, is an
instructive example of legislative power exerted in the public
interest. The Constitution of Illinois declared all elevators or
storehouses where grain or other property was stored for a
compensation to be public warehouses, and a law was subsequently
enacted fixing rates of storage. In other words, that which had
been private property had, from its
Page 233 U. S. 408
uses, become, it was declared, of public concern, and the
compensation to be charged for its use prescribed. The law was
sustained against the contention that it deprived the owners of the
warehouses of their property without due process of law. We can
only cite the case and state its principle, not review it at any
length. The principle was expressed to be, quoting Lord Chief
Justice Hale, "that, when private property is
affected with a
public interest, it ceases to be juris privati' only," and
it becomes "clothed with a public interest when used in a manner to
make it of public consequence, and affect the community at large,"
and, so using it, the owner "grants to the public an interest in
that use, and must submit to be controlled by the public for the
common good." And it was said that the application of the principle
could not be denied, because no precedent could be found for a
statute precisely like the one reviewed. It presented a case, the
Court further said,
"for the application of a long known and well established
principle in social science, and this statute simply extends the
law so as to meet this new development of commercial progress."
The principle was expressed as to property, and the instance of
its application was to property, but it is manifestly broader than
that instance. It is the business that is the fundamental thing;
property is but its instrument, the means of rendering the service
which has become of public interest.
That the case had broader application than the use of property
is manifest from the grounds expressed in the dissenting opinion.
The basis of the opinion was that the business regulated was
private, and had "no special privilege connected with it, nor did
the law ever extend to it any greater protection than it extended
to all other private business." The argument encountered opposing
examples, among others, the regulation of the rate of interest on
money. The regulation was accounted for on the ground that the act
of Parliament permitting the charging
Page 233 U. S. 409
of some interest was a relaxation of a prohibition of the common
law against charging any interest; but this explanation overlooked
the fact that both the common law and the act of Parliament were
exercises of government regulation of a strictly private business
in the interest of public policy -- a policy which still endures
and still dictates regulating laws. Against that conservatism of
the mind which puts to question every new act of regulating
legislation, and regards the legislation invalid or dangerous until
it has become familiar, government -- state and national -- has
pressed on in the general welfare, and our reports are full of
cases where, in instance after instance, the exercise of regulation
was resisted and yet sustained against attacks asserted to be
justified by the Constitution of the United States. The dread of
the moment having passed, no one is now heard to say that rights
were restrained or their constitutional guaranties impaired.
Munn v. Illinois was approved in many state decisions,
but it was brought to the review of this Court in
Budd v. New
York, 143 U. S. 517, and
its doctrine, after elaborate consideration, reaffirmed, and
against the same arguments which are now urged against the Kansas
statute. Nowhere have these arguments been, or could be, advanced
with greater strength and felicity of expression than in the
dissenting opinion of Mr. Justice Brewer. Every consideration was
adduced, based on the private character of the business regulated,
and, for that reason, its constitutional immunity from regulation,
with all the power of argument and illustration of which that great
judge was a master. The considerations urged did not prevail.
Against them, the Court opposed the ever-existing police power in
government and its necessary exercise for the public good, and
declared its entire accommodation to the limitations of the
Constitution. The Court was not deterred by the charge (repeated in
the case at bar) that its decision had the sweeping and dangerous
comprehension of subjecting to
Page 233 U. S. 410
legislative regulation all of the businesses and affairs of life
and the prices of all commodities. Whether we may apprehend such
result by extending the principle of the cases to fire insurance we
shall presently consider.
In
Brass v. North Dakota, 153 U.
S. 391,
Munn v. Illinois and
Budd v. New
York were affirmed. A law of the State of North Dakota was
sustained which made all buildings, elevators, and warehouses used
for the handling of grain for a profit public warehouses, and fixed
a storage rate. The case is important. It extended the principle of
the other two cases and denuded it of the limiting element which
was supposed to beset it -- that, to justify regulation of a
business, the business must have a monopolistic character. That
distinction was pressed and answered. It was argued, the Court
said,
"[t]hat the statutes of Illinois and New York [passed on in the
Munn and
Budd cases] are intended to operate in
great trade centers where, on account of the business being
localized in the hands of a few persons in close proximity to each
other, great opportunities for combinations to raise and control
elevating and storage charges are afforded, while the wide extent
of the State of North Dakota and the small population of its
country towns and villages are said to present no such
opportunities."
And it was also urged that the method of carrying on business in
North Dakota and the eastern cities was different, that the
elevators in the latter were essentially means of transporting
grain from the lakes to the railroads, and those who owned them
could, if uncontrolled by law, extort such charges as they pleased,
and stress was laid upon the expression in the other cases which
represented the business as a practical monopoly. A contrast was
made between those conditions and those which existed in an
agricultural state where land was cheap and limitless in quantity.
It was replied that this difference in conditions was "for those
who make, not for those who interpret, the laws." And,
considering
Page 233 U. S. 411
the expressions in the other cases which, it was said, went
rather to the expediency of the laws than to their validity, yet,
it was further said, the expressions had their value, because
the
"obvious aim of the reasoning that prevailed was to show that
the subject matter of these enactments fell within the legitimate
sphere of legislative power, and that, so far as the laws and
Constitution of the United States were concerned, the legislation
in question deprived no person of his property without due process
of law."
