The dissolution of the freight association does not prevent this
Court from taking cognizance of the appeal and deciding the case on
its merits, as, where parties have entered into an illegal
agreement and are acting under it, and there is no adequate remedy
at law, and the jurisdiction of the court has attached by the
filing of a bill to restrain such or like action under a similar
agreement, and a trial has been had and judgment entered, the
appellate jurisdiction of this Court is not ousted by a simple
dissolution of the association, effected subsequently to the entry
of judgment in the suit.
While the statutory amount must, as a matter of fact, be in
controversy, yet the fact that it is so need not appear in the
bill, but may be shown to the satisfaction of the court.
The provisions respecting contracts, combinations, and
conspiracies in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
States or with foreign countries, contained in the Act of July 2,
1890, c. 647, "to protect trade and commerce against unlawful
restraints and monopolies," apply to and cover common carriers by
railroad, and a contract between them in restraint of such trade or
commerce is prohibited even though the contract is entered into
between competing railroads only for the purpose of thereby
affecting traffic rates for the transportation of persons and
property.
The Act of February 4, 1887, "to regulate commerce," is not
inconsistent
Page 166 U. S. 291
with the Act of July 2, 1890, as it does not confer upon
competing railroad companies power to enter into a contract in
restraint of trade and commerce like the one which forms the
subject of this suit.
Debates in Congress are not appropriate sources of information
from which to discover the meaning of the language of a statute
passed by that body.
The prohibitory provisions of the said Act of July 2, 1890,
apply to all contracts in restraint of interstate or foreign trade
or commerce without exception or limitation, and are not confined
to those in which the restraint is unreasonable.
In order to maintain this suit, the Government is not obliged to
show that the agreement in question was entered into for the
purpose of restraining trade or commerce if such restraint is its
necessary effect.
This agreement, though legal when made, became illegal on the
passage of the Act of July 2, 1890, and acts done under it after
that statute became operative were done in violation of it.
The fourth section of the act invests the Government with full
power and authority to bring such a suit as this, and, if the facts
alleged are proved, an injunction should issue.
On the 2d of July, 1890, an act was passed by the Congress of
the United States, entitled "An act to protect trade and commerce
against unlawful restraints and monopolies." 26 Stat. 209, c. 647;
Supp. Rev. St. p. 726. The act is given in full in the margin.
*
Page 166 U. S. 292
On the 15th day of March, 1889, all but three of the defendants,
the railway companies named in the bill, made and entered into an
agreement by which they formed themselves into an association to be
known at the "Trans-Missouri Freight Association," and they agreed
to be governed by the provisions contained in the articles of
agreement.
The memorandum of agreement entered into between the railway
companies named therein stated, among other things, as follows:
"For the purpose of mutual protection by establishing and
maintaining reasonable rates, rules, and regulations on all freight
traffic, both through and local, the subscribers do hereby form an
association to be known as the 'Trans-Missouri Freight
Association,' and agree to be governed by the following
provisions:"
"
Article I"
"The traffic to be included in the Trans-Missouri Freight
Association shall be as follows: "
Page 166 U. S. 293
"1. All traffic competitive between any two or more members
hereof, passing between points in the following described
territory: Commencing at the Gulf of Mexico, on the 95th meridian;
thence north, to the Red river; thence, via that river, to the
eastern boundary line of the Indian Territory; thence north, by
said boundary line and the eastern line of the state of Kansas, to
the Missouri river at Kansas City; thence, via the said Missouri
river, to the point of intersection of that river with the eastern
boundary of Montana; thence, via the said eastern boundary line, to
the international line -- the foregoing to be known as the
'Missouri River Line'; thence, via said international line, to the
Pacific coast; thence, via the Pacific coast, to the international
line between the United States and Mexico; thence, via said
international line, to the Gulf of Mexico; and thence, via said
gulf, to the point of beginning -- including business between
points on the boundary line as described. "
Page 166 U. S. 294
"2. All freight traffic originating within the territory as
defined in the first section when destined to points east of the
aforesaid Missouri River Line."
Certain exceptions to the above article are then stated as to
the particular business of several railway companies, which was to
be regarded as outside and beyond the provisions of the
agreement.
Article II provided for the election of a chairman of the
organization, and for meetings at Kansas City, or otherwise, as
might be provided for. By section 2 of that article, each road was
to
"designate to the chairman one person who shall be held
personally responsible for rates on that road. Such person shall be
present at all regular meetings, when possible, and shall represent
his road, unless a superior officer is present. If unable to
attend, he shall send a substitute, with written authority to act
upon all questions which may arise, and the vote of such substitute
shall be binding upon the company he represents."
Section 3 provides that
"A committee shall be appointed to establish rates, rules, and
regulations on the traffic subject to this association, and to
consider changes therein, and makes rules for meeting the
competition of outside lines. Their conclusions, when unanimous,
shall be made effective when they so order; but, if they differ,
the question at issue shall be referred to the managers of the
lines parties hereto; and, if they disagree, it shall be arbitrated
in the manner provided in article VII."
By section 4, it was provided that
"at least five days' written notice prior to each monthly
meeting shall be given the chairman of any proposed reduction in
rates or change in any rule or regulation governing freight
traffic, eight days insofar as applicable to the traffic of
Colorado or Utah."
Sections 5, 6, 7, 8, 9, 10, and 11 of article II read as
follows:
"Sec. 5. At each monthly meeting, the association shall consider
and vote upon all changes proposed, of which due notice has been
given, and all parties shall be bound by the decision of the
association, as expressed, unless then and there
Page 166 U. S. 295
the parties shall give the association definite written notice
that, in ten days thereafter, they shall make such modification,
notwithstanding the vote of the association:
Provided,
that, if the member giving notice of change shall fail to be
represented at the meeting, no action shall be taken on its notice,
and the same shall be considered withdrawn. Should any member
insist upon a reduction of rate against the views of the majority,
or if the majority favor the same and if, in the judgment of such
majority, the rate so made affects seriously the rates upon other
traffic, then the association may, by a majority vote, upon such
other traffic put into effect corresponding rates to take effect on
the same day. By unanimous consent, any rate, rule, or regulation
relating to freight traffic may be modified at any meeting of the
association without previous notice."
"Sec. 6. Notwithstanding anything in this article contained,
each member may at its peril, make at any time, without previous
notice, such rate, rule, or regulations as may be necessary to meet
the competition of lines not members of the association, giving at
the same time notice to the chairman of its action in the premises.
If the chairman, upon investigation, shall decide that such rate is
not necessary to meet the direct competition of lines not members
of the association, and shall so notify the road making the rate,
it shall immediately withdraw such rate. At the next meeting of the
association held after the making of such rate, it shall be
reported to the association, and, if the association shall decide
by a two-thirds vote that such rate was not made in good faith to
meet such competition, the member offending shall be subject to the
penalty provided in section 8 of this article. If the association
shall decide by a two-thirds vote that such rate was made in good
faith to meet such competition, it shall be considered as authority
for the rate so made."
"Sec. 7. All arrangements with connecting lines for the division
of through rates relating to traffic covered by this agreement
shall be made by authority of the association:
Provided,
however, that, when one road has a proprietary interest in
another, the divisions between such roads shall be
Page 166 U. S. 296
what they may elect, and shall not be the property of the
association:
Provided, further, that, as regards traffic
contracts at this date actually existing between lines not having
common proprietary interests, the same shall be reported, so far as
divisions are concerned, to the association, to the end that
divisions with competing lines may, if thought advisable by them,
be made on equally favorable terms."
"Sec. 8. It shall be the duty of the chairman to investigate all
apparent violations of the agreement, and to report his findings to
the managers, who shall determine, by a majority vote (the member
against whom complaint is made to have no vote), what, if any,
penalty shall be assessed, the amount of each fine not to exceed
one hundred dollars, to be paid to the association. If any line
party hereto agrees with a shipper, or any one else, to secure a
reduction or change in rates, or change in the rules and
regulations, and it is shown upon investigation by the chairman
that such an arrangement was effected, and traffic thereby secured,
such action shall be reported to the managers, who shall determine,
as above provided, what, if any, penalty shall be assessed."
"Sec. 9. When a penalty shall have been declared against any
member of this association, the chairman shall notify the managing
officer of said company that such fine has been assessed, and that
within ten days thereafter he will draw for the amount of the fine;
and the draft, when presented, shall be honored by the company thus
assessed."
"Sec. 10. All fines collected to be used to defray the expenses
of the association, the offending party not to be benefited by the
amounts it may pay as fines."
"Sec. 11. Any member not present or fully represented at roll
call of general or special meetings of the freight association, of
which due and proper notice has been given, shall be fined one
dollar, to be assessed against his company, unless he shall have
previously filed with the chairman notice of inability to be
present or represented."
Articles 3, 5, 6, and 7 contain appropriate provisions for the
carrying out of the purposes of the agreement, but it is not
necessary to here set them forth in detail.
Page 166 U. S. 297
Article IV reads as follows:
"
Article IV"
"Any willful underbilling in weights, or billing of freight at
wrong classification shall be considered a violation of this
agreement, and the rules and regulations of any weighing
association or inspection bureau, as established by it or as
enforced by its officers and agents, shall be considered binding
under the provisions of this agreement, and any willful violation
of them shall be subject to the penalties provided herein."
Article VIII provides that the agreement should take effect
April 1, 1889, subject thereafter to 30 days' notice of a desire on
the part of any line to withdraw from the same.
On the 6th of January, 1892, the United States, as complainant,
filed in the circuit court, of the United States for the district
of Kansas, through its United States attorney for that district,
and under the direction of the attorney general of the United
States, its bill of complaint against the Trans-Missouri Freight
Association, named in the agreement above mentioned, the Atchison,
Topeka & Santa Fe Railroad Company, and some 17 other railroad
companies, the officers of which had, it was alleged, signed the
agreement above mentioned in behalf of and for their respective
companies. The bill was filed by the government for the purpose of
having the agreement between the defendant railroad companies set
aside and declared illegal and void, and to have the association
dissolved.
It alleged that the defendant railroad corporations signing the
agreement were at that time, and ever since have been, common
carriers of all classes and kinds of freight and commodities which
were commonly moved, carried, and transported by railroad companies
in their freight traffic, and at all such times have been, and then
were, continuously engaged in transporting freight and commodities
in the commerce, trade, and traffic which is continuously carried
on among
Page 166 U. S. 298
and between the several states of the United States, and among
and between the several states and territories of the United
States, and between the people residing in, and all persons engaged
in trade and commerce within and among and between, the states,
territories, and countries aforesaid; that each of the defendants
was, prior to the 15th day of March, 1889, the owner and in the
control of, and that they were respectively operating and using,
distinct and separate lines of railroad, fitted up for carrying on
business as such carriers in the freight traffic above mentioned,
independently and disconnectedly with each other, and that said
lines of railroad had been, and then were, the only lines of
transportation and communication engaged in the freight traffic
between and among the states and territories of the United States
having through lines for said freight traffic in all that region of
country lying to the westward of the Mississippi and Missouri
rivers, and east of the Pacific Ocean; that these lines of railroad
furnish to the public, and to persons engaged in trade and traffic
and commerce between the several states and territories and
countries above mentioned, separate, distinct, and competitive
lines of transportation and communication extending along and
between the states and territories of the United States lying
westward of the Mississippi and Missouri rivers to the Pacific
Ocean; and that the construction and maintenance of said several
separate, distinct, and competitive lines of railroad aforesaid had
been encouraged and assisted by the United States and by the states
and territories in the region of country aforesaid, and by the
people of the said several states and territories, by franchises
and by grants and donations of large amounts of land of great
value, and of money and securities, for the purpose of securing to
the public, and to the people engaged in trade and commerce
throughout the region of country aforesaid, competitive lines of
transportation and communication; and that, prior to the 15th day
of March, 1889, and subsequently and up to the present time, each
and all of said defendants have been and are engaged as common
carriers in the railway freight traffic connected with the
interstate commerce of the United States
It is then alleged in the bill as follows:
Page 166 U. S. 299
"And your orator further avers that, on or about the fifteenth
day of March, 1889, the defendants not being content with the usual
rates and prices for which they and others were accustomed to move,
carry, and transport property, freight, and commodities in the
trade and commerce aforesaid, and in their said business and
occupation, but contriving and intending unjustly and oppressively
to increase and augment the said rates and prices, and to
counteract the effect of free competition on the facilities and
prices of transportation, and to establish and maintain arbitrary
rates, and to prevent any one of said defendants from reducing such
arbitrary rates, and thereby exact and procure great sums of money
from the people of the said states and territories aforesaid, and
from the people engaged in the interstate commerce, trade, and
traffic within the region of country aforesaid, and from all
persons having goods, wares and merchandise to be transported by
said railroads, and intending to monopolize the trade, traffic, and
commerce among and between the states and territories aforesaid,
did combine, conspire, confederate, and unlawfully agree together,
and did then and there enter into a written contract, combination,
agreement, and compact, known as a memorandum of agreement of the
Trans-Missouri Freight Association, which was signed by each of
said above-named defendants."
The bill then sets forth the agreement signed by the various
corporations defendant.
It is further alleged that the agreement went into effect on the
1st day of April, 1889, and that, since that time, each and all of
the defendants, by reason of the agreement, have put into effect
and kept in force upon the several lines of railroads the rules and
regulations and rates and prices for moving, carrying, and
transporting freight fixed and established by the association, and
have declined and refused to fix or establish and maintain or give
on their railroads rates and prices for the carrying of freight
based upon the cost of constructing and maintaining their several
lines of railroad and the cost of carrying freights over the same,
and such other elements as should be considered in establishing
tariff rates upon each
Page 166 U. S. 300
particular road; and the people of the states and territories
subject to said association, and all persons engaged in trade and
commerce within, among, and between the different states and
territories, have been compelled to, and are still compelled to,
pay the arbitrary rates of freight, and submit to the arbitrary
rules and regulations, established and maintained by the
association, and ever since that date have been, and still are,
deprived of the benefits that might be expected to flow from free
competition between said several lines of transportation and
communication, and are deprived of the better facilities and
cheaper rates of freight that might be reasonably expected to flow
from free competition between the lines above mentioned; and that
the trade, traffic, and commerce in such region of country, and the
freight traffic in connection therewith, have been and are
monopolized and restrained, hindered, injured, and retarded by the
defendants by means and through the instrumentality of such
association.
The bill further averred that, notwithstanding the passage of
the act of Congress above mentioned, on the 2d day of July, 1890,
the
"defendants still continue in and still engage in said unlawful
combination and conspiracy, and still maintain said Trans-Missouri
Freight Association, with all the powers specified in the
memorandum of agreement and articles of association hereinbefore
set forth, which said agreement, combination, and conspiracy so as
aforesaid entered into and maintained by said defendants is of
great injury and grievous prejudice to the common and public good,
and to the welfare of the people of the United States."