The cases need no explanatory or fortifying comment. They
demonstrate that a business, by circumstances and its nature, may
rise from private to be of public concern, and be subject, in
consequence, to governmental regulation. And they demonstrate, to
apply the language of Judge Andrews in the
Budd case (117
N.Y. 27), that the attempts made to place the right of public
regulation in the cases in which it has been exerted, and of which
we have given examples, upon the ground of special privilege
conferred by the public on those affected, cannot be supported.
"The underlying principle is that business of certain kinds hold
such a peculiar relation to the public interest that there is
superinduced upon it the right of public regulation."
Is the business of insurance within the principle? It would be a
bold thing to say that the principle is fixed, inelastic, in the
precedents of the past, and cannot be applied though modern
economic conditions may make necessary or beneficial its
application. In other words, to say that government possessed at
one time a greater power to recognize the public interest in a
business and its regulation to promote the general welfare than
government possesses today. We proceed, then, to consider whether
the business of insurance is within the principle.
A contract for fire insurance is one for indemnity against loss,
and is personal. The admission, however, does not
Page 233 U. S. 412
take us far in the solution of the question presented. Its
personal character certainly does not, of itself, preclude
regulation, for there are many examples of government regulation of
personal contracts, and, in the statutes of every state in the
Union, superintendence and control over the business of insurance
are exercised, varying in details and extent. We need not
particularize in detail. We need only say that there was quite
early (in Massachusetts, 1837, New York, 1853) state provision for
what is known as the unearned premium fund or reserve; then came
the limitation of dividends, the publishing of accounts, valued
policies, standards of policies, prescribing investment, requiring
deposits in money or bonds, confining the business to corporations,
preventing discrimination in rates, limitation of risks, and other
regulations equally restrictive. In other words, the state has
stepped in and imposed conditions upon the companies, restraining
the absolute liberty which businesses strictly private are
permitted to exercise.
Those regulations exhibit it to be the conception of the
lawmaking bodies of the country, without exception, that the
business of insurance so far affects the public welfare as to
invoke and require governmental regulation. A conception so general
cannot be without cause. The universal sense of a people cannot be
accidental; its persistence saves it from the charge of
unconsidered impulse, and its estimate of insurance certainly has
substantial basis. Accidental fires are inevitable, and the extent
of loss very great. The effect of insurance -- indeed, it has been
said to be its fundamental object -- is to distribute the loss over
as wide an area as possible. In other words, the loss is spread
over the country, the disaster to an individual is shared by many,
the disaster to a community shared by other communities; great
catastrophes are thereby lessened, and, it may be, repaired. In
assimilation of insurance to a tax, the companies have been said to
be
Page 233 U. S. 413
the mere machinery by which the inevitable losses by fire are
distributed so as to fall as lightly as possible on the public at
large, the body of the insured, not the companies, paying the tax.
Their efficiency, therefore, and solvency, are of great concern.
The other objects, direct and indirect, of insurance we need not
mention. Indeed, it may be enough to say, without stating other
effects of insurance, that a large part of the country's wealth,
subject to uncertainty of loss through fire, is protected by
insurance. This demonstrates the interest of the public in it, and
we need not dispute with the economists that this is the result of
the "substitution of certain for uncertain loss," or the diffusion
of positive loss over a large group of persons, as we have already
said to be certainly one of its effects. We can see, therefore, how
it has come to be considered a matter of public concern to regulate
it, and governmental insurance has its advocates and even examples.
Contracts of insurance therefore have greater public consequence
than contracts between individuals to do or not to do a particular
thing whose effect stops with the individuals. We may say in
passing that, when the effect goes beyond that, there are many
examples of regulation.
Holden v. Hardy, 169 U.
S. 366;
Griffith v. Connecticut, 218 U.
S. 563;
Muller v. Oregon, 208 U.
S. 412;
Mutual Loan Co. v. Martell,
222 U. S. 225;
Schmidinger v. Chicago, 226 U. S. 578;
Chicago, Burlington & Quincy R. Co. v. McGuire,
219 U. S. 549;
Noble State Bank v. Haskell, 219 U.
S. 104.
Complainant feels the necessity of accounting for the regulatory
state legislation, and refers it to the exertion of the police
power, but, while expressing the power in the broad language of the
cases, seeks to restrict its application. Counsel states that this
power may be exerted to "pass laws whose purpose is the health,
safety, morals, and the general welfare of the people." The
admission is very comprehensive. What makes for the general welfare
is
Page 233 U. S. 414
necessarily, in the first instance, a matter of legislative
judgment, and a judicial review of such judgment is limited.
"The scope of judicial inquiry in deciding the question of power
is not to be confused with the scope of legislative considerations
in dealing with the matter of policy. Whether the enactment is wise
or unwise, whether it is based on sound economic theory, whether it
is the best means to achieve the desired result, whether, in short,
the legislative discretion within its prescribed limits should be
exercised in a particular manner, are matters for the judgment of
the legislature, and the earnest conflict of serious opinion does
not suffice to bring them within the range of judicial
cognizance."
Chicago, Burlington & Quincy Railroad Co. v.
McGuire, 219 U. S. 549,
219 U. S.
569.
The restrictions upon the legislative power which complainant
urges we have discussed, or rather, the considerations which take,
it is contended, the business of insurance outside of the sphere of
the power. To the contention that the business is private we have
opposed the conception of the public interest. We have shown that
the business of insurance has very definite characteristics, with a
reach of influence and consequence beyond and different from that
of the ordinary businesses of the commercial world, to pursue which
a greater liberty may be asserted. The transactions of the latter
are independent and individual, terminating in their effect with
the instances. The contracts of insurance may be said to be
interdependent. They cannot be regarded singly, or isolatedly, and
the effect of their relation is to create a fund of assurance and
credit, the companies becoming the depositories of the money of the
insured, possessing great power thereby, and charged with great
responsibility. How necessary their solvency is is manifest. On the
other hand, to the insured, insurance is an asset, a basis of
credit. It is practically a necessity to business activity and
enterprise. It is therefore essentially different from ordinary
commercial
Page 233 U. S. 415
transactions, and, as we have seen, according to the sense of
the world from the earliest times -- certainly the sense of the
modern world -- is of the greatest public concern. It is therefore
within the principle we have announced.
But it is said that the reasoning of the opinion has the broad
reach of subjecting to regulation every act of human endeavor, and
the price of every article of human use. We might, without much
concern, leave our discussion to take care of itself against such
misunderstanding or deductions. The principle we apply is definite
and old, and has, as we have pointed out, illustrating examples.
And, both by the expression of the principle and the citation of
the examples, we have tried to confine our decision to the
regulation of the business of insurance, it having, become "clothed
with a public interest," and therefore subject "to be controlled by
the public for the common good."
If there may be controversy as to the business having such
character, there can be no controversy as to what follows from such
character if it be established. It is idle, therefore, to debate
whether the liberty of contract guaranteed by the Constitution of
the United States is more intimately involved in price regulation
than in the other forms of regulation as to the validity of which
there is no dispute. The order of their enactment certainly cannot
be considered an element in their legality. It would be very
rudimentary to say that measures of government are determined by
circumstances, by the presence or imminence of conditions, and of
the legislative judgment of the means or the policy of removing or
preventing them. The power to regulate interstate commerce existed
for a century before the Interstate Commerce Act was passed, and
the Commission constituted by it was not given authority to fix
rates until some years afterwards. Of the agencies which those
measures were enacted to
Page 233 U. S. 416
regulate at the time of the creation of the power, there was no
prophecy or conception. Nor was regulation immediate upon their
existence. It was exerted only when the size, number, and influence
of those agencies had so increased and developed as to seem to make
it imperative. Other illustrations readily occur which repel the
intimation that the inactivity of a power, however prolonged,
militates against its legality when it is exercised.
United
States v. Delaware & Hudson Co., 213 U.
S. 366. It is oftener the existence of necessity, rather
than the prescience of it, which dictates legislation. And so with
the regulations of the business of insurance. They have proceeded
step by step, differing in different jurisdictions. If we are
brought to a comparison of them in relation to the power of
government, how can it be said that fixing the price of insurance
is beyond that power and the other instances of regulation are not?
How can it be said that the right to engage in the business is a
natural one when it can be denied to individuals and permitted to
corporations? How can it be said to have privilege of a private
business when its dividends are restricted, its investments
controlled, the form and extent of its contracts prescribed,
discriminations in its rates denied, and a limitation on its risks
imposed? Are not such regulations restraints upon the exercise of
the personal right -- asserted to be fundamental -- of dealing with
property freely, or engaging in what contracts one may choose, and
with whom and upon what terms one may choose?
We may venture to observe that the price of insurance is not
fixed over the counters of the companies by what Adam Smith calls
the higgling of the market, but formed in the councils of the
underwriters, promulgated in schedules of practically controlling
constancy which the applicant for insurance is powerless to oppose,
and which therefore has led to the assertion that the business of
insurance is of monopolistic character, and that "it is
illusory
Page 233 U. S. 417
to speak of a liberty of contract." It is in the alternative
presented of accepting the rates of the companies or refraining
from insurance, business necessity impelling if not compelling it,
that we may discover the inducement of the Kansas statute, and the
problem presented is whether the legislature could regard it of as
much moment to the public that they who seek insurance should no
more be constrained by arbitrary terms than they who seek
transportation by railroads, steam, or street, or by coaches whose
itinerary may be only a few city blocks, or who seek the use of
grain elevators, or to be secured in a night's accommodation at a
wayside inn, or in the weight of a five-cent loaf of bread. We do
not say this to belittle such rights or to exaggerate the effect of
insurance, but to exhibit the principle which exists in all and
brings all under the same governmental power.
We have summarized the provisions of the Kansas statute, and it
will be observed from them that they attempt to systematize the
control of insurance. The statute seeks to secure rates which shall
be reasonable both to the insurer and the insured, and, as a means
to this end, it prescribes equality of charges, forbids initial
discrimination or subsequently by the refund of a portion of the
rates, or the extension to the insured of any privilege; to this
end, it requires publicity in the basic schedules and of all of the
conditions which affect the rates or the value of the insurance to
the insured, and also adherence to the rates as published. Whether
the requirements are necessary to the purpose, or -- to confine
ourselves to that which in under review -- whether rate regulation
is necessary to the purpose, is a matter for legislative judgment,
not judicial. Our function is only to determine the existence of
power.