The prayer of the bill is as follows:
"In consideration whereof, and inasmuch as your orator can only
have adequate relief in the premises in this honorable court where
matters of this nature are properly cognizable and relievable, your
orator prays that this honorable court may order, adjudge, and
decree that said Trans-Missouri Freight Association be dissolved,
and that said defendants, and all and each of them, be enjoined and
prohibited from further agreeing, combining, and conspiring and
acting together to maintain rules and regulations and rates for
carrying
Page 166 U. S. 301
freight upon their several lines of railroad to hinder trade and
commerce between the states and territories of the United States;
and that all and each of them be enjoined and prohibited from
entering or continuing in a combination, association, or conspiracy
to deprive the people engaged in trade and commerce between and
among the states and territories of the United States of such
facilities and rates and charges of freight transportation as will
be afforded by free and unrestrained competition between the said
several lines of railroad; and that all and each of said defendants
be enjoined and prohibited from agreeing, combining, and conspiring
and acting together to monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, the
freight traffic in the trade and commerce between the states and
territories of the United States; and that all and each of said
defendants be enjoined and prohibited from agreeing, combining, and
conspiring and acting together to prevent each and any of their
associates from carrying freight and commodities in the trade and
commerce between the states and territories of the United States at
such rates as shall be voluntarily fixed by the officers and agents
of each of said roads acting independently and separately in its
own behalf."
The defendants were required to answer fully, etc., each and all
of the matters charged in the bill, but such answer was not
required to be under oath, an answer under oath being specially
waived.
The Chicago, Kansas & Nebraska Railway Company, the
Missouri, Kansas & Texas Railway Company, and the Denver, Texas
& Ft. Worth Railroad Company denied being parties to the
association. the other 15 companies filed separate answers, each
setting up substantially the same defense.
They admit they are common carriers engaged in the
transportation of persons and property in the states and
territories mentioned in the agreement, and they allege that, as
such common carriers, they are subject to the provisions of the Act
of Congress approved February 4, 1887, entitled "An act to regulate
commerce," with the various amendments thereof and additions
thereto,
Page 166 U. S. 302
and they allege that that act and the amendments constitute a
system of regulations established by Congress for common carriers
subject to the act, and they deny that they are subject to the
provisions of the act of Congress passed July 2, 1890, and above
set forth.
They admit that they severally own, control, and operate
separate and distinct lines of railroad constructed and fitted for
carrying on business as common carriers of freight, independently
and disconnectedly with each other, except that a common interest
exists between certain companies, named in the answer. They admit
that the lines of railroad mentioned in the bill furnish lines of
transportation and communication to persons engaged in freight
traffic between and among the states and territories of the United
States, having through lines for freight traffic in that region of
country lying to the westward of the Mississippi and Missouri
rivers and east of the Pacific Ocean, but deny that they are the
only such lines, and allege that there are several others, naming
them.
They further admit that, prior to the organization of the
freight association, the defendants furnished to the public, and to
persons engaged in trade, traffic, and commerce between the several
states and territories named in the agreement, separate, distinct,
and competitive lines of transportation and communication, and they
allege that they still continue to do so.
They admit that some of the roads mentioned in the bill received
aid by land grants from the United States, and others received aid
from states and territories by loans of credits, donations of depot
sites and rights of way, and, in a few cases, by investments of
money, and that the people of the states and territories, to a
limited extent, made investments in the stocks and bonds of some of
the roads, while others, mentioned in the bill, were almost
exclusively constructed by capital furnished by nonresidents of
that region.
It is also admitted that the purpose of the land grants, loans,
donations, and investments was to obtain the construction of
competitive lines of transportation and communication, to the end
that the public and the people engaged in trade
Page 166 U. S. 303
and commerce throughout that region of country might have
facilities afforded by railways in communicating with each other
and with other portions of the United States and the world, and
denies that they were granted for any other purpose.
The defendants admit the formation, on or about March 15, 1889,
of the voluntary association described in the bill as the
"Trans-Missouri Freight Association."
They deny the allegation that they were not content with the
rates and prices prevailing at the date of the agreement; they deny
any intent to unjustly increase rates, and deny that the agreement
destroyed, prevented, or illegally limited or influenced
competition; they deny that arbitrary rates were fixed or charged,
or that rates have been increased, or that the effect of free
competition has been counteracted; they deny any purpose in the
formation of the association to monopolize trade, traffic, and
commerce between the states and territories within the region
mentioned the bill; and they deny that the agreement is in any
respect the illegal result of any unlawful confederation or
conspiracy. The defendants allege that the power object of the
association is to establish reasonable rates, rules, and
regulations on all freight traffic, and the maintenance of such
rates until changed in the manner provided by law; that the
agreement was filed with the Interstate Commerce Commission as
required by section 6 of the act of February 4, 1887. They also
allege that it was not the purpose of the association to prevent
the members from reducing rates or changing the rules and
regulations fixed by the association; that, by the terms of the
agreement, each member may do so, the preliminary requirement being
that the proposed change shall be voted upon at a meeting of the
association, after which, if the proposal is not agreed to, the
line making the proposal can make such reduced rate notwithstanding
the objection of the other lines; that the purpose of this
provision was to afford opportunity for the consideration of the
reasonableness of any proposed rate, rule or regulation by all
lines interested, and an interchange of views on the effect of
such
Page 166 U. S. 304
reduction, and that reductions of rates have been made in
numerous instances through said process by the association. They
admit the agreement took effect April 1, 1889, and that it has
remained in operation since, and that the rates, rules, and
regulations fixed and established from time to time under said
agreement have been put into effect and maintained in conformity to
law; and it is denied that, by reason of the agreement, or under
duress of fines and penalties, or otherwise, the defendants have
refused to establish and maintain just and reasonable rates; and it
is alleged that the object of the association at all times has been
and is to establish all rates, rules, and regulations upon a just
and reasonable basis, and to avoid unjust discrimination and undue
preference. They deny that shippers or the public are in any way
oppressed or injured by reason of the rates fixed by the
association, but, on the contrary, they allege that the agreement
and the association established under it have been beneficial to
the patrons of the railway lines composing the association and the
public at large. These, in substance, are the allegations in the
various answers.
The cause came on for hearing on bill and answer before the
Circuit Court of the United States for the district of Kansas,
First division. That court dismissed the bill without costs against
the complainant. 53 Fed. 440. The Government duly appealed from the
judgment to the United States Circuit Court of Appeals for the
Eighth circuit, and that court, after argument, affirmed, in
October, 1893, the judgment of the Circuit Court, without costs,
Shiras, district judge, dissenting. 19 U.S.App. 36. From that
judgment, the Government has appealed to this Court.
A motion is now made upon affidavits to dismiss the appeal. The
affidavits show that, on the 18th of November, 1892, a resolution
was adopted by the Trans-Missouri Freight Association, one of the
defendants, providing that the organization should be discontinued
from and after the 19th of November, 1892, and the secretary was
instructed to wind up its affairs at as early a date as possible.
It further appeared by the affidavits that the Trans-Missouri
Freight Association was
Page 166 U. S. 305
actually dissolved, and its existence ended, on the above date,
November 19, 1982, and that it has not since that date been
revived, nor has it since that date had any activity of any kind,
"and that it has not conducted or been engaged in any operations or
business whatever, but that it has been dead and out of
existence."
It is also alleged as another ground for dismissing the appeal
that the matter in controversy does not exceed $1,000, and that the
case does not come under any other provision of the act of 1891,
allowing an appeal from the Circuit Courts of appeals to this
Court. In opposition to the motion, it appeared upon the part of
the appellant that at the same meeting at which the resolution
above referred to was adopted, the following resolution was also
adopted:
"
Resolved, that a committee of seven be appointed by
the chairman of this meeting to draw up a new agreement for the
conduct of business now substantially covered by the Trans-Missouri
agreement, and to make a report to all lines in the Trans-Missouri
Association at a meeting to be called in Chicago on December 6,
1892."
A committee of seven was accordingly appointed, which adopted a
resolution calling a meeting for the 6th of December, 1892, of the
lines formerly members of the Trans-Missouri Association, and
representatives of other interested lines, for the purpose of
considering any changes in the tariffs and of business which was
under the jurisdiction of that association, and which might be
submitted to the parties at that time, and to further consider the
organization of one or more rate committees to govern the manner of
making rates on such traffic until some permanent organization
could be effected. In the early days of December, 1892, the meeting
so called was held, and was participated in by most of the railroad
companies which were parties to the Trans-Missouri agreement, and
at that meeting, an agreement was made upon the subject of rates of
freight, and a West Missouri freight rate committee was appointed,
the duties of which committee were to establish and maintain
reasonable rates in the territory described, and other lines not
therein represented, but interested in the freight traffic of such
territory, were to be invited to become members. A plan for
Page 166 U. S. 306
the establishment of subrate committees for the purpose of
agreeing upon rates was therein set forth and agreed to. The
agreement was to become effective on the 1st of January, 1892, and
to remain in force until the following April, during which time it
was supposed that a new and permanent association to provide for an
agreement relating to rates of freight might be founded. It does
not appear whether such permanent association has been formed, or
that the temporary agreement has been actually terminated.
In answer to the motion to dismiss on the ground that the matter
in controversy did not amount to over a thousand dollars, the
parties have stipulated as follows:
"It is hereby stipulated for the purposes of this case, and no
other, and without waiving any right to question the legal effect
of such fact, that the daily freight charges on interstate
shipments collected by all the railway companies at points where
they compete with each other were at the time of the agreement
mentioned in the pleadings herein, and have been since, more than
one thousand dollars. "
Page 166 U. S. 307
MR. JUSTICE PECKHAM, after stating the facts in the foregoing
language, delivered the opinion of the Court.
The defendants object to the hearing of this appeal, and ask
that it be dismissed on the ground that the Trans-Missouri Freight
Association has been dissolved by a vote of its members since the
judgment entered in this suit in the court below. A further ground
urged for the dismissal of the appeal is that the requisite amount
(over $1,000) is not in controversy in the suit, and that, as an
appeal would only lie to this Court in this character of suit under
the Act of March 3, 1891, c. 517, 28 Stat. 826, where that amount
is in controversy the appeal should be dismissed.
As to the first ground, we think the fact of the dissolution of
the association does not prevent this Court from taking cognizance
of the appeal and deciding the case upon its merits.
Page 166 U. S. 308
The prayer of the bill filed in this suit asks not only for the
dissolution of the association, but, among other things, that the
defendants should be restrained from continuing in a like
combination, and that they should be enjoined from further
conspiring, agreeing, or combining and acting together to maintain
rules and regulations and rates for carrying freight upon their
several lines, etc. The mere dissolution of the association is not
the most important object of this litigation. The judgment of the
court is sought upon the question of the legality of the agreement
itself for the carrying out of which the association was formed,
and, if such agreement be declared to be illegal, the court is
asked not only to dissolve the association named in the bill, but
that the defendants should be enjoined for the future.
The defendants, in bringing to the notice of the Court the fact
of the dissolution of the association, take pains to show that such
dissolution had no connection or relation whatever with the
pendency of this suit, and that the association was not terminated
on that account. They do not admit the illegality of the agreement,
nor do they allege their purpose not to enter into a similar one in
the immediate future. On the contrary, by their answers, the
defendants claim that the agreement is a perfectly proper,
legitimate, and salutary one, and that it or one like it is
necessary to the prosperity of the companies. If the injunction
were limited to the prevention of any action by the defendants
under the particular agreement set out, or if the judgment were to
be limited to the dissolution of the association mentioned in the
bill, the relief obtained would be totally inadequate to the
necessities of the occasion, provided an agreement of that nature
were determined to be illegal. The injunction should go further,
and enjoin defendants from entering into or acting under any
similar agreement in the future. In other words, the relief granted
should be adequate to the occasion.
As an answer to the fact of the dissolution of the association,
it is shown on the part of the Government that these very
defendants, or most of them, immediately entered into a
substantially similar agreement, which was to remain in force
for
Page 166 U. S. 309
a certain time, and under which the companies acted, and in
regard to which it does not appear that they are not still acting.
If the mere dissolution of the association worked an abatement of
the suit as to all the defendants, as is the claim made on their
part, it is plain that they have thus discovered an effectual means
to prevent the judgment of this Court being given upon the question
really involved in the case. The defendants having succeeded in the
court below, it would only be necessary thereafter to dissolve
their association and instantly form another of a similar kind, and
the fact of the dissolution would prevent an appeal to this Court
or procure its dismissal if taken. This result does not, and ought
not to, follow. Although the general rule is that equity does not
interfere simply to restrain a possible future violation of law,
yet where parties have entered into an illegal agreement, and are
acting under it, and there is no adequate remedy at law, and the
jurisdiction of the court has attached by the filing of a bill to
restrain such or any like action under a similar agreement, and a
trial has been had, and judgment entered, the appellate
jurisdiction of this Court is not ousted by a simple dissolution of
the association, effected subsequently to the entry of judgment in
the suit.
Private parties may settle their controversies at any time, and
rights which a plaintiff may have had at the time of the
commencement of the action may terminate before judgment is
obtained or while the case is on appeal, and, in any such case, the
court, being informed of the facts, will proceed no further in the
action. Here, however, there has been no extinguishment of the
rights (whatever they are) of the public, the enforcement of which
the Government has endeavored to procure by a judgment of a court
under the provisions of the act of Congress above cited. The
defendants cannot foreclose those rights, nor prevent the assertion
thereof by the Government as a substantial trustee for the public
under the act of Congress, by any such action as has been taken in
this case. By designating the agreement in question as illegal, and
the alleged combination as an unlawful one, we simply mean to say
that such is the character of the agreement as claimed by
Page 166 U. S. 310
the Government. That question the Government has the right to
bring before the Court and obtain its judgment thereon. Whether the
agreement is of that character is the question herein to be
decided.
We think, therefore, the first ground urged by defendants for
the dismissal of the appeal is untenable.
We have no difficulty, either, in sustaining the jurisdiction of
this Court in regard to the second ground, that of the amount in
controversy in the suit.
The bill need not state, in so many words, that a certain
amount, exceeding $1,000, is in controversy, in order that this
Court may have jurisdiction on appeal. The statutory amount must as
a matter of fact be in controversy, yet that fact may appear by
affidavit after the appeal is taken to this Court (
Whiteside v.
Haselton, 110 U. S. 296;
Cattle Co. v. Needham, 137 U. S. 632), or
it may be made to appear in such other manner as shall establish it
to the satisfaction of the Court. A stipulation between the parties
as to the amount is not controlling, but, in the discretion of the
Court, it may be regarded in a particular case, and with reference
to the other facts appearing in the record, as sufficient proof of
the amount in controversy to sustain the jurisdiction of this
Court.
The bill shows here an agreement entered into (as stated in the
agreement itself) for the purpose of maintaining reasonable rates
to be received by each company executing the agreement, and the
stipulation entered into between the parties hereto shows that the
daily freight charges on interstate shipments collected by the
railway companies at points where they compete with each other were
at the time of the making of the agreement mentioned in the
pleadings herein, and have been since, more than $1,000. This
agreement, so made, the Government alleges, is illegal, as being in
restraint of trade, and was entered into between the companies for
the purpose of enhancing the freight rates. The companies, while
denying the illegality of the agreement or its purpose to be other
than to maintain reasonable rates, yet allege that without some
such agreement the competition between them for
Page 166 U. S. 311
traffic would be so severe at to cause great losses to each
defendant, and possibly ruin the companies represented in the
agreement. Such a result, it is claimed, is avoided by reason of
the agreement. Upon the existence, therefore, of this or some
similar agreement directly depends (as is alleged) the prosperity,
if not the life, of each company. It must follow that an amount
much more than a thousand dollars is involved in the maintenance of
the agreement or in the right to maintain it or something like it.