The bill attacks the statute of Kansas as discriminating against
complainant because the statute excludes from its provisions
farmers' mutual insurance companies, organized
Page 233 U. S. 418
and doing business under the laws of the state and insuring only
farm property. The charge is not discussed in the elaborate brief
of counsel, nor does it seem to have been pressed in the lower
court; it is, however, covered by the assignments of error.
The provision of the statute is,
"That nothing in this act shall affect farmers' mutual insurance
companies, organized and doing business under the laws of this
state, and insuring only farm property."
The distinction is therefore between cooperative insurance
companies insuring a special kind of property and all other
insurance companies. It is only with that distinction that we are
now concerned. There are special provisions in the statutes of
Kansas for the organization of cooperative companies, and if the
statute under review discriminates between them, the German
Alliance Company cannot avail itself of the discrimination. A
citation of cases is not necessary, nor for the general principle
that a discrimination is valid if not arbitrary, and arbitrary in
the legislative sense -- that is, outside of that wide discretion
which a legislature may exercise. A legislative classification may
rest on narrow distinctions. Legislation is addressed to evils as
they may appear, and even degrees of evil may determine its
exercise.
Ozan Lumber Co. v. Union County Bank, 202 U.S.
623. There are certainly differences between stock companies, such
as complainant is, and the mutual companies described in the bill,
and a recognition of the differences we cannot say is outside of
the constitutional power of the legislature.
Orient Ins. Co. v.
Daggs, 172 U. S. 557.
Decree affirmed.
MR. JUSTICE LAMAR, dissenting:
I dissent from the decision and the reasoning upon which it is
based. The case does not deal with a statute affecting
Page 233 U. S. 419
the safety or morals of the public. It presents no question of
monopoly in a prime necessity of life, but relates solely to the
power of the state to fix the price of a strictly personal
contract. The court holds that fire insurance, though personal, is
affected with a public interest, and therefore that the business
may not only be regulated, but that the premium or price to be paid
to the insurer for entering into that personal contract can be
fixed by law.
The fixing of the price for the use of private property is as
much a taking as though the fee itself had been condemned for a
lump sum; that taking, whether by fixing rates for the use or by
paying a lump sum for the fee, has always heretofore been thought
to be permissible only when it was for a public use. But the Court
in this case holds that there is no distinction between the power
to take for public use and the power to regulate the exercise of
private rights for the public good. That is the fundamental
proposition on which the case must stand, and the decision must
therefore be considered in the light of that ruling and of the
results which must necessarily flow from the future application of
that principle. For if the power to regulate, in the interest of
the public, comprehends what is intended in the power to take
property for public use, it must inevitably follow that the price
to be paid for any service or the use of any property can be
regulated by the general assembly. This is so because the power of
regulation is all-pervading, as witness the statute of frauds, the
recording acts, weight and measure laws, pure food laws, hours of
service laws, and innumerable other enactments of that class. And
if this power be as extensive as is now, for the first time,
decided, then the citizen holds his property and his individual
right of contract and of labor under legislative favor, rather than
under constitutional guaranty. The principle is applied here to the
case of insurance; but the nature of that business
Page 233 U. S. 420
and the intangible character of its contracts are such as to
indicate the far-reaching effect of the principle announced, and
warrants a statement of some of the grounds of dissent.
Insurance is not production; nor manufacture; nor
transportation; nor merchandise. And this Court, in
N.Y. Life
Co. v. Deer Lodge Co., 231 U. S. 495, at
the present term, reaffirmed its previous rulings that "insurance
is not commerce," "not an instrumentality of commerce," "not a
transaction of commerce," "but simply contracts of indemnity
against loss by fire." Such a contract is personal, and in the
state whose statute is under consideration, insurance companies are
classed among those "strictly private."
Leavenworth County v.
Miller, 7 Kan. 520. The fact that insurance is a strictly
private and a personal contract of indemnity puts it on the extreme
outside limit, and removes it as far as any business can be from
those that are in their nature public. So that, if the price of a
private and personal contract of indemnity can be regulated -- if
the price of a chose in action can be fixed -- then the price of
everything within the circle of business transactions can be
regulated. Considering, therefore, the nature of the subject
treated and the reasoning on which the court's opinion is based, it
is evident that the decision is not a mere entering wedge, but
reaches the end from the beginning, and announces a principle which
points inevitably to the conclusion that the price of every article
sold and the price of every service offered can be regulated by
statute.
And such laws are not without English precedent. For while no
statute ever before attempted to fix the price of a contract of
indemnity,
* yet under a
Parliament that sat as a perpetual constitutional convention, with
power
Page 233 U. S. 421
to pass bills of attainder to take property for private
purposes, and to take it without due process of law, many statutes
approaching that now under review were adopted and enforced. Acts
were passed by Parliament fixing the price of many commodities that
were convenient or useful. These laws did not stop at fixing the
price of property, but, like the present act, they fixed the price
of private contracts, and by statute prescribed the rate of wages,
and made it unlawful for the employee to receive or for the
employer to give more than the wage fixed by law. It is needless to
say that these laws were felt to be an infringement upon the rights
of men; that they were bitterly resisted by buyer and seller, by
employer and employee, and were a source of perpetual irritation
often leading to violence. But the fact that the English Parliament
had the arbitrary power to pass such statutes made them valid in
law, though they were in violation of the inherent rights of
individual. In time, the great injustice in this was so far
recognized that these laws, fixing the price of strictly private
contracts, seem to have been repealed, and Lord Ellenborough, while
enforcing, as proper, a rate for public wharves, was able to say,
in
Allnutt v. Inglis, 12 East, 535, "that the general
principle is favored that every man may fix whatever price he
pleases for his own property or for the use of it." But what was a
favor in England, that might at any time be withdrawn, was in this
country made a constitutional right that could not be withdrawn.
For although the practice of fixing prices may have prevailed in
some of the colonies "up to the time of independence," yet, as
Judge Cooley says, since independence, "it has been commonly
supposed that a general power in the state to regulate prices was
inconsistent with constitutional liberty." Cooley's Const. Law (7th
ed.) 807; Stickney's State Control of Trade, p. 3, and the abstract
of English price-fixing statutes, pp. 9
et seq. That
common supposition is rightly founded on the fact
Page 233 U. S. 422
that the Constitution recognizes the liberty to contract and
right of private property. They include not only the right to make
contracts with which to acquire property, but the right to fix the
price of its use while it is held, and the further right to fix the
price if it is to be sold. To deprive any person of either is to
take property, since there can be no liberty of contract and true
private ownership if the price of its use or its sale is fixed by
law. That right is an attribute of ownership.
State
Freight Tax Case, 15 Wall. 278, top.
But it may be said that, though insurance is a contract of
indemnity, and personal, its personal character has not been
thought to preclude the many regulatory measures adopted and
sustained during the past hundred years.
This is most freely conceded. But it is equally true that the
failure for more than one hundred years to attempt to fix the rates
of insurance is indubitable evidence of the general public and
legislative conception that the business of insurance did not
belong to the class whose rates could be fixed. That settled usage
is not an accident. For ratemaking is no new thing, and neither is
insurance. Its use in protecting the owner of property against
loss, its value as collateral in securing loans, its method of
averages and distributing the risk between many persons widely
separated, and all contributing small premiums in return for the
promise of a large indemnity, has been known for centuries. All
these considerations were recently pressed upon the Court in an
effort to secure a ruling that insurance was commerce. In refusing
to accede to the sufficiency of the argument, the court, in the
Deer Lodge case, pointed out that the size of the business
of insurance did not change the inherent nature of the business
itself, saying that "the number of transactions do not give the
business any other character than magnitude."
The character of insurance, therefore, as a private and personal
contract of indemnity has not been changed by
Page 233 U. S. 423
its magnitude or by the fact that more policies and for greater
amounts are now written than in the centuries during which no
effort has ever before been made to fix their rates. It is,
however, undoubtedly true that, during all of that period,
regulatory statutes were, from time to time, adopted to protect the
public against conditions and practices which were subject to
regulation. The public had no means of knowing whether these
corporations were solvent or not, and statutes were passed to
require a publication of the financial condition. The policies were
long and complicated, with exceptions and qualifications and
provisos. They were often unread by the policyholder, and sometimes
not understood when read. Statutes were accordingly passed
providing for a standard form of policy in order to protect the
assured against his inexperience, to prevent hard bargains, and to
avoid vexatious litigation, and as similar evils appear they may be
dealt with by regulatory or prohibitory legislation just as
statutes were passed, and can still be passed to punish
combinations, pooling arrangements, and all those practices which
amount to unfair competition.
But these and those referred to in
Attorney General v.
Firemen's Insurance Co., 74 N.J.Eq. 372, furnish instances of
the exercise of this power to regulate which can be exerted against
any person, trade, or business, no matter great or small. This
power to regulate is so much oftener exerted against the large
business, because the evils are then more apparent, that the size
of the business and the number of persons interested is sometimes
referred to as indicating that the business is affected with a
public interest. But there is no such limitation. For the power to
regulate is the essential power of government which can be exerted
against the whole body of the public or the smallest business. And
if, as seems to be implied, the fact that a business may be
regulated is to be the test of the power to fix rates, it would
follow, since all can be
Page 233 U. S. 424
regulated, the price charged by all can be regulated. Or if
great size is the test, if the number of customers is the test, if
the scope of the business throughout the nation is the test, if the
contributions of the many to the value of the business is the test
-- or if it takes a combination of all to meet the condition --
then every business with great capital and many customers
distributed throughout the country, and making a large business
possible, must be treated as affected with a public interest, and
the price of the goods on its shelves can be fixed by law. Then
could the price of newspapers, magazines, and the like be fixed,
because certainly nothing is more affected with a public interest,
nothing is so dependent on the public, nothing reaches so many
persons, and so profoundly affects public thought and public
business. Such a business is, indeed, affected with a public
interest, justifying regulation (
Lewis Pub. Co. v. Morgan,
229 U. S. 288),
but not the fixing of the price of the paper or periodical or the
rates of advertising. For great and pervasive as is the power to
regulate, it cannot override the constitutional principle that
private property cannot be taken for private purposes.