These facts, appearing in the record and the stipulation, show that
the right involved is a right which is of the requisite pecuniary
value. A reduction of the rates by only the fractional part of 1
per centum would, in the aggregate, amount to over a thousand
dollars in a very few days. This is sufficient to give the court
jurisdiction on appeal.
South Carolina v. Seymour,
153 U. S. 353,
153 U. S. 357.
There is directly involved in this suit the validity and the life
of this agreement, or one similar to it. Out of this agreement
directly springs the ability, as well as the right, to maintain
these rates, and each company is interested in maintaining the
validity of the agreement to the same extent as all the others. As
against the agreement, the Government represents the interest of
the public, and thus the parties stand opposed to each other -- the
one in favor of dissolving, and the other of maintaining, the
agreement.
Unlike the case of
Gibson v. Shufeldt, 122 U. S.
27, and the cases therein cited in the opinion of the
Court delivered by Mr. Justice Gray, the defendants here are
jointly interested in the question, and it is not the case of a
fund amounting to more than the requisite sum which is to be paid
to different parties in sums less than the jurisdictional
amount.
For the reasons above stated, we think the jurisdictional fact
in regard to each defendant appears plainly and necessarily from
the record and the stipulation, and that the duty is thus laid upon
this Court to entertain the appeal.
Coming to the merits of the suit, there are two important
questions which demand our examination. They are, first, whether
the above-cited act of Congress (called herein the "Trust Act")
applies to and covers common carriers by railroad,
Page 166 U. S. 312
and, if so, second, does the agreement set forth in the bill
violate any provision of that act?
As to the first question:
The language of the act includes every contract, combination in
the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of
trade or commerce among the several states or with foreign nations.
So far as the very terms of the statute go, they apply to any
contract of the nature described. A contract, therefore, that is in
restraint of trade or commerce is, by the strict language of the
act, prohibited, even though such contract is entered into between
competing common carriers by railroad, and only for the purposes of
thereby affecting traffic rates for the transportation of persons
and property. If such an agreement restrain trade or commerce, it
is prohibited by the statute, unless it can be said that an
agreement, no matter what its terms, relating only to
transportation, cannot restrain trade or commerce. We see no escape
from the conclusion that, if any agreement of such a nature does
restrain it, the agreement is condemned by this act. It cannot be
denied that those who are engaged in the transportation of persons
or property from one state to another are engaged in interstate
commerce, and it would seem to follow that, if such persons enter
into agreements between themselves in regard to the compensation to
be secured from the owners of the articles transported, such
agreement would at least relate to the business of commerce, and
might more or less restrain it. The point urged on the defendants'
part is that the statute was not really intended to reach that kind
of an agreement relating only to traffic rates entered into by
competing common carriers by railroad; that it was intended to
reach only those who were engaged in the manufacture or sale of
articles of commerce, and who, by means of trusts, combinations,
and conspiracies, were engaged in affecting the supply or the price
or the place of manufacture of such articles. The terms of the act
do not bear out such construction. Railroad companies are
instruments of commerce, and their business is commerce itself.
State Freight Tax
Case, 15 Wall. 232,
82 U. S. 275;
Telegraph Co. v. Texas, 105 U. S. 460,
105 U. S.
464.
Page 166 U. S. 313
An act which prohibits the making of every contract, etc., in
restraint of trade or commerce among the several states would seem
to cover by such language a contract between competing railroads,
and relating to traffic rates for the transportation of articles of
commerce between the states, provided such contract, by its direct
effect, produces a restraint of trade or commerce. What amounts to
a restraint, within the meaning of the act if thus construed, need
not now be discussed.
We have held that the Trust Act did not apply to a company
engaged in one state in the refining of sugar under the
circumstances detailed in the case of
United States v. E. C.
Knight Co., 156 U. S. 1, because
the refining of sugar under those circumstances bore no distinct
relation to commerce between the states or with foreign nations. To
exclude agreements as to rates by competing railroads for the
transportation of articles of commerce between the states would
leave little for the act to take effect upon.
Nor do we think that, because the sixth section does not forfeit
the property of the railroad company when merely engaged in the
transportation of property owned under, and which was the subject
of, a contract or combination mentioned in that first section, any
ground is shown for holding the rest of the act inapplicable to
carriers by railroad. It is not perceived why, if the rest of the
act were intended to apply to such a carrier, the sixth section
ought necessarily to have provided for the seizure and condemnation
of the locomotives and cars of the carrier engaged in the
transportation between the states of those articles of commerce
owned as stated in that sixth section. There is some justice and
propriety in forfeiting those articles, but we see none in
forfeiting the locomotives or cars of the carrier simply because
such carrier was transporting articles as described from one state
to another, even though the carrier knew that they had been
manufactured or sold under a contract or combination in violation
of the act. In the case of a simple transportation of such
articles, the carrier would be guilty of no violation of any of the
provisions of the act. Why, therefore,
Page 166 U. S. 314
would it follow that the sixth section should provide for the
forfeiture of the property of the carrier if the rest of the act
were intended to apply to it? To subject the locomotives and cars
to forfeiture under such circumstances might also cause great
confusion to the general business of the carrier, and in that way
inflict unmerited punishment upon the innocent owners of other
property in the course of transportation in the same cars and drawn
by the same locomotives. If the company itself violates the act,
the penalties are sufficient as provided for therein.
But it is maintained that an agreement like the one in question
on the part of the railroad companies is authorized by the Commerce
Act, which is a special statute applicable only to railroads, and
that a construction of the Trust Act (which is a general act) so as
to include within its provisions the case of railroads carries with
it the repeal by implication of so much of the Commerce Act as
authorized the agreement. It is added that there is no language in
the Trust Act which is sufficiently plain to indicate a purpose to
repeal those provisions of the Commerce Act which permit the
agreement; that both acts may stand -- the special or Commerce Act
as relating solely to railroads and their proper regulation and
management, while the later and general act will apply to all
contracts of the nature therein described, entered into by any one
other than competing common carriers by railroad for the purpose of
establishing rates of traffic for transportation. On a line with
this reasoning, it is said that, if Congress had intended to in any
manner affect the railroad carrier as governed by the Commerce Act,
it would have amended that Act directly and in terms, and not have
left it as a question of construction to be determined whether so
important a change in the commerce statute had been accomplished by
the passage of the statute relating to trusts.
The first answer to this argument is that, in our opinion, the
Commerce Act does not authorize an agreement of this nature. It may
not in terms prohibit, but it is far from conferring, either
directly or by implication, any authority to make it. If the
agreement be legal, it does not owe its
Page 166 U. S. 315
validity to any provision of the Commerce Act; and, if illegal,
it is not made so by that Act. The fifth section prohibits what is
termed "pooling," but there is no express provision in the Act
prohibiting the maintenance of traffic rates among competing roads
by making such an agreement as this, nor is there any provision
which permits it. Prior to the passage of the Act, the companies
had sometimes endeavored to regulate competition and to maintain
rates by pooling arrangements, and, in the Act, that kind of an
arrangement was forbidden. After its passage, other devices were
resorted to for the purpose of curbing competition and maintaining
rates. The general nature of a contract like the one before us is
not mentioned in or provided for by the Act. The provisions of that
Act look to the prevention of discrimination; to the furnishing of
equal facilities for the interchange of traffic; to the rate of
compensation for what is termed the "long and the short haul"; to
the attainment of a continuous passage from the point of shipment
to the point of destination at a known and published schedule, and,
in the language of counsel for defendants, "without reference to
the location of those points or the lines over which it is
necessary for the traffic to pass"; to procuring uniformity of
rates charged by each company to its patrons; and to other objects
of a similar nature. The Act was not directed to the securing of
uniformity of rates to be charged by competing companies, nor was
there any provision therein as to a maximum or minimum of rates.
Competing and nonconnecting roads are not authorized by this
statute to make an agreement like this one.
As the Commerce Act does not authorize this agreement, argument
against a repeal by implication of the provisions of the Act which
it is alleged grant such authority becomes ineffective. There is no
repeal in the case, and both statutes may stand, as neither is
inconsistent with the other.
It is plain, also, that an amendment of the Commerce Act would
not be an appropriate method of enacting the legislation contained
in the Trust Act, for the reason that the latter act includes other
subjects in addition to the contracts of or combinations among
railroads, and is addressed to the
Page 166 U. S. 316
prohibition of other contracts besides those relating to
transportation. The omission, therefore, to amend the Commerce Act
furnishes no reason for claiming that the later statute does not
apply to railroad transportation. Although the commerce statute may
be described as a general code for the regulation and Government of
railroads upon the subjects treated of therein, it cannot be
contended that it furnishes a complete and perfect set of rules and
regulations which are to govern them in all cases, and that any
subsequent act in relation to them must, when passed, in effect
amend or repeal some provision of that statute. The statute does
not cover all cases concerning transportation by railroad and all
contracts relating thereto. It does not purport to cover such an
extensive field.
The existence of agreements similar to this one may have been
known to Congress at the time it passed the Commerce Act, although
we are not aware, from the record, that an agreement of this kind
had ever been made and publicly known prior to the passage of the
Commerce Act. Yet, if it had been known to Congress, its omission
to prohibit it at that time, while prohibiting the pooling
arrangements, is no reason for assuming that when passing the Trust
Act it meant to except all contracts of railroad companies in
regard to traffic rates from the operation of such act. Congress,
for its own reasons, even if aware of the existence of such
agreements, did not see fit, when it passed the Commerce Act, to
prohibit them with regard to railroad companies alone, and the act
was not an appropriate place for general legislation on the
subject. And at that time, and for several years thereafter,
Congress did not think proper to legislate upon the subject at all.
Finally it passed this trust act, and in our opinion no obstacle to
its application to contracts relating to transportation by
railroads is to be found in the fact that the Commerce Act had been
passed several years before, in which the entering into such
agreements was not in terms prohibited.
It is also urged that the debates in Congress show beyond a
doubt that the Act, as passed, does not include railroads.
Counsel
Page 166 U. S. 317
for the defendants refer in considerable detail to its history
from the time of its introduction in the Senate to its final
passage. As the Act originally passed the Senate, the first section
was in substance as it stands at present in the statute. On its
receipt by the House, that body proposed an amendment by which it
was, in terms, made unlawful to enter into any contract for the
purpose of preventing competition in the transportation of persons
or property. As thus amended, the bill went back to the Senate,
which itself amended the amendment by making the act apply to any
such contract as tended to raise prices for transportation above
what was just and reasonable. This amendment by the Senate of the
amendment proposed by the House was disagreed to by that body. The
amendments were then considered by conference committees, and the
first conference committee reported to each house in favor of the
amendment of the Senate. This report was disagreed to, and another
committee appointed, which agreed to strike out both amendments and
leave the bill as it stood when it first passed the Senate; and
that report was finally adopted, and the bill thus passed.
Looking at the debates during the various times when the bill
was before the Senate and the House, both on its original passage
by the Senate and upon the report from the conference committees,
it is seen that various views were declared in regard to the legal
import of the Act. Some of the members of the House wanted it
placed beyond doubt or cavil that contracts in relation to the
transportation of persons and property were included in the bill.
Some thought the amendment unnecessary, as the language of the Act
already covered it; and some refused to vote for the amendment, or
for the bill if the amendments were adopted, on the ground that it
would then interfere with the Interstate Commerce Act, and tend to
create confusion as to the meaning of each act. Senator Hoar (who
was a member of the first committee of conference from the Senate),
when reporting the result arrived at by the judiciary committee
recommending the adoption of the House amendment, said:
"The other clause of the House amendment is that contracts or
agreements entered into for the purpose of
Page 166 U. S. 318
preventing competition in the transportation of persons or
property from one state or territory into another shall be deemed
unlawful. That the committee recommend shall be concurred in.
We suppose that it is already covered by the bill as it
stands -- that is, that transportation is as much trade or
commerce among the several states as the sale of goods in one state
to be delivered in another, and, therefore, that it is covered
already by the bill as it stands. But there is no harm in agreeing
in an amendment which expressly describes it, and an objection to
the amendment might be construed as if the Senate did not mean to
include it; so we let it stand."
Looking simply at the history of the bill from the time it was
introduced in the Senate until it was finally passed, it would be
impossible to say what were the views of a majority of the members
of each House in relation to the meaning of the Act. It cannot be
said that a majority of both houses did not agree with Senator Hoar
in his views as to the construction to be given to the Act as it
passed the Senate. All that can be determined from the debates and
reports is that various members had various views, and we are left
to determine the meaning of this act, as we determine the meaning
of other acts. from the language used therein.
There is, too, a general acquiescence in the doctrine that
debates in Congress are not appropriate sources of information from
which to discover the meaning of the language of a statute passed
by that body.
United States v. Union Pacific R. Co.,
91 U. S. 72,
91 U. S. 79;
Aldridge v.
Williams, 3 How. 9,
44 U. S. 24,
Taney, Chief Justice;
Mitchell v. Manufacturing Co., 2
Story 648, 653;
Queen v. Hertford College, 3 Q.B.D. 693,
707.
The reason is that it is impossible to determine with certainty
what construction was put upon an act by the members of a
legislative body that passed it by resorting to the speeches of
individual members thereof. Those who did not speak may not have
agreed with those who did, and those who spoke might differ from
each other, the result being that the only proper way to construe a
legislative act is from the language used in the act, and, upon
occasion, by a resort
Page 166 U. S. 319
to the history of the times when it was passed. (Cases cited
supra.) If such resort be had, we are still unable to see
that the railroads were not intended to be included in this
legislation.
It is said that Congress had very different matters in view, and
very different objects to accomplish, in the passage of the act in
question; that a number of combinations, in the form of trusts and
conspiracies in restraint of trade, were to be found throughout the
country; and that it was impossible for the state governments to
successfully cope with them, because of their commercial character
and of their business extension through the different states of the
Union. Among these trusts, it was said in Congress, were the Beef
Trust, the Standard Oil Trust, the Steel Trust, the Barbed Fence
Wire Trust, the Sugar Trust, the Cordage Trust, the Cotton-Seed Oil
Trust, the Whisky Trust, and many others; and these trusts, it was
stated, had assumed an importance and had acquired a power which
were dangerous to the whole country, and that their existence was
directly antagonistic to its peace and prosperity. To combinations
and conspiracies of this kind it is contended that the act in
question was directed, and not to the combinations of competing
railroads to keep up their prices to a reasonable sum for the
transportation of persons and property. It is true that many and
various trusts were in existence at the time of the passage of the
Act, and it was probably sought to cover them by the provisions of
the Act. Many of them had rendered themselves offensive by the
manner in which they exercised the great power that combined
capital gave them. But a further investigation of "the history of
the times" shows also that those trusts were not the only
associations controlling a great combination of capital which had
caused complaint at the manner in which their business was
conducted. There were many and loud complaints from some portions
of the public regarding the railroads, and the prices they were
charging for the service they rendered, and it was alleged that the
prices for the transportation of persons and articles of commerce
were unduly and improperly enhanced by combinations among the
different
Page 166 U. S. 320
roads. Whether these complaints were well or ill founded we do
not presume at this time, and under these circumstances, to
determine or to discuss. It is simply for the purpose of answering
the statement that it was only to trusts of the nature above set
forth that this legislation was directed that the subject of the
opinions of the people in regard to the actions of the railroad
companies in this particular is referred to. A reference to this
history of the times does not, as we think, furnish us with any
strong reason for believing that it was only trusts that were in
the minds of the members of Congress, and that railroads and their
manner of doing business were wholly excluded therefrom.
Our attention is also called to one of the rules for the
construction of statutes which has been approved by this Court --
that, while it is the duty of courts to ascertain the meaning of
the legislature from the words used in the statute and the subject
matter to which it relates, there is an equal duty to restrict the
meaning of general words whenever it is found necessary to do so in
order to carry out the legislative intent.
Brewer v.
Blougher, 14 Pet. 178,
39 U. S. 198;
Petri v. Commercial Bank of Chicago, 142 U.
S. 644,
142 U. S. 650;
McKee v. United States, 164 U. S. 287. It
is therefore urged that if, by a strict construction of the
language of this statute, it may be made to include railroads, yet
it is evident from other considerations now to be mentioned that
the real meaning of the legislature would not include them, and
they must for that reason be excluded. It is said that this meaning
is plainly to be inferred because of fundamental differences, both
in an economic way and before the law, between trade and
manufacture, on the one hand, and railroad transportation, on the
other. Among these differences are the public character of railroad
business, and, as a result, the peculiar power of control and
regulation possessed by the state over railroad companies. The
trader or manufacturer, on the other hand, carries on an entirely
private business, and can sell to whom he pleases; he may charge
different prices for the same article to different individuals; he
may charge as much as he can get for the article in which he deals,
whether the price be reasonable or
Page 166 U. S. 321
unreasonable; he may make such discrimination in his business as
he chooses, and he may cease to do any business whenever his choice
lies in that direction; while, on the contrary, a railroad company
must transport all persons and property that come to it, and it
must do so at the same price for the same service, and the price
must be reasonable, and it cannot at its will discontinue its
business. It is also urged that there are evils arising from
unrestricted competition in regard to railroads which do not exist
in regard to any other kind of property; that it is so admitted by
the latest and best writers on the subject, and that practical
experience of the results of unrestricted competition among
railroads tends directly to the same view; that the difference
between railroad property, on the one hand, and all other kinds of
property, on the other hand, is so plain that entirely different
economic results follow from unrestricted competition among
railroads from those which obtain in regard to all other kinds of
business. It is also said that the contemporaneous industrial
history of the country, the legal situation in regard to railroad
properties at the time of the enactment of this statute, its
legislative history, the ancient and constantly maintained
different legal effect and policy regarding railway transportation
and ordinary trade and manufacture, together with a just regard for
interests of such enormous magnitude as are represented by the
railroads of the country, all tend to show that Congress, in
passing the antitrust act, never could have contemplated the
inclusion of railroads within its provisions. It is therefore
claimed to be the duty of the court, in carrying out the rule of
statutory construction above stated, to restrict the meaning of
these general words of the statute which would include railroads,
because, from the considerations above mentioned, it is plain that
Congress never intended, that railroads should be included.
Many of the foregoing assertions may be well founded, while at
the same time the correctness of the conclusions sought to be drawn
therefrom need not be conceded. The points of difference between
the railroad and other corporations are many and great. It cannot
be disputed that a railroad
Page 166 U. S. 322
is a public corporation, and its business pertains to and
greatly affects the public, and that it is of a public nature. The
company may not charge unreasonable prices for transportation, nor
can it make unjust discriminations, nor select its patrons, nor go
out of business when it chooses, while a mere trading or
manufacturing company may do all these things. But the very fact of
the public character of a railroad would itself seem to call for
special care by the legislature in regard to its conduct, so that
its business should be carried on with as much reference to the
proper and fair interests of the public as possible. While the
points of difference just mentioned, and others, do exist between
the two classes of corporations, it must be remembered they have
also some points of resemblance. Trading, manufacturing, and
railroad corporations are all engaged in the transaction of
business with regard to articles of trade and commerce, each in its
special sphere -- either in manufacturing or trading in commodities
or in their transportation by rail. A contract among those engaged
in the latter business, by which the prices for the transportation
of commodities traded in or manufactured by the others is greatly
enhanced from what it otherwise would be if free competition were
the rule, affects, and to a certain extent restricts, trade and
commerce, and affects the price of the commodity. Of this there can
be no question. Manufacturing or trading companies may also affect
prices by joining together in forming a trust or other combination,
and by making agreements in restraint of trade and commerce which,
when carried out, affect the interests of the public. Why should
not a railroad company be included in general legislation aimed at
the prevention of that kind of agreement made in restraint of
trade, which may exist in all companies, which is substantially of
the same nature wherever found, and which tends very much towards
the same results whether put in practice by a trading and
manufacturing or by a railroad company? It is true, the results of
trusts, or combinations of that nature, may be different in
different kinds of corporations, and yet they all have an essential
similarity, and have been induced by motives of individual or
corporate aggrandizement
Page 166 U. S. 323
as against the public interest. In business or trading
combinations,
brk:
they may even temporarily, or perhaps permanently, reduce the
price of the article traded in or manufactured by reducing the
expense inseparable from the running of many different companies
for the same purpose. Trade or commerce under those circumstances
may nevertheless be badly and unfortunately restrained by driving
out of business the small dealers and worthy men whose lives have
been spent therein, and who might be unable to readjust themselves
to their altered surroundings. Mere reduction in the price of the
commodity dealt in might be dearly paid for by the ruin of such a
class and the absorption of control over one commodity by an
all-powerful combination of capital. In any great and extended
change in the manner or method of doing business, it seems to be an
inevitable necessity that distress, and perhaps ruin, shall be its
accompaniment in regard to some of those who were engaged in the
old methods. A change from stagecoaches and canal boats to
railroads threw at once a large number of men out of employment.
Changes from hand labor to that of machinery, and from operating
machinery by hand to the application of steam for such purpose,
leave behind them, for the time, a number of men who must seek
other avenues of livelihood. These are misfortunes which seem to be
the necessary accompaniment of all great industrial changes. It
takes time to effect a readjustment of industrial life so that
those who are thrown out of their old employment by reason of such
changes as we have spoken of may find opportunities for labor in
other departments than those to which they have been accustomed. It
is a misfortune, but yet, in such cases, it seems to be the
inevitable accompaniment of change and improvement.
It is wholly different, however, when such changes are effected
by combinations of capital whose purpose in combining is to control
the production or manufacture of any particular article in the
market, and by such control dictate the price at which the article
shall be sold, the effect being to drive out of business all the
small dealers in the commodity and to render the public subject to
the decision of the combination
Page 166 U. S. 324
as to what price shall be paid for the article. In this light,
it is not material that the price of an article may be lowered. It
is in the power of the combination to raise it, and the result in
any event is unfortunate for the country, by depriving it of the
services of a large number of small but independent dealers who
were familiar with the business and who had spent their lives in
it, and who supported themselves and their families from the small
profits realized therein. Whether they be able to find other
avenues to earn their livelihood is not so material, because it is
not for the real prosperity of any country that such changes should
occur which result in transferring an independent businessman, the
head of his establishment, small though it might be, into a mere
servant or agent of a corporation for selling the commodities which
he once manufactured or dealt in, having no voice in shaping the
business policy of the company and bound to obey orders issued by
others. Nor is it for the substantial interests of the country that
any one commodity should be within the sole power and subject to
the sole will of one powerful combination of capital. Congress has,
so far as its jurisdiction extends, prohibited all contracts or
combinations in the form of trusts entered into for the purpose of
restraining trade and commerce. The results naturally flowing from
a contract or combination in restraint of trade or commerce, when
entered into by a manufacturing or trading company such as above
stated, while differing somewhat from those which may follow a
contract to keep up transportation rates by railroads, are
nevertheless of the same nature and kind, and the contracts
themselves do not so far differ in their nature that they may not
all be treated alike and be condemned in common. It is entirely
appropriate generally to subject corporations or persons engaged in
trading or manufacturing to different rules from those applicable
to railroads in their transportation business; but, when the evil
to be remedied is similar in both kinds of corporations, such as
contracts which are unquestionably in restraint of trade, we see no
reason why similar rules should not be promulgated in regard to
both, and both be covered in the same
Page 166 U. S. 325
statute by general language sufficiently broad to include them
both. We see nothing, either in contemporaneous history, in the
legal situation at the time of the passage of the statute, in its
legislative history, or in any general difference in the nature or
kind of these trading or manufacturing companies from railroad
companies, which would lead us to the conclusion that it cannot be
supposed the legislature, in prohibiting the making of contracts in
restraint of trade, intended to include railroads within the
purview of that act.
Neither is the statute, in our judgment, so uncertain in its
meaning, or its language so vague, that it ought not to be held
applicable to railroads. It prohibits contracts, combinations,
etc., in restraint of trade or commerce. Transporting commodities
is commerce, and, if from one state to or through another, it is
interstate commerce. To be reached by the federal statute, it must
be commerce among the several states or with foreign nations. When
the act prohibits contracts in restraint of trade or commerce, the
plain meaning of the language used includes contracts which relate
to either or both subjects. Both trade and commerce are included,
so long as each relates to that which is interstate or foreign.
Transportation of commodities among the several states or with
foreign nations falls within the description of the words of the
statute with regard to that subject, and there is also included in
that language that kind of trade in commodities among the states or
with foreign nations which is not confined to their mere
transportation. It includes their purchase and sale. Precisely at
what point in the course of the trade in or manufacture of
commodities the statute may have effect upon them, or upon
contracts relating to them, may be somewhat difficult to determine,
but interstate transportation presents no difficulties. In
United States v. E. C. Knight Co., 156 U. S.
1, heretofore cited, it was in substance held,
reiterating the language of Mr. Justice Lamar in
Kidd v.
Pearson, 128 U. S. 1, that
the intent to manufacture of export a manufactured article to
foreign nations, or to send it to another state, did not determine
the time when the article or product passed from the control of the
state and
Page 166 U. S. 326
belonged to commerce. The difficulty in determining that
question, however, is no reason for denying effect to language
which, by its terms, plainly includes the transportation of
commodities among the several states or with foreign nations, and
which may also be the subject of contracts or combination in
restraint of such commerce. The difficulty of the subject, so far
as the trade in or the manufacture of commodities is concerned,
arises from the limited control which Congress has over the matter
of trade or manufacture. It was said by Mr. Justice Lamar in
Kidd v. Pearson, supra:
"If it be held that the term 'commerce' includes the regulation
of all such manufactures as are intended to be the subject of
commercial transactions in the future, it is impossible to deny
that it would also include the productive industries that
contemplate the same thing. The result would be that Congress would
be invested, to the exclusion of the states, with the power to
regulate not only manufactures, but also agriculture, horticulture,
stock raising, domestic fisheries, and mining -- in short, every
branch of human industry."
In the
Knight Company Case, supra, it was said that
this statute applied to monopolies in restraint of interstate or
international trade or commerce, and not to monopolies in
manufacture even of a necessary of life. It is readily seen from
these cases that, if the Act do not apply to the transportation of
commodities by railroads from one state to another or to foreign
nations, its application is so greatly limited that the whole Act
might as well be held inoperative.
Still another ground for holding the Act inapplicable is urged,
and that is that the language covers only contracts or combinations
like trusts, or those which, while not exactly trusts, are
otherwise of the same form or nature. This is clearly not so.
While the statute prohibits all combinations in the form of
trusts or otherwise, the limitation is not confined to that form
alone. All combinations which are in restraint of trade or commerce
are prohibited, whether in the form of trusts or in any other form
whatever.
We think, after a careful examination, that the statute
Page 166 U. S. 327
covers, and was intended to cover, common carriers by
railroad.
Second. The next question to be discussed is as to what is the
true construction of the statute, assuming that it applies to
common carriers by railroad. What is the meaning of the language,
as used in the statute, that
"[e]very contract, combination in the form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce among
the several states or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to
be illegal?"
Is it confined to a contract or combination which is only in
unreasonable restraint of trade or commerce, or does it include --
what the language of the act plainly and in terms covers -- all
contracts of that nature?
We are asked to regard the title of this Act as indicative of
its purpose to include only those contracts which were unlawful at
common law, but which require the sanction of a federal statute in
order to be dealt with in a federal court. It is said that, when
terms which are known to the common law are used in a federal
statute, those terms are to be given the same meaning that they
received at common law, and that, when the language of the title is
"to protect trade and commerce against unlawful restraints and
monopolies," it means those restraints and monopolies which the
common law regarded as unlawful, and which were to be prohibited by
the federal statute. We are of opinion that the language used in
the title refers to and includes, and was intended to include,
those restraints and monopolies which are made unlawful in the body
of the statute. It is to the statute itself that resort must be had
to learn the meaning thereof, though a resort to the title here
creates no doubt about the meaning of, and does not alter the plain
language contained in, its text.
It is now, with much amplification of argument, urged that the
statute, in declaring illegal every combination in the form of
trust or otherwise, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or
commerce, does not mean what the language used therein plainly
imports, but that it only means to declare illegal any such
contract which is in
unreasonable restraint of trade,
while leaving all others unaffected by the provisions of the
Page 166 U. S. 328
Act; that the common law meaning of the term "contract in
restraint of trade" includes only such contracts as are in
unreasonable restraint of trade; and, when that term is
used in the federal statute, it is not intended to include all
contracts in restraint of trade, but only those which are in
unreasonable restraint thereof.
The term is not of such limited signification. Contracts in
restraint of trade have been known and spoken of for hundreds of
years, both in England and in this country, and the term includes
all kinds of those contracts which, in fact, restrain or may
restrain trade. Some of such contracts have been held void and
unenforceable in the courts by reason of their restraint's being
unreasonable, while others have been held valid because they were
not of that nature. A contract may be in restraint of trade and
still be valid at common law. Although valid, it is nevertheless a
contract in restraint of trade, and would be so described either at
common law or elsewhere. By the simple use of the term "contract in
restraint of trade," all contracts of that nature, whether valid or
otherwise, would be included, and not alone that kind of contract
which was invalid and unenforceable as being in unreasonable
restraint of trade. When, therefore, the body of an act pronounces
as illegal every contract or combination in restraint of trade or
commerce among the several states, etc., the plain and ordinary
meaning of such language is not limited to that kind of contract
alone which is in unreasonable restraint of trade, but all
contracts are included in such language, and no exception or
limitation can be added without placing in the act that which has
been omitted by Congress.