Missouri
Pacific v. Nebraska, 164 U. S. 403.
That limitation on the power of government over the individual and
his property cannot be avoided by calling an unlawful taking a
reasonable regulation. Indeed, the protection of property is an
incident of the more fundamental and important right of liberty
guaranteed by the Constitution, and which entitled the citizen
freely to engage in any honest calling, and to make contracts as
buyer or seller, as employer or employee, in order to support
himself and family.
It said, however, that the validity of rates statutes has often
been recognized, notably in the
Munn
case (94 U.S. 126), where a statute was sustained which regulated
the price to be charged for storing grain in elevators.
The
Munn case is a landmark in the law. It is
accepted
Page 233 U. S. 425
as an authoritative and accurate statement of the principle on
which the right to fix rates is based. But the statute there under
review did not undertake to fix the price of a personal contract,
but to fix the price for the use of property, once private, but
then public. The reasoning of the Court clearly shows that, in
order to regulate rates, two things must concur -- (1) the business
must be affected with a public interest, and (2) the property
employed in such business must be devoted to a public use. The
basic principle of the decision was the oft-quoted saying of Lord
Hale that "when private property is affected with a public
interest, it ceases to be
juris privati only." The
decision in the
Munn case was but an application of that
terse statement, and was applied in a case where the elevators had
been devoted to a public use. This will distinctly appear from the
statement by the Court of the question involved and decided. For,
after reviewing and applying Lord Hale's pithy saying, and
reviewing the other authorities, the court said (italics ours):
"Enough has already been said to show that, when
private
property is devoted to a public use, it is subject to public
regulation. It remains only to ascertain whether the warehouses of
these plaintiffs in error and the business which is carried on
there come within the operation of this principle."
Not only does the
Munn case show that the right to fix
prices depends on the concurrence of public interest and the
employment of property devoted to a public use, but, with the
exception of the
Louisiana Bread case, 12 La.Ann. 432, it
is believed that every American rate statute since the requirement
that property should not be taken without due process of law
related to a business which was public in its character and
employed visible and tangible property which had been devoted to a
public use.
The list of rate-regulated occupations is not too long to be
here given. It includes canals, waterways, and
Page 233 U. S. 426
booms; bridges and ferries; wharves, docks, elevators, and
stockyards; telegraph, telephone, electric, gas, and oil lines;
turnpikes, railroads, and the various forms of common carriers,
including express and cabs. To this should be added the case of the
innkeeper (as to which no American case has been found where the
constitutional question as to the right to fix his rates has been
considered), the confessedly close case of the irrigation ditches
for distributing water (
189 U. S. 189 U.S.
439), and the toll mill acts. This, of course, does not include the
case of condemnation for governmental purposes or for roads and
ways where no question of rates is involved. There may be other
instances not found, but it is believed that the foregoing
numeration exhausts the list of what has heretofore been treated as
a public business justifying the exercise of the price-fixing power
against persons or corporations.
It is to be noted that, in each instance, the power to regulate
rates is exercised against a business which in every case used
tangible property devoted to a public use. Some of them had a
monopoly (
Spring Valley Water Co. v. Schottler,
110 U. S. 347,
110 U. S.
354). Some of them had franchises. Most of them used
public ways or employed property which they had acquired by virtue
of the power of eminent domain. They were therefore subject to the
correlative obligation to have the use of what had been thus taken
by law fixed by law. And as further pointing out the
characteristics of the public use justifying the fixing of prices,
it will be noted that, with the exception of toll mills (which,
however, to employ property devoted to a public use), they all have
direct relation to the business or facilities of transportation or
distribution -- to transportation by carriers of passengers, goods,
or intelligence by vehicle or wire; to distribution of water, gas,
or electricity through ditch, pipe, or wire; to wharfage, storage,
or accommodation of property before the journey begins, when it
ends, or along the way.
Page 233 U. S. 427
When thus enumerated, they appear to be grouped around the
common carrier as the typical public business, and all employing in
some way property devoted to a public use.
It will be seen, too, that the size of the business is
unimportant, for the fares of a cabman, employing a broken-down
horse and a dilapidated vehicle, can be fixed by law as well as the
rates of a railroad with millions of capital and thousands of cars
transporting persons and property across the continent.
The fact that rate statutes, enacted and sustained since the
adoption of constitutional government in this country, all had some
reference to transportation or distribution is a practical
illustration of the accepted meaning of "public use" when that
phrase was first employed in American Constitutions, and when
turnpikes and carriers, wharfingers and ferrymen, had rates, tolls,
and fares fixed by law. No change was made in the meaning of the
words or in the principle involved when it opened to take in new
forms and facilities of transportation, whether by vehicle, pipe,
or wire, and new forms of storage, whether on the wharf or in the
grain elevator.
But it is said that business is the fundamental thing, with the
property but an instrument, and that there is no basis for the
distinction between a public interest and a public use. But there
is a distinction between a public interest -- justifying regulation
-- and a public use justifying price-fixing. "Public interest and
public use are not synonymous."