Proceeding, however, upon the theory that the statute did not
mean what its plain language imported, and that it intended in its
prohibition to denounce as illegal only those contracts which were
in unreasonable restraint of trade, the courts below have made an
exhaustive investigation as to the general rules which guide courts
in declaring contracts to be void as being in restraint of trade,
and therefore against the public policy of the country. In the
course of their discussion
Page 166 U. S. 329
of that subject, they have shown that there has been a gradual,
though great, alteration in the extent of the liberty granted to
the vendor of property in agreeing, as part consideration for his
sale, not to enter into the same kind of business for a certain
time or within a certain territory. So long as the sale was the
bona fide consideration for the promise, and was not made
a mere excuse for an evasion of the rule itself, the later
authorities, both in England and in this country, exhibit a strong
tendency towards enabling the parties to make such a contract in
relation to the sale of property, including an agreement not to
enter into the same kind of business, as they may think proper, and
this with the view to granting to a vendor the freest opportunity
to obtain the largest consideration for the sale of that which is
his own. A contract which is the mere accompaniment of the sale of
property, and thus entered into for the purpose of enhancing the
price at which the vendor sells it, which, in effect, is collateral
to such sale, and where the main purpose of the whole contract is
accomplished by such sale, might not be included within the letter
or spirit of the statute in question. But we cannot see how the
statute can be limited, as it has been by the courts below, without
reading into its text an exception which alters the natural meaning
of the language used, and that, too, upon a most material point,
and where no sufficient reason is shown for believing that such
alteration would make the statute more in accord with the intent of
the lawmaking body that enacted it.
The great stress of the argument for the defendants on this
branch of the case has been to show, if possible, some reason in
the attendant circumstances, or some fact existing in the nature of
railroad property and business, upon which to found the claim that,
although, by the language of the statute, agreements or
combinations in restraint of trade or commerce are included, the
statute really means to declare illegal only those contracts, etc.,
which are in unreasonable restraint of trade. In order to do this,
the defendants call attention to many facts which they have already
referred to in their argument, upon the point that railroads were
not included at all in the statute. They again draw attention to
the fact of the peculiar nature of
Page 166 U. S. 330
railroad property. When a railroad is once built, it is said, it
must be kept in operation. It must transport property when
necessary in order to keep its business at the smallest price, and
for the narrowest profit, or even for no profit, provided running
expenses can be paid, rather than not to do the work; that railroad
property cannot be altered for use for any other purpose at least
without such loss as may fairly be called destructive; that
competition, while perhaps right and proper in other business,
simply leads in railroad business to financial ruin and insolvency,
and to the operation of the road by receivers in the interest of
its creditors, instead of in that of its owners and the public;
that a contest between a receiver of an insolvent corporation and
one which is still solvent tends to ruin the latter company, while
being of no benefit to the former; that a receiver is only bound to
pay operating expenses so he can compete with the solvent company,
and oblige it to come down to prices incompatible with any profit
for the work done, and until ruin overtakes it, to the destruction
of innocent stockholders and the impairment of the public
interests.
To the question why competition should necessarily be conducted
to such an extent as to result in this relentless and continued
war, to eventuate only in the financial ruin of one or all of the
companies indulging in it, the answer is made that, if competing
railroad companies be left subject to the sway of free and
unrestricted competition, the results above foreshadowed
necessarily happen from the nature of the case; that, competition
being the rule, each company will seek business to the extent of
its power, and will underbid its rival in order to get the
business, and such underbidding will act and react upon each
company until the prices are so reduced as to make it impossible to
prosper or live under them; that it is too much to ask of human
nature for one company to insist upon charges sufficiently high to
afford a reasonable compensation, and, while doing so, to see its
patrons leave for rival roads who are obtaining its business by
offering less rates for doing it than can be afforded, and a fair
profit obtained therefrom. Sooner than experience ruin from mere
inanition, efforts will
Page 166 U. S. 331
be made in the direction of meeting the underbidding of its
rival, until both shall end in ruin. The only refuge, it is said,
from this wretched end lies in the power of competing roads
agreeing among themselves to keep up prices for transportation to
such sums as shall be reasonable in themselves, so that companies
may be allowed to save themselves from themselves, and to agree not
to attack each other, but to keep up reasonable and living rates
for the services performed. It is said that, as railroads have a
right to charge reasonable rates, it must follow that a contract
among themselves to keep up their charges to that extent is valid.
Viewed in the light of all these facts, it is broadly and
confidently asserted that it is impossible to believe that
Congress, or any other intelligent and honest legislative body,
could ever have intended to include all contracts or combinations
in restraint of trade, and, as a consequence thereof, to prohibit
competing railways from agreeing among themselves to keep up prices
for transportation to such a rate as should be fair and
reasonable.
These arguments, it must be confessed, bear with much force upon
the policy of an act which should prevent a general agreement upon
the question of rate among competing railroad companies to the
extent simply of maintaining those rates which reasonable and
fair.
There is another side to this question, however, and it may not
be amiss to refer to one or two facts which tend to somewhat modify
and alter the light in which the subject should be regarded. If
only that kind of contract which is in unreasonable restraint of
trade be within the meaning of the statute, and declared therein to
be illegal, it is at once apparent that the subject of what is a
reasonable rate is attended with great uncertainty. What is a
proper standard by which to judge the fact of reasonable rates?
Must the rate be so high as to enable the return for the whole
business done to amount to a sum sufficient to afford the
shareholder a fair and reasonable profit upon his investment? If
so, what is a fair and reasonable profit? That depends sometimes
upon the risk incurred, and the rate itself differs in different
localities. Which is the one to which reference is to be made as
the standard? Or is
Page 166 U. S. 332
the reasonableness of the profit to be limited to a fair return
upon the capital that would have been sufficient to build and equip
the road, if honestly expended? Or is still another standard to be
created, and the reasonableness of the charges tried by the cost of
the carriage of the article, and a reasonable profit allowed on
that? And, in such case, would contribution to a sinking fund to
make repairs upon the roadbed and renewal of cars, etc., be assumed
as a proper item? or is the reasonableness of the charge to be
tested by reference to the charges for the transportation of the
same kind of property made by other roads similarly situated? If
the latter, a combination among such roads as to rates would, of
course, furnish no means of answering the question. It is quite
apparent, therefore, that it is exceedingly difficult to formulate
even the term of the rule itself which should govern in the matter
of determining what would be reasonable rates for transportation.
While, even after the standard should be determined, there is such
an infinite variety of facts entering into the question of what is
a reasonable rate, no matter what standard is adopted, that any
individual shipper would in most cases be apt to abandon the effort
to show the unreasonable character of a charge, sooner than hazard
the great expense in time and money necessary to prove the fact,
and at the same time incur the ill will of the road itself in all
his future dealings with it, to say, therefore, that the Act
excludes agreements which are not in unreasonable restraint of
trade, and which tend simply to keep up reasonable rates for
transportation, is substantially to leave the question of
reasonableness to the companies themselves.
It must also be remembered that railways are public corporations
organized for public purposes, granted valuable franchises and
privileges, among which the right to take the private property of
the citizen
in invitum is not the least (
Cherokee
Nation v. Southern Kansas Railway Co., 135 U.
S. 641,
135 U. S.
657); that many of them are the donees of large tracts
of public lands, and of gifts of money by municipal corporations,
and that they all primarily owe duties to the public of a higher
nature even than that of earning large dividends for
Page 166 U. S. 333
their shareholders. The business which the railroads do is of a
public nature, closely affecting almost all classes in the
community -- the farmer, the artisan, the manufacturer, and the
trader. It is of such a public nature that it may well be doubted,
to say the least, whether any contract which imposes any restraint
upon its business would not be prejudicial to the public
interest.
We recognize the argument upon the part of the defendants that
restraint upon the business of railroads will not be prejudicial to
the public interest so long as such restraint provides for
reasonable rates for transportation and prevents the deadly
competition so liable to result in the ruin of the roads, and to
thereby impair their usefulness to the public, and in that way to
prejudice the public interest. But it must be remembered that these
results are by no means admitted with unanimity; on the contrary,
they are earnestly and warmly denied on the part of the public and
by those who assume to defend its interests both in and out of
Congress. Competition, they urge, is a necessity for the purpose of
securing in the end just and proper rates.
It was said in
Gibbs v. Baltimore Gas Co., 130 U.
S. 396 at page
130 U. S. 408,
by Mr. Chief Justice Fuller, as follows:
"The supply of illuminating gas is a business of a public nature
to meet a public necessity. It is not a business like that of an
ordinary corporation engaged in the manufacture of articles that
may be furnished by individual effort.
New Orleans Gas Co. v.
Louisiana Light Co., 115 U. S. 650;
Louisville
Gas Co. v. Citizens' Gas Co., 115 U. S.
683;
Shepard v. Milwaukee Gas Co., 6 Wisconsin
539;
Chicago Gas Light & Coke Co. v. People's Gas Light
& Coke Co., 121 Illinois 530;
St. Louis v. St. Louis
Gas Light Co., 70 Missouri 69. Hence, while it is justly urged
that those rules which say that a given contract is against public
policy should not be arbitrarily extended so as to interfere with
the freedom of contract.
Printing &c. Registering Co. v.
Samson, L.R. 19 Eq. 462, yet, in the instance of business of
such a character that it presumably cannot be restrained to any
extent whatever without prejudice to the public interest, courts
decline to enforce or
Page 166 U. S. 334
sustain contracts imposing such restraint, however partial,
because in contravention of public policy. This subject is much
considered, and the authorities cited in
West Virginia
Transportation Co. v. Ohio River Pipe Line Co., 22 West Va.
600;
Chicago &c. Gas Co. v. People's Gas Co., 121
Illinois 530;
Western Union Telegraph Co. v. American Union
Telegraph Co., 65 Georgia 160."
It is true, in the
Gibbs Case, there was a special
statute which prohibited the company from entering into any
consolidation, combination, or contract with any other gas company
whatever, and it was provided that any attempt to do so, or to make
such combination or contract, should be utterly null and void. The
above extract from the opinion of the Court is made for the purpose
of showing the difference which exists between a private and a
public corporation; that kind of a public corporation which, while
doing business for remuneration, is yet so connected in interest
with the public as to give a public character to its business; and
it is seen that while, in the absence of a statute prohibiting
them, contracts of private individuals or corporations touching
upon restraints in trade must be unreasonable in their nature to be
held void, different considerations obtain in the case of public
corporations like those of railroads, where it well may be that any
restraint upon a business of that character, as affecting its rates
of transportation, must thereby be prejudicial to the public
interests.
The plaintiffs are, however, under no obligation, in order to
maintain this action, to show that, by the common law, all
agreements among competing railroad companies to keep up rates to
such as are reasonable were void as in restraint of trade or
commerce. There are many cases which look in that direction, if
they do not precisely decide that point. Some of them are referred
to in the opinion in the
Baltimore Gas Company Case, above
cited. The case of the
Mogul Steamship Co. v McGregor, 21
Q.B.D. 544, 23 Q.B.D. 598; 1892 App.Cas. 25, has been cited by the
courts below as holding in principle that contracts of this nature
are valid at common law. The agreement held valid there was
Page 166 U. S. 335
an agreement for lowering rates of transportation among the
parties thereto, and it was entered into for the purpose of driving
out of trade rival steamships, in order that thereafter the rates
might be advanced. The English courts held that the agreement was
not a conspiracy, and that it was valid, although the result aimed
at was to drive a rival out of the field, because, so long as the
injury to such rival was not the sole reason for the agreement, but
self-interest the predominating motive, there was nothing wrong in
law with an agreement of that kind. But, assuming that agreements
of this nature are not void at common law, and that the various
cases cited by the learned courts below show it, the answer to the
statement of their validity now is to be found in the terms of the
statute under consideration. The provisions of the Interstate
Commerce Act relating to reasonable rates, discriminations, etc.,
do not authorize such an agreement as this, nor do they authorize
any other agreements which would be inconsistent with the
provisions of this Act.
The general reasons for holding agreements of this nature to be
invalid, even at common law, on the part of railroad companies are
quite strong, if not entirely conclusive.
Considering the public character of such corporations, the
privileges and franchises which they have received from the public
in order that they might transact business, and bearing in mind how
closely and immediately the question of rates for transportation
affects the whole public, it may be urged that Congress had in mind
all the difficulties which we have before suggested of proving the
unreasonableness of the rate, and might, in consideration of all
the circumstances, have deliberately decided to prohibit all
agreements and combinations in restraint of trade or commerce,
regardless of the question whether such agreements were reasonable
or the reverse.
It is true that, as to a majority of those living along its
line, each railroad is a monopoly. Upon the subject now under
consideration, it is well said by Judge Oliver P. Shiras, United
States District Judge, Northern district of Iowa, in his very able
dissenting opinion in this case in the United States Circuit Court
of Appeals, as follows:
Page 166 U. S. 336
"As to the majority of the community living along its line, each
railway company has a monopoly of the business demanding
transportation as one of its elements. By reason of this fact, the
action of this corporation in establishing the rates to be charged
largely influences the net profit coming to the farmer, the
manufacturer, and the merchant, from the sale of the products of
the farm, the workshop and manufactory, and of the merchandise
purchased and resold, and also largely influences the price to be
paid by everyone who consumes any of the property transported over
the line of railway. There is no other line of business carried on
in our midst which is so intimately connected with the public as
that conducted by the railways of the country. . . . A railway
corporation engaged in the transportation of the persons and
property of the community is always carrying on a public business
which at all times directly affects the public welfare. All
contracts or combinations entered into between railway corporations
intended to regulate the rates to be charged the public for the
service rendered must, of necessity, affect the public interests.
By reason of this marked distinction existing between enterprises
inherently public in their character and those of a private nature,
and, further, by reason of the difference between private persons
and corporations engaged in private pursuits, who owe no direct or
primary duty to the public and public corporations created for the
express purpose of carrying on public enterprises, and which, in
consideration of the public powers exercised in their behalf, are
under obligation to carry on the work intrusted to their management
primarily in the interest and for the benefit of the community, it
seems clear to me that the same test is not applicable to both
classes of business and corporations in determining the validity of
contracts and combinations entered into by those engaged therein. .
. . In the opinion of the court are found "
brk:
citations from the reports of the Interstate Commerce Commission
in which are depicted the evils that are occasioned to the railway
companies and the public by warfares over rate charges, and the
advantages that are gained in many directions by proper conference
and concert of action among the competing
Page 166 U. S. 337
lines. It may be entirely true that, as we proceed in the
development of the policy of public control over railway traffic,
methods will be devised and put in operation by legislative
enactment whereby railway companies and the public may be protected
against the evils arising from unrestricted competition, and from
rate wars which unsettle the business of the community; but I fail
to perceive the force of the argument that, because railway
companies, through their own action, cause evils to themselves and
the public by sudden changes or reductions in tariff rates, they
must be permitted to deprive the community of the benefit of
competition in securing reasonable rates for the transportation of
the products of the country. Competition, free and unrestricted, is
the general rule which governs all the ordinary business pursuits
and transactions of life. Evils, as well as benefits, result
therefrom. In the fierce heat of competition, the stronger
competitor may crush out the weaker; fluctuations in prices may be
caused that result in wreck and disaster; yet, balancing the
benefits as against the evils, the law of competition remains as a
controlling element in the business world. That free and
unrestricted competition in the matter of railroad charges may be
productive of evils does not militate against the fact that such is
the law now governing the subject. No law can be enacted nor system
be devised for the control of human affairs that, in its
enforcement, does not produce some evil results, no matter how
beneficial its general purpose may be. There are benefits and there
are evils which result from the operation of the law of free
competition between railway companies. The time may come when the
companies will be relieved from the operation of this law, but they
cannot, by combination and agreements among themselves, bring about
this change. The fact that the provisions of the Interstate
Commerce Act may have changed in many respects the conduct of the
companies in the carrying on of the public business they are
engaged in does not show that it was the intent of Congress, in the
enactment of that statute, to clothe railway companies with the
right to combine together for the purpose of avoiding the effects
of competition on the subject of rates.
Page 166 U. S. 338
The whole opinion is a remarkably strong presentation of the
views of the learned judge who wrote it.
Still, again, it is answered that the effects of free
competition among railroad companies, as described by the counsel
for the companies themselves in the course of their argument, are
greatly exaggerated. According to that argument, the moment an
agreement of this nature is prohibited the railroads commence to
cut their rates, and they cease only with their utter financial
ruin, leaving, perhaps, one to raise rates indefinitely when its
rivals have been driven away. It is said that this is a most
overdrawn statement, and that, while absolutely free competition
may have, in some instances and for a time, resulted in injury to
some of the railroads, it is not at all clear that the general
result has been other than beneficial to the whole public, and not,
in the long run, detrimental to the prosperity of the roads. It is
matter of common knowledge that agreements as to rates have been
continually made of late years, and that complaints of each company
in regard to the violation of such agreements by its rivals have
been frequent and persistent. Rate wars go on notwithstanding any
agreement to the contrary, and the struggle for business among
competing roads keeps on, and, in the nature of things, will keep
on, and alleged agreement to the contrary notwithstanding; and it
is only by the exercise of good sense, and by the presence of a
common interest, that railroads, without entering into any
affirmative agreement in regard thereto, will keep within the limit
of exacting a fair and reasonable return for services rendered.
These agreements have never been found really effectual for any
extended period.
The Interstate Commerce Commission, from whose reports
quotations have been quite freely made by counsel for the purpose
of proving the views of its learned members in regard to this
subject, has never distinctly stated that agreements among
competing railroads to maintain prices are to be commended, or that
the general effect is to be regarded as beneficial. They have
stated in their fourth annual report that competition may
degenerate into rate wars, and that such wars are as unsettling to
the business of the country
Page 166 U. S. 339
as they are mischievous to the carriers, and that the spirit of
existing law is against them. They then add:
"Agreements between railroad companies which from time to time
they have entered into with a view to prevent such occurrences have
never been found effectual, and for the very sufficient reason that
the mental reservations in forming them have been quite as numerous
and more influential than the written stipulations."
It would seem true, therefore, that there is no guaranty of
financial health to be found in entering into agreements for the
maintenance of rates, nor is financial ruin or insolvency the
necessary result of their absence.
The claim that the company has the right to charge reasonable
rates, and that, therefore, it has the right to enter into a
combination with competing roads to maintain such rates, cannot be
admitted. The conclusion does not follow from an admission of the
premise. What one company may do in the way of charging reasonable
rates is radically different from entering into an agreement with
other and competing roads to keep up the rates to that point. If
there be any competition, the extent of the charge for the service
will be seriously affected by that fact. Competition will itself
bring charges down to what may be reasonable, while, in the case of
an agreement to keep prices up, competition is allowed no play. It
is shut out, and the rate is practically fixed by the companies
themselves by virtue of the agreement, so long as they abide by
it.
As a result of this review of the situation, we find two very
widely divergent views of the effects which might be expected to
result from declaring illegal all contracts in restraint of trade,
etc., one side predicting financial disaster and ruin to competing
railroads, including thereby the ruin of shareholders, the
destruction of immensely valuable properties, and the consequent
prejudice to the public interest; while, on the other side,
predictions equally earnest are made that no such mournful results
will follow, and it is urged that there is a necessity, in order
that the public interest may be fairly and justly protected, to
allow free and open competition among railroads upon the subject of
the rates for the transportation of persons and property.
Page 166 U. S. 340
The arguments which have been addressed to us against the
inclusion of all contracts in restraint of trade, as provided for
by the language of the Act, have been based upon the alleged
presumption that Congress, notwithstanding the language of the Act,
could not have intended to embrace all contracts, but only such
contracts as were in unreasonable restraint of trade. Under these
circumstances, we are therefore asked to hold that the Act of
Congress excepts contracts which are not in unreasonable restraint
of trade, and which only keep rates up to a reasonable price,
notwithstanding the language of the Act makes no such exception. In
other words, we are asked to read into the Act, by way of judicial
legislation, an exception that is not placed there by the lawmaking
branch of the Government, and this is to be done upon the theory
that the impolicy of such legislation is so clear that it cannot be
supposed Congress intended the natural import of the language it
used. This we cannot and ought not to do. That impolicy is not so
clear, nor are the reasons for the exception so potent, as to
permit us to interpolate an exception into the language of the Act,
and to thus materially alter its meaning and effect. It may be that
the policy evidenced by the passage of the act itself will, if
carried out, result in disaster to the roads and in a failure to
secure the advantages sought from such legislation. Whether that
will be the result or not we do not know and cannot predict. These
considerations are, however, not for us. If the Act ought to read
as contended for by defendants, Congress is the body to amend it,
and not this Court, by a process of judicial legislation wholly
unjustifiable. Large numbers do not agree that the view taken by
defendants is sound or true in substance, and Congress may, and
very probably did, share in that belief in passing the Act. The
public policy of the Government is to be found in its statutes,
and, when they have not directly spoken, then in the decisions of
the courts and the constant practice of the Government officials;
but when the lawmaking power speaks upon a particular subject over
which it has constitutional power to legislate, public policy in
such a case is what the statute enacts. If the law prohibit any
contract
Page 166 U. S. 341
or combination in restraint of trade or commerce, a contract or
combination made in violation of such law is void whatever may have
been theretofore decided by the courts to have been the public
policy of the country on that subject.
The conclusion which we have drawn from the examination above
made into the question before us is that the antitrust act applies
to railroads, and that it renders illegal all agreements which are
in restraint of trade or commerce, as we have above defined that
expression, and the question then arises whether the agreement
before us is of that nature.
Although the case is heard on bill and answer, thus making it
necessary to assume the truth of the allegations in the answer
which are well pleaded, yet the legal effect of the agreement
itself cannot be altered by the answer, nor can its violation of
law be made valid by allegations of good intention or of desire to
simply maintain reasonable rates; nor can the plaintiffs'
allegations as to the intent with which the agreement was entered
into be regarded, as such intent is denied on the part of the
defendants; and, if the intent alleged in the bill were a necessary
fact to be proved in order to maintain the suit, the bill would
have to be dismissed. In the view we have taken of the question,
the intent alleged by the Government is not necessary to be proved.
The question is one of law in regard to the meaning and effect of
the agreement itself, namely, does the agreement restrain trade or
commerce in any way so as to be a violation of the Act? We have no
doubt that it does. The agreement, on its face, recites that it is
entered into
"for the purpose of mutual protection by establishing and
maintaining reasonable rates, rules, and regulations on all freight
traffic, both through and local."
To that end, the association is formed, and a body created which
is to adopt rates which, when agreed to, are to be the governing
rates for all the companies, and a violation of which subjects the
defaulting company to the payment of a penalty; and, although the
parties have a right to withdraw from the agreement on giving 30
days' notice of a desire so to do, yet while in force, and assuming
it to be lived up to, there can be no doubt
Page 166 U. S. 342
that its direct, immediate, and necessary effect is to put a
restraint upon trade or commerce as described in the act.
For these reasons, the suit of the Government can be maintained
without proof of the allegation that the agreement was entered into
for the purpose of restraining trade or commerce, or for
maintaining rates above what was reasonable. The necessary effect
of the agreement is to restrain trade or commerce, no matter what
the intent was on the part of those who signed it.
One or two subsidiary questions remain to be decided.
It is said that to grant the injunction prayed for in this case
is to give the statute a retroactive effect; that the contract at
the time it was entered into, was not prohibited or declared
illegal by the statute, as it had not then been passed, and to now
enjoin the doing of an act which was legal at the time it was done
would be improper. We give to the law no retroactive effect. The
agreement in question is a continuing one. The parties to it adopt
certain machinery, and agree to certain methods for the purpose of
establishing and maintaining in the future reasonable rates for
transportation. Assuming such action to have been legal at the time
the agreement was first entered into, the continuation of the
agreement, after it has been declared to be illegal, becomes a
violation of the Act. The statute prohibits the continuing or
entering into such an agreement for the future, and, if the
agreement be continued, it then becomes a violation of the Act.
There is nothing of an
ex post facto character about the
Act. The civil remedy by injunction and the liability to punishment
under the criminal provisions of the Act are entirely distinct, and
there can be no question of any act being regarded as a violation
of the statute which occurred before it was passed. After its
passage, if the law be violated, the parties violating it may
render themselves liable to be punished criminally, but not
otherwise.
It is also argued that the United States have no standing in
court to maintain this bill; that they have no pecuniary interest
in the result of the litigation, or in the question to be decided
by the court. We think that the fourth section of
Page 166 U. S. 343
the Act invests the Government with full power and authority to
bring such an action as this, and, if the facts be proved, an
injunction should issue. Congress, having the control of interstate
commerce, has also the duty of protecting it, and it is entirely
competent for that body to give the remedy by injunction, as more
efficient than any other civil remedy. The subject is fully and
ably discussed in the case of
In re Debs, 158 U.
S. 564.
See also Cincinnati, New Orleans &c.
Railway v. Interstate Commerce Commission, 162 U.
S. 184;
Texas & Pacific Railway v. Interstate
Commerce Commission, 162 U. S. 197.
For the reasons given, the decrees of the United States Circuit
Court of Appeals and of the Circuit Court for the district of
Kansas must be reversed, and the case remanded to the Circuit Court
for further proceedings in conformity with this opinion.
*
"An act to protect trade and commerce against unlawful
restraints and monopolies."
"
Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives of
the United States of America in Congress assembled:"
"Section 1. Every contract, combination in the from of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among
the several states, or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to
be illegal. Every person who shall make any such contract or engage
in any such combination or conspiracy shall be deemed guilty of a
misdemeanor and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine
not exceeding five thousand dollars, or by imprisonment not
exceeding one year, or by both said punishments, in the discretion
of the court."
"Sec. 2. Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to
monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or
persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the
several states, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of
a misdemeanor and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine
not exceeding five thousand dollars, or by imprisonment not
exceeding one year, or by both said punishments, in the discretion
of the court."
"Sec. 3. Every contract, combination in form of trust or
otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce in any
territory of the United States or of the District of Columbia, or
in restraint of trade or commerce between any such territory and
another, or between any such territory or territories and any state
or states or the District of Columbia, or with foreign nations, or
between the District of Columbia and any state or states or foreign
nations, is hereby declared illegal. Every person who shall make
any such contract or engage in any such combination or conspiracy.
shall be deemed guilty of a misdemeanor, and, on conviction
thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding five thousand
dollars, or by imprisonment not exceeding one year, or by both said
punishments, in the discretion of the court."
"Sec. 4. The several Circuit Courts of the United States are
hereby invested with jurisdiction to prevent and restrain
violations of this act; and it shall be the duty of the several
district attorneys of the United States, in their respective
districts, under the direction of the attorney general, to
institute proceedings in equity to prevent and restrain such
violations. Such proceedings may be by way of petition setting
forth the case and praying that such violation shall be enjoined or
otherwise prohibited. When the parties complained of shall have
been duly notified of such petition the court shall proceed, as
soon as may be, to the hearing and determination of the case; and
pending such petition and before final decree, the court may at any
time make such temporary restraining order or prohibition as shall
be deemed just in the premises."
"Sec. 5. Whenever it shall appear to the court before which any
proceeding under section four of this act may be pending, that the
ends of justice require that other parties should be brought before
the court, the court may cause them to be summoned, whether they
reside in the district in which the court is held or not; and
subpoenas to that end may be served in any district by the marshal
thereof."
"Sec. 6. Any property owned under any contract or by any
combination, or pursuant to any conspiracy (and being the subject
thereof) mentioned in section one of this act, and being in the
course of transportation from one state to another, or to a foreign
country, shall be forfeited to the United States, and may be seized
and condemned by like proceedings as those provided by law for the
forfeiture, seizure and condemnation of property imported into the
United States contrary to law."
"Sec. 7. Any person who shall be injured in his business or
property by any other person or corporation by reason of anything
forbidden or declared to be unlawful by this act, may sue therefor
in any circuit court of the United States in the district in which
the defendant resides or is found, without respect to the amount in
controversy, and shall recover threefold the damages by him
sustained, and the costs of suit, including a reasonable attorney's
fee."
"Sec. 8. That the word 'person,' or 'persons,' wherever used in
this act shall be deemed to include corporations and associations
existing under or authorized by the laws of either the United
States, the laws of any of the territories, the laws of any state,
or the laws of any foreign country."
"Approved July 2, 1890."
MR. JUSTICE WHITE, dissenting.
It is unnecessary to refer to the authorities showing that,
although a contract may in some measure restrain trade, it is not
for that reason void, or even voidable, unless the restraint which
it produces be unreasonable. The opinion of the court concedes this
to be the settled doctrine.
The contract between the railway companies which the court holds
to be void because it is found to violate the act of Congress of
the 2d of July, 1890, 26 Stat. 209, substantially embodies only an
agreement between the corporations by which a uniform
classification of freight is obtained, by which the secret
undercutting of rates is sought to be avoided, and the rates as
stated in the published rate sheets, and which, as a general rule,
are required by law to be filed with the Interstate Commerce
Commission, are secured against arbitrary and sudden changes. I
content myself with giving this mere outline of the results of the
contract, and do not stop to demonstrate that its provisions are
reasonable, since the opinion of
Page 166 U. S. 344
the court rests upon that hypothesis. I commence, then, with
these two conceded propositions, one of law and the other of fact:
first, that only such contracts as unreasonably restrain trade are
violative of the general law, and second, that the particular
contract here under consideration is reasonable, and therefore not
unlawful, if the general principles of law are to be applied to
it.