In re Niagara Falls Ry.
Co., 108 N.Y. 385. And since the case here involves the
validity of a Kansas statute, it is well to note that the supreme
court of that state, in
Howard v. Schwartz, 77 Kan. 599,
recognizes that there is a difference, and adjudges accordingly. It
there cited numerous decisions from other states, and in defining a
public use made the following quotation from the opinion of the
Supreme Court of Maine:
Page 233 U. S. 428
"
Property is devoted to a public use when, and only when, .
. . all the public has a right to demand and share in [it].' . . .
In a broad sense, it is the right in the public to an actual use,
and not to an incidental benefit."
The effect of the difference between public use and public
interest appears from the application; for the Supreme Court of
Kansas, on the authority of this and numerous other cases, held
that a steam flour mill was not such a public use as would
authorize its owners to exercise the power of eminent domain,
though it was a useful and important business instrumentality which
contributed to the growth and development of the locality where the
[mills] are situated. This may also be said, however, of every
legitimate business. To a limited extent, every honest industry
adds to the general sum of prosperity and promotes the public
welfare.
Nothing more can be said of insurance, nor can the power to take
the private property of insurers by fixing rates be enlarged by a
legislative declaration that the business is affected with a broad
and definite public interest. For, since the contract of insurance
is private and personal, it is almost a contradiction in terms to
say that the private contract is public, or that a business which
consists in making such private contracts is public in the
constitutional sense. The fundamental idea of a public business, as
well declared by the Supreme Court of Kansas, 77 Kan. 608, is that
"all of the public have a right to demand and share in it." That
means that each member of the public, on demand and upon equal
terms, without written contract, without haggling as to terms, may
demand the public service, and secure the use of the facility
devoted to public use. If the company can make distinctions and
serve one and refuse to serve another, the business
ex vi
termini is not public. The common carrier has no right to
refuse to haul a passenger even if he has been
Page 233 U. S. 429
convicted of arson. But if an insurance company is indeed
public, it is bound to insure the property of the man who is
suspected of having set fire to his own house, or whose statements
of value it is unwilling to take. This is manifestly inconsistent
with the contract of insurance, which requires the utmost good
faith not only in making truthful answers to questions asked, but
in not concealing anything material to the risk. If the company has
the discretion to insure or the right to refuse to insure, then, by
the very definition of the terms, it is not a public business. If,
on the other hand, the company is obliged to insure bad risks or
the property of men of bad character, of doubtful veracity, or
known to be careless in their handling of property, the law would
be an arbitrary exertion of power in compelling men to enter into
contract with persons with whom they did not choose to deal where
confidence is the very foundation of a contract of indemnity.
Indeed, it seems to be conceded that a person owning property is
not entitled to demand insurance as a matter of right. If not, the
business is not public, and not within the provision of the
Constitution which only authorizes the taking of property for
public purposes -- whether the taking be of the fee, for a lump sum
assessed in condemnation proceedings, or whether the use be taken
by rate regulation, which is but another method of exercising the
same power.
The suggestion that the public interest is found in the
characteristics of the business of insurance justifies a brief
examination of those characteristics and a statement of the results
that logically must follow from such a test. For if the power is to
develop out of the characteristics, it must necessarily follow that
other occupations, having similar characteristics, must be subject
to the same rate regulating power.
The elements which are said to show that insurance is affected
with a public interest do not arise out of the size of any one
company, but out of the volume of the aggregate
Page 233 U. S. 430
business of all the companies doing business within the state
and beyond its borders. If that test be applied, and if the sum of
the units is to determine whether or not a business is affected
with a public interest (which is said to be the equivalent of a
public use), then if the principle of the decision be applied to
the business of farming, all can see to what end it leads. In view
of the amount of property employed and the aggregate number of
persons engaged in agriculture, and the public's absolute
dependence upon that pursuit, it would follow that, farming being
affected with a broad and definite public interest, the price of
wheat and corn; cotton and wools; beef, pork, mutton, and poultry;
fruit and vegetables, could be fixed. Or if we take the aggregate
of those who labor, and consider the public's absolute dependence
upon labor, it would inevitably follow that it, too, was affected
with a broad and definite public interest, and that wages in the
United States of America in this 20th century could be fixed by
law, just as in England between the 14th and 18th centuries. And
inasmuch as the prices of agricultural products are dependent on
the price of land and labor, and as the price of labor is closely
related to the cost of rent and food and clothes and the comforts
of life, there would be the power to take the further step and
regulate the cost of everything which enters into the cost of
living. Of course, it goes without saying that, if the rates for
fire insurance can be fixed, then the rates for life and marine
insurance can be fixed. By a parity of reasoning, the rates of
accident, guaranty, and fidelity insurance could also be regulated.
There seems no escape from the conclusion that the asserted power
to fix the price to be paid by one private person to another
private person or private corporation for a private contract of
indemnity, or for his product, or his labor, or for his private
contracts of any sort, will become the center of a circle of
price-making legislation that, in its application, will destroy the
right of
Page 233 U. S. 431
private property, and break down the barriers which the
Constitution has thrown around the citizen to protect him in his
right of property -- which includes his right of contract to make
property -- his right to fix the price at which his property shall
be used by another. By virtue of the liberty which is guaranteed by
the Constitution, he also has the right to name the wage for his
labor and to fix the terms of contracts of indemnity, whether they
be contracts of indorsement or suretyship or contracts of indemnity
against loss by fire, flood, or accident.