The theory upon which the contract is held to be illegal is
that, even though it be reasonable, and hence valid, under the
general principles of law, it is yet void, because it conflicts
with the act of Congress already referred to. Now at the outset, it
is necessary to understand the full import of this conclusion. As
it is conceded that the contract does not unreasonably restrain
trade, and that, if it does not so unreasonably restrain, it is
valid under the general law, the decision, substantially, is that
the act of Congress is a departure from the general principles of
law, and, by its terms, destroys the right of individuals or
corporations to enter into very many reasonable contracts. But this
proposition, I submit, is tantamount to an assertion that the act
of Congress is itself unreasonable. The difficulty of meeting, by
reasoning, a premise of this nature is frankly conceded, for, of
course, where the fundamental proposition upon which the whole
contention rests is that the act of Congress is unreasonable, it
would seem conducive to no useful purpose to invoke reason as
applicable to and as controlling the construction of a statute
which is admitted to be beyond the pale of reason. The question
then is, is the act of Congress relied on to be so interpreted as
to give it a reasonable meaning, or is it to be construed as being
unreasonable and as violative of the elementary principles of
justice?
The argument upon which it is held that the act forbids those
reasonable contracts which are universally admitted to be legal is
thus stated in the opinion of the court, and I quote the exact
language in which it is there expressed lest, in seeking to
epitomize, I may not accurately reproduce the thought which it
conveys:
"Contracts in restraint of trade have been known and
Page 166 U. S. 345
spoken of for hundreds of years both in England and in this
country, and the term includes all kinds of those contracts which,
in fact, restrain trade. Some of such contracts have been held void
and unenforceable in the courts by reason of their restraint being
unreasonable, while others have been held valid because they were
not of that nature. A contract may be in restraint of trade and
still be valid at common law. Although valid, it is nevertheless a
contract in restraint of trade, and would be so described either at
common law or elsewhere. By the simple use of the term 'contract in
restraint of trade,' all contracts of that nature, whether valid or
otherwise, would be included, and not alone that kind of contract
which was invalid and unenforceable as being in unreasonable
restraint of trade. When, therefore, the body of an act pronounces
as illegal every contract or combination in restraint of trade or
commerce among the several states, etc., the plain and ordinary
meaning of such language is not limited to that kind of contract
alone which is in unreasonable restraint of trade, but all
contracts are included in such language, and no exception or
limitation can be added without placing in the act that which has
been omitted by Congress."
To state the proposition in the form in which it was earnestly
pressed in the argument at bar, it is as follows: Congress has said
every contract in restraint of trade is illegal. When the law says
"every," there is no power in the courts, if they correctly
interpret and apply the statute, to substitute the word "some" for
the word "every." If Congress had meant to forbid only restraints
of trade which were unreasonable, it would have said so. Instead of
doing this, it has said "every," and this word of universality
embraces both contracts which are reasonable and unreasonable.
Is the proposition which is thus announced by the court, and
which was thus stated at bar, well founded? is the first question
which arises for solution. I quote the title and the first section
of the act which, it is asserted, if correctly interpreted,
destroys the right to make just and reasonable contracts:
Page 166 U. S. 346
"An act to protect trade and commerce against unlawful
restraints and monopolies."
"Every contract, combination, in the form of trust or otherwise,
or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce among the several
states or with foreign nations, is hereby declared to be illegal.
Every person who shall make any such contract or engage in any such
combination or conspiracy, shall be deemed guilty of a misdemeanor,
and on conviction thereof shall be punished by fine not exceeding
$5,000, or by imprisonment not exceeding one year, or by both said
punishments in the discretion of the court."
Is it correct to say that at common law, the words "restraint of
trade" had a generic signification which embraced all contracts
which restrained the freedom of trade, whether reasonable or
unreasonable, and therefore that all such contracts are within the
meaning of the words "every contract in restraint of trade?" I
think a brief consideration of the history and development of the
law on the subject will not only establish the inaccuracy of this
proposition, but also demonstrate that the words "restraint of
trade" embrace only contracts which unreasonably restrain trade,
and, therefore, that reasonable contracts, although they, in some
measure, "restrain trade," are not within the meaning of the words.
It is true that, in the adjudged cases, language may be found
referring to contracts in restraint of trade which are valid
because reasonable. But this mere form of expression, used not as a
definition, does not maintain the contention that such contracts
are embraced within the general terms "every contract in restraint
of trade." The rudiments of the doctrine of contracts in restraint
of trade are found in the common law at a very early date. The
first case on the subject is reported in 6 Year Book 5, 2 Hen. V.,
and is known as
Dier's Case. That was an action of damages
upon a bond conditioned that the defendant should not practice his
trade as a dyer at a particular place during a limited period, and
it was held that the contract was illegal. The principle upon which
this case was decided was not described as one forbidding contracts
in restraint of trade, but was stated to be one by which contracts
restricting the liberty of
Page 166 U. S. 347
the subject were forbidden. The doctrine declared in that case
was applied in subsequent cases in England prior to the case of
Mitchell v. Reynolds, decided in 1711, and reported in 1
P.Wms. 181. There, the distinction between general restraints and
partial restraints was first definitely formulated, and it was held
that a contract creating a partial restraint was valid, and one
creating a general restraint was not. The theory of partial and
general restraints established by that case was followed in many
decided cases in England -- not, however, without the correctness
of the difference between the two being in some instances denied,
and in others questioned, until the matter was set finally at rest
by the House of lords in
Nordenfelt v. The Maxim Nordenfelt
Guns and Ammunition Co., reported in (1894) App.Cas. 535. In
that case, it was held that the distinction between partial and
general restraint was an incorrect criterion, but that whether a
contract was invalid because in restraint of trade must depend upon
whether, on considering all the circumstances, the contract was
found to be reasonable or unreasonable. If reasonable, it was not a
contract in restraint of trade, and, if unreasonable, it was.
The decisions of the American courts substantially conform to
both the development and ultimate results of the English cases.
While the rule of partial and general restraint has been either
expressly or impliedly admitted, the exact scope of the distinction
between the two has been the subject of discussion and varying
adjudication. And although it is accurate to say that, in the
cases, expressions may be found speaking of contracts as being, in
form, in restraint of trade, and yet valid, it results from an
analysis of all the American cases, as it does from the English,
that these expressions in no way imply that contracts which were
valid because they only partially restrained trade were yet
considered as embraced within the definition of "contracts in
restraint of trade." On the contrary, the reason of the cases,
where contracts partially restraining trade were excepted, and
hence held to be valid, was because they were not contracts in
restraint of trade in the legal meaning of those words. Referring
to the modern and American
Page 166 U. S. 348
rule on the subject, Beach, in his recent treatise on the Modern
Law of Contracts at section 1569, says:
"The tendency of modern thought and decisions has been no longer
to uphold in its strictness the doctrine which formerly prevailed
respecting agreements in restraint of trade. The severity with
which such agreements were treated in the beginning has relaxed
more and more by exceptions and qualifications, and a gradual
change has taken place, brought about by the growth of industrial
activities and the enlargement of commercial facilities which tend
to render such agreements less dangerous because monopolies are
less easy of accomplishment."
The fact that the exclusion of reasonable contracts from the
doctrine of restraint of trade was predicated on the conclusion
that such contracts were no longer considered as coming within the
meaning of the words "restraint of trade" is nowhere more clearly
and cogently stated than in the opinion of the court of appeals of
the state of New York in the case of
Matthews v. Associated
Press, 136 N.Y. 333. In considering the contention that a
bylaw of the defendant association which prohibited its members
from receiving or publishing "the regular news dispatches of any
other news association covering a like territory and organized for
a like purpose" was void because it tended to restrain trade and
competition and to create a monopoly, the learned judge said (page
340):
"We do not think the bylaw improperly tends to restrain trade,
assuming that the business of collecting and distributing news
would come within the definition of 'a trade.' The latest decisions
of courts in this country and in England show a strong tendency to
very greatly circumscribe and narrow the doctrine of avoiding
contracts in restraint of trade.
The courts do not go to the
length of saying that contracts which they now would say are in
restraint of trade are nevertheless valid contracts, and to be
enforced. They do, however, now hold many contracts not open to the
objection that they are in restraint of trade which a few years
back would have been avoided on that sole ground both here and in
England. The
Page 166 U. S. 349
cases in this Court which are the latest manifestations of the
turn in the tide are cited in the opinion in this case at general
term, and are
Match Co. v. Roeber, 106 N.Y. 473;
Hodge
v. Sloan, 107 N.Y. 244;
Leslie v. Lorillard, 110 N.Y.
519."
"So that, when we agree that a bylaw which is in restraint of
trade is void, we are still brought back
to the question what
is a 'restraint of trade' in the modern definition of that
term? The authority to make bylaws must also be limited by the
scope and purpose of the association. I think this bylaw is thus
limited, and that
it is not in restraint of trade as the courts
now interpret that phrase."
This lucid statement aptly sums up the process of reasoning by
which partial and reasonable contracts came no longer to be
considered as included in the words "contracts in restraint of
trade," and points to the fallacy embodied in the proposition that
contracts which were held not to be in restraint of trade were yet
covered by the words "in restraint of trade"; that is, that,
although they were not such contracts, yet they continued so to be.
After analyzing the provisions of the bylaw, the opinion proceeds
as follows (page 341):
"Thus, a bylaw of the nature complained of would have a tendency
to strengthen the association, and to render it more capable of
filling the duty it was incorporated to perform. A business
partnership could provide that none of its members should attend to
any business other than that of the partnership, and that each
partner who came in must agree not to do any other business, and
must give up all such business as he had theretofore done. Such an
agreement would not be in restraint of trade, although its direct
effect might be to restrain to some extent the trade which had been
done."
This adds cogency to the demonstration, and shows in the most
conclusive manner that the words "contracts in restraint of trade"
do not continue to define those contracts which are no longer
covered by the legal meaning of the words.
This court has not only recognized and applied the distinction
between partial and general restraints, but has also decided that
the true test whether a contract be in restraint of trade is
Page 166 U. S. 350
not whether, in a measure, it produces such effect, but whether,
under all the circumstances, it is reasonable.
Oregon
Steam Navigation Co. v. Winsor, 20 Wall. 64,
87 U. S. 68;
Gibbs v. Baltimore Gas Co., 130 U.
S. 396,
130 U. S. 409.
As it is unnecessary here to enter into a detailed examination of
the cases, I append in the margin a reference to decisions of some
of the state courts, and to several writers on the subject of
contracts in restraint of trade, by whom the doctrine is reviewed
and the authorities very fully referred to.*
It follows from the foregoing statement that at common law,
contracts which only partially restrain trade, to use the precise
language of Maule, J., in
Rannie v. Irvine, 7 Man. &
G. 969, 978, were "
an exception ingrafted upon that rule"
-- that is, the rule as to contracts in restraint of trade,
"
and that the exception is in furtherance of the rule
itself." I submit also, manifestly, that the further
development of the doctrine by which it was decided that, if a
contract was reasonable, it would not be held to be included within
contracts in restraint of trade, although such contract might in
some measure produce such an effect, was also an exception to the
general rule as to the invalidity of contracts in restraint of
trade. The theory, then, that the words "restraint of trade" define
and embrace all such contracts, without reference to whether they
are reasonable, amounts substantially to saying that, by the common
law and the adjudged American cases, certain classes of contracts
were carved out of and excepted from the general rule, and yet were
held to remain embraced within the general rule from which they
were removed. But the obvious conflict which is shown by this
contradictory result to which the contention leads rests not upon
the mere form of statement, but upon the
Page 166 U. S. 351
reason of things. This will, I submit, be shown by a very brief
analysis of the reasons by which partial restraints were held not
to be embraced in contracts in restraint of trade, and by which
ultimately all reasonable contracts were likewise decided not to be
so embraced; that is to say that the reasoning by which the
exceptions were created conclusively shows the error of contending
that the words "contracts in restraint of trade" continued to
embrace those reasonable contracts which those words no longer
described.
It is perhaps true that the principle by which contracts in
restraint of the freedom of the subject or of trade were held to be
illegal was first understood to embrace all contracts which in any
degree accomplished these results. But, as trade developed, it came
to be understood that, if contracts which only partially restrained
the freedom of the subject or of trade were embraced in the rule
forbidding contracts in restraint of trade, both the freedom of
contract and trade itself would be destroyed. Hence, from the
reason of things, arose the distinction that, where contracts
operated only a partial restraint of the freedom of contract or of
trade, they were not, in contemplation of law, contracts in
restraint of trade. And it was this conception also which, in its
final aspect, led to the knowledge that reason was to be the
criterion by which it was to be determined whether a contract which
in some measure restrained the freedom of contract and of trade was
in reality, when considered in all its aspects, a contract of that
character, or one which was necessary to the freedom of contract
and of trade. To define, then, the words "in restraint of trade" as
embracing every contract which in any degree produced that effect
would be violative of reason, because it would include all those
contracts which are the very essence of trade, and would be
equivalent to saying that there should be no trade, and therefore
nothing to restrain. The dilemma which would necessarily arise from
defining the words "contracts in restraint of trade" so as to
destroy trade by rendering illegal the contracts upon which trade
depends, and yet presupposing that trade would continue, and should
not be restrained, is shown by an argument advanced, and which has
been compelled
Page 166 U. S. 352
by the exigency of the premise upon which it is based. Thus,
after insisting that the word "every" is all-embracing, it is said,
from the necessity of things, it will not be held to apply to
covenants in restraint of trade which are collateral to a sale of
property, because not "supposed" to be within the letter or spirit
of the statute. But how, I submit, can it be held that the words
"every contract in restraint of trade" embrace all such contracts,
and yet at the same time, it be said that certain contracts of that
nature are not included? The asserted exception not only destroys
the rule which is relied on, but it rests upon no foundation of
reason. It must either result from the exclusion of particular
classes of contracts, whether they be reasonable or not, or it must
arise from the fact that the contracts referred to are merely
collateral contracts. But many collateral contracts may contain
provisions which make them unreasonable. The exception which is
relied upon, therefore, as rendering possible the existence of
trade to be restrained is either arbitrary or it is
unreasonable.
But, admitting
arguendo the correctness of the
proposition by which it is sought to include every contract,
however reasonable, within the inhibition of the law, the statute,
considered as a whole, shows, I think, the error of the
construction placed upon it. Its title is, "An act to protect trade
and commerce against unlawful restraints and monopolies." The word
"unlawful" clearly distinguishes between contracts in restraint of
trade which are lawful and those which are not -- in other words,
between those which are unreasonably in restraint of trade, and
consequently invalid, and those which are reasonable, and hence
lawful. When, therefore, in the very title of the act, the well
settled distinction between lawful and unlawful contracts is
broadly marked, how can an interpretation be correct which holds
that all contracts, whether lawful or not, are included in its
provisions? While it is true that the title of an act cannot be
used to destroy the plain import of the language found in its body,
yet, when a literal interpretation will work out wrong or injury,
or where the words of the statute are ambiguous, the title may be
resorted to as an instrument of construction. In
United
States
Page 166 U. S. 353
v. Palmer, 3 Wheat. 610, where general language found
in the body of a criminal statute was given a narrow and restricted
meaning, Mr. Chief Justice Marshall, in the course of the opinion,
said (page
16 U. S.
631):
"The title of an act cannot control its words, but may furnish
some aid in showing what was in the mind of the legislature. The
title of this act is, 'An act for the punishment of certain crimes
against the United States.' It would seem that offenses against the
United States, not offenses against the human race, were the crimes
which the legislature intended by this law to punish."