In view of what Judge Cooley calls the general supposition that
"the right to fix prices was inconsistent with constitutional
liberty," it is not surprising that little is to be found in the
books relating to a statute like this. It is, however, somewhat
curious that among the few expressions to be found on the subject
is the intimation by Lord Ellenborough in
Allnutt v.
Inglis, 12 East 535, that insurance rates were not on the same
basis as a public business using property devoted to a public use.
For, in answering the argument that, if the rates of a public wharf
could be fixed, insurance rates could also be fixed, he clearly
intimates that this could not be done, since the wharf was a
monopoly, and "the business of insurance and of counting-houses may
be carried on elsewhere."
In the following cases, the statutes fixing prices have been
held to be void:
Ex Parte Dickey, 144 Cal. 234, fixing the
price to be charged by an employment bureau;
Ex Parte
Quarg, 149 Cal. 79;
People v. Steele, 231 Ill. 340,
prohibiting the sale of theater tickets at a price higher than that
charged by the theater;
State v. Fire Creek Coal & Coke
Co., 33 W.Va. 188, limiting the profits on sales to employees.
See also State v. McCool, 83 Kan. 430, bot., where, in
sustaining a statute regulating the weight of bread, the court
called attention to the fact that the statute did not attempt to
fix the price. To these could be added a multitude of decisions
showing that the power
Page 233 U. S. 432
to regulate is limited by the constitutional prohibition against
the taking of private property.
Guillotte v. New Orleans,
12 La.Ann. 432, is the only American case found which sustains the
right to fix prices for other than a commodity or service furnished
by a public utility company of the kind already pointed out. In
that case, the court said that the city could fix the price of
bread, and that, if the baker did not desire to do business within
the limits of such city, he could go elsewhere. That reasoning
would support any statute, for every citizen at least has the right
to go out of business. But it has been repeatedly held by this
Court that such an answer cannot sustain an invalid statute, the
Constitution being intended to secure the citizen against being
driven out of business by an unconstitutional statute or
regulation.
There is, in the opinion, an allusion to usury laws as instances
of fixing rates for other than public service corporations. We do
not understand that the opinion is founded on that proposition, for
even the usury laws do not fix a flat rate, but only a maximum
rate, and do not require lenders to make loans to all borrowers,
similarly situated at the same rate of interest. Moreover, interest
laws were in their inception not a restriction upon the right of
contract, but an enlargement, permitting what theretofore had been
regarded both as an ecclesiastical and civil offense. This fact may
have been coupled with the idea that, as the sovereign had the
prerogative to coin money and make legal tender for all claims, he
could fix the price that should be charged for the use of that
money.
At any rate, interest laws had been long recognized before the
Constitution, and have been prevalent ever since. They therefore
fall within the rule that contemporary practice, if subsequently
continued and universally acquiesced in, amounts to an
interpretation of the Constitution. But the same character of long
continued acquiescence
Page 233 U. S. 433
and settled usage that sustains a usury law also sustains the
right of the contracting parties to agree upon the charge for
insurance. For centuries before the Constitution, and continuously
ever since, they have themselves fixed this charge, and this makes
most strongly in favor of their right to continue to agree upon the
price of a private contract of indemnity against loss by fire.
The act now under review not only takes property without due
process of law, but it unequally and arbitrarily selects those from
which such property shall be taken by price-fixing. Although
including all other fire insurance companies, it excepts certain
mutual insurance companies. Persons engaged in doing an insurance
business are not within its terms. In Kansas, the right to do a
fire insurance business is not limited to corporations, but may be
conducted by persons, individuals, partners, companies, and
associations, whether incorporated or not. General Statutes of
Kansas (1909), §§ 4086, 4091, 4122. And if it could be
true that the legislature could fix the price of insurance, it
would seem to be doubly necessary that all doing an insurance
business should be treated alike. There is no difference in
principle and none by statute in the character of the contract,
whether it is made by one man, or the Lloyds, or a corporation.
There is no difference in the character of the contract made by a
stock company and a mutual company. In each instance, the contract
is one of indemnity against loss for a fixed premium. If the
policyholder is a stockholder in an ordinary corporation, he may
get back some of his premium by way of dividends; if he is a member
of a mutual company, he pays his premium and gets back his share of
the earnings. But to say that the state may fix the price to be
charged for insurance by a stock company, and that it will not fix
the price to be charged by mutual companies or by the Lloyds, who
do an enormous business of exactly the same nature, on exactly
Page 233 U. S. 434
the same sort of property, and on exactly the same terms, is to
make a discrimination which amounts to a denial of the equal
protection of the law.
THE CHIEF JUSTICE and MR. JUSTICE VAN DEVANTER concur in this
dissent.
* The statute fixing the premium rates on surety bonds was held
to be void in
American Surety Co. v. Shallenberger, 183 F.
636.