So also, in
United States v. Union Pacific Railroad,
91 U. S. 72, where
the construction of a statute was involved, it was held that the
interpretation adopted was supported by the title, which disclosed
the general purpose which Congress had in view in adopting the law
under consideration. The same rule was announced in
Smythe v.
Fiske, 23 Wall. 374,
90 U. S. 380, and
Coosaw Mining Co. v. South Carolina, 144 U.
S. 550, and cases there cited.
Pretermitting the consideration of the title, it cannot be
denied that the words "restraint of trade," used in the act in
question, had, long prior to the adoption of that act, been
construed as not embracing reasonable contracts. The well settled
rule is that, where technical words are used in an act, and their
meaning has previously been conclusively settled by long usage and
judicial construction, the use of the words without an indication
of an intention to give them a new significance is an adoption of
the generally accepted meaning affixed to the words at the time the
act was passed. Particularly is this rule imperative where the
statute in which the words are used creates a crime, as does the
statute under consideration, and gives no specific definition of
the crime created. Thus, in
United States v. Palmer,
supra, Mr. Chief Justice Marshall, referring to the term
"robbery," as used in the statute, said (page
16 U. S.
630):
"Of the meaning of the term 'robbery' as used in the statute, we
think no doubt can be entertained. It must be understood in the
sense in which it is recognized and defined at common law. "
Page 166 U. S. 354
If these obvious rules of interpretation be applied, it seems to
me they render it impossible to construe the words "every restraint
of trade," used in the act, in any other sense than as excluding
reasonable contracts, as the fact that such contracts were not
considered to be within the rule of contracts in restraint of trade
was thoroughly established, both in England and in this country at
the time the act was adopted. It is, I submit, not to be doubted
that the interpretation of the words "every contract in restraint
of trade" so as to embrace within its purview every contract,
however reasonable, would certainly work an enormous injustice, and
operate to the undue restraint of the liberties of the citizen. But
there is no canon of interpretation which requires that the letter
be followed when, by so doing, an unreasonable result is
accomplished. On the contrary, the rule is the other way, and
exacts that the spirit which vivifies, and not the letter which
killeth, is the proper guide by which to correctly interpret a
statute. In
Smythe v.
Fiske, 23 Wall. 374,
90 U. S. 380,
this Court declared that:
"A thing may be within the letter of the statute, and not within
its meaning, and within its meaning, though not within its letter.
The intention of the lawmaker is the law."
In
Lau Ow Bew v. United States, 144 U. S.
47, this Court, speaking through Mr. Chief Justice
Fuller, said (page
144 U. S.
59):
"Nothing is better settled than that statutes should receive a
sensible construction, such as will effectuate the legislative
intention, and, if possible, so as to avoid an unjust or an absurd
conclusion.
Church of Holy Trinity v. United States,
143 U. S.
457;
Henderson v. Mayor of New York,
92 U. S.
259;
United States v. Kirby, 7
Wall. 482;
Oates v. National Bank, 100 U. S.
239."
In all the cases there cited, the literal language of the
statutes was disregarded in order to restrict its operation within
reason. To those cases may also be added
United States v.
Mooney, 116 U. S. 104,
where it was contended that, by the Act of March 3, 1875, c. 137,
the Circuit Courts were vested with jurisdiction concurrent with
district courts over certain suits. The plausibility of the
argument, based upon the literal language of the statute, was
conceded by the court, but the
Page 166 U. S. 355
results which would follow from sustaining the construction
contended for were pointed out by the court, and it was observed
(page
116 U. S.
107): "A construction which involves such results was
clearly not contemplated by Congress."
Indeed, it seems to me there can be no doubt that reasonable
contracts cannot be embraced within the provisions of the statute
if it be interpreted by the light of the supreme rule commanding
that the intention of the law must be carried out, and it must be
so construed as to afford the remedy and frustrate the wrong
contemplated by its enactment.
The plain intention of the law was to protect the liberty of
contract and the freedom of trade. Will this intention not be
frustrated by a construction which, if it does not destroy at least
gravely impairs, both the liberty of the individual to contract and
the freedom of trade? If the rule of reason no longer determines
the right of the individual to contract, or secures the validity of
contracts upon which trade depends and results, what becomes of the
liberty of the citizen or of the freedom of trade? Secured no
longer by the law of reason, all these rights become subject, when
questioned, to the mere caprice of judicial authority. Thus, a law
in favor of freedom of contract, it seems to me, is so interpreted
as to gravely impair that freedom. Progress, and not reaction, was
the purpose of the act of Congress. The construction now given the
act disregards the whole current of judicial authority, and tests
the right to contract by the conceptions of that right entertained
at the time of the Year Books, instead of by the light of reason
and the necessity of modern society. To do this violates, as I see
it, the plainest conception of public policy, for, as said by Sir
G. Jessel, Master of the Rolls in
Printing &c. Company v.
Sampson, L.R. 19 Eq. 462:
"If there is one thing which more than another public policy
requires, it is that men of full age and competent understanding
shall have the utmost liberty of contracting, and their contracts,
when entered into freely and voluntarily, shall be held sacred, and
shall be enforced by courts of justice."
The remedy intended to be accomplished by the act of Congress
was to shield against the danger of contract or combination
Page 166 U. S. 356
by the few against the interest of the many, and to the
detriment of freedom. The construction now given, I think, strikes
down the interest of the many to the advantage and benefit of the
few. It has been held, in a case involving a combination among
working men, that such combinations are embraced in the act of
Congress in question, and this view was not doubted by this Court.
In re Debs, 64 Fed. 724, 745-755;
id.,
158 U. S. 158
U.S. 564. The interpretation of the statute, therefore, which holds
that reasonable agreements are within its purview, makes it embrace
every peaceable organization or combination of the laborer to
benefit his condition either by obtaining an increase of wages or
diminution of the hours of labor. Combinations among labor for this
purpose were treated as illegal under the construction of the law
which included reasonable contracts within the doctrine of the
invalidity of contract or combinations in restraint of trade, and
they were only held not to be embraced within that doctrine either
by statutory exemption therefrom, or by the progress which made
reason the controlling factor on the subject. It follows that the
construction which reads the rule of reason out of the statute
embraces within its inhibition every contract or combination by
which workingmen seek to peaceably better their condition. It is,
therefore, as I see it, absolutely true to say that the
construction now adopted, which works out such results, not only
frustrates the plain purpose intended to be accomplished by
Congress, but also makes the statute tend to an end never
contemplated, and against the accomplishment of which its
provisions were enacted.
But conceding, for the sake of argument, that the words "every
contract in restraint of trade," as used in the act of Congress in
question, prohibit all such contracts, however reasonable they may
be, and therefore that all that great body of contracts which are
commonly entered into between individuals or corporations, and
which promote and develop trade, and which have been heretofore
considered as lawful, are no longer such; and conceding also that
agreements entered into by associations of workingmen to peaceably
better their condition, either by obtaining an increase or
preventing a decrease
Page 166 U. S. 357
of wages, or by securing a reduction in the hours of labor, or
for mutually protecting each other from unjust discharge, or for
other reasonable purposes, have become unlawful -- it remains to
consider whether the provisions of the act of 1890 were intended to
apply to agreements made between carriers for the purpose of
classifying the freight to be by them carried, or preventing secret
cutting of the published rates; in other words, whether the terms
of the statute were intended to apply to contracts between carriers
entered into for the purpose of securing fairness in their dealings
with each other, and tending to protect the public against improper
discrimination and sudden changes in rates. To answer this question
involves deciding whether the act here relied upon was intended to
abrogate the provisions of the act of Congress of the 4th of
February, 1887, and the amendments thereto, commonly known as the
"Interstate Commerce Act." The question is not whether railway
companies may not violate the terms of the statute of 1890 if they
do acts which it forbids and punishes, but whether that statute was
intended to abrogate the power of railway companies to make
contracts with each other which are either expressly sanctioned by
the Interstate Commerce Act or the right to make which arises by
reasonable implication from the terms of that Act; that is to say,
not whether the Act of 1890 is not operative upon all persons and
corporations, but whether, being so generally operative, it was
intended to forbid, as in restraint of trade, all contracts on the
subjects embraced within and controlled by the interstate commerce
law. The statute commonly known as the "Interstate Commerce Law"
was a special act, and it was intended to regulate interstate
commerce transported by railway carriers. All its provisions
directly and expressly related to this subject. The Act of 1890, on
the contrary, is a general law, not referring specifically to
carriers of interstate commerce. The rule is that a general law
will not be held to repeal a special statute unless there be a
clear implication, unavoidably resulting from the general law, that
it was the intention should cover the subject matter previously
should cover the subject matter previously expressly and
specifically provided for by particular legislation. The doctrine
on this
Page 166 U. S. 358
subject is thus stated in
Ex parte Crow Dog,
109 U. S.
570:
"'The general principle to be applied,' said Boville, C.J., in
Thorpe v. Adams, L.R. 6 C.P. 135, 'to the construction of
acts of parliament, is that a general act is not to be construed to
repeal a previous particular act, unless there is some express
reference to the previous legislation on the subject, or unless
there is a necessary inconsistency in the two acts standing
together.' 'And the reason is,' said Wood, V.C., in
Fitzgerald
v. Champenys, 30 Law J.Eq. 782, 2 Johns. & H. 31-54, 'that
the legislature, having had its attention directed to a special
subject, and having observed all the circumstances of the case, and
provided for them, does not intend by a general enactment afterward
to derogate from its own act when it makes no special mention of
its intention so to do.'"
These principles thus announced are treated as elementary by the
text writers. Endlich on Interpretation of Statutes § 223;
Sedgwick on Statutory Construction, §§ 157, 158;
Sutherland on Statutory Construction § 157.
Does, therefore, the implication irresistibly arise that
Congress intended in the act of 1890 to abrogate, in whole or in
part, the provisions of the Act of 1887 regulating interstate
commerce? It seems to me that the nature of the two enactments
clearly demonstrates that there was no such intention. The act to
regulate interstate commerce expressed the purpose of Congress to
deal with a complex and particular subject which, from its very
nature, required special legislation. That act was the initiation
of a policy by Congress looking to the development and working out
of a harmonious system to regulate the highly important subject of
interstate transportation.
Conceding,
arguendo, that the debates which took place
at the time of the passage of the Act of 1890 may not be resorted
to as a means of interpreting its text, yet a review of the
proceedings connected with the passage of the Act of July 2, 1890,
through the two Houses of Congress, it seems to me, leaves no room
for question that the Act was not designed to cover the particular
subjects which had been theretofore specially regulated by
provisions of the interstate commerce law.
Page 166 U. S. 359
Prior to the passage of the Act of 1890, various reports had
been made to Congress concerning the operations of the Interstate
Commerce Act in which the Commission pointed out the desirability
and necessity of contracts between railroad companies in the matter
of classification, stable rates, etc. After the Act of 1890 had
been adopted in the Senate, it was amended in the House of
representatives so as to specifically include among the contracts
declared lawful "contracts for the transportation of persons or
property from one state or territory into another." Cong.Rec. vol.
21, part 5, pp. 4099, 4144. On the return of the bill to the
Senate, the amendment was agreed to with the added provision that
the contracts for transportation to be prohibited "should only be
such as raise the rates of transportation above what is just and
reasonable."
Ib., p. 4753. The House refused to concur in
the Senate amendment. A conference committee was appointed by both
bodies which recommended that the House of representatives recede
from its disagreement to the amendments of the Senate and agree to
the same modified by the addition of the provision that
"nothing in this act shall be deemed or held to impair the
powers of the several states in respect to any of the matters in
this act mentioned."
In a statement accompanying the report, Mr. Stewart, for the
conferees on the part of the House, said:
"A majority of the committee of conference on the part of the
House on the disagreeing votes of the two Houses on Senate bill
submit the following statement:"
"In the original bill two things were declared illegal, namely,
contracts in restraint of interstate trade or commerce and the
monopolization of such trade."
"Its only object was the control of trusts, so-called, so far as
such combinations in their relation to interstate trade are within
reach of federal legislation."
"The House amendment extends the scope of the act to all
agreements entered into for the purpose of preventing competition,
either in the purchase or sale of commodities or in the
transportation of persons or property within the jurisdiction of
Congress. "
Page 166 U. S. 360
"It declares illegal any agreement for relief from the effects
of competition in the two industries of transportation or
merchandising, however excessive or destructive such competition
may be."
"The amendment reported by the conference is the Senate
amendment with the added proviso that the power of the states over
the subjects embraced in the act shall not be impaired
thereby."
"It strikes from the House amendment the clause relating to
contracts for the purchase of merchandise, and modifies the
transportation clause by making unlawful agreements which raise
rates above what is just and reasonable."
Cong.Rec. vol. 21, part 6, p. 5950.
The House rejected the report of the conference committee, and
adhered to its amendments. A new conference committee was
appointed, and the recommendation of that committee that both
Houses recede was concurred in, and the bill as it originally
passed the Senate was adopted. Cong.Rec. vol. 21, part 9, p.
6212.
It thus appears that the bill was originally introduced in the
form in which it now appears; that this form was thought not to be
sufficient to embrace railroad transportation, that a determined
effort was made by the proposed amendment to include such
contracts, and that the effort was unsuccessful. The reports to
Congress by the commission and by the conference committee being
facts proper to be noticed in seeking to ascertain the intention of
Congress (
Church of Holy Trinity v. United States,
143 U. S. 457), it
would seem to be manifest therefrom that there was no intention by
the Act to interfere with the control and regulation of railroads
under the Interstate Commerce Act, or with acts of the companies
which had theretofore been recognized as in conformity to, and not
in conflict with, that Act.
That there was and could have been no intention to repeal by the
Act of 1890 the earlier "act to regulate interstate commerce" is
additionally evidenced by the fact that no reference is made in the
later act to the prior one, and that no language is contained in
the Act of 1890 which could in any way be construed
Page 166 U. S. 361
as abrogating any of the rights conferred or powers called into
existence by the Interstate Commerce Act. Nowhere, contemporaneous
with the act of 1890, is there anything indicating that anyone
supposed that the provisions of that Act were intended to repeal
the Interstate Commerce Act. The understanding of Congress in this
respect is shown by the circumstance that the Interstate Commerce
Act has been amended in material particulars, and treated as
existing, since the adoption of the Act of 1890, and this
conception of the legislative department of the Government has also
been that entertained by the executive and judicial departments,
evidenced by the appointment of new members of the Commission and
by decisions of the courts enforcing various provisions of that
Act, and treating it as still subsisting in its entirety. The two
laws then coexisting, is the agreement of the carriers to secure a
uniform classification of freight, and to prevent secret changes of
the published rates -- in other words, to secure just and fair
dealings between each other -- sanctioned by the act to regulate
interstate commerce, and therefore not within the inhibition of the
Act of 1890?
The Interstate Commerce Act provided for the appointment of a
commission to whom was to be confided the supervision of the
execution of the law. Without going into detailed mention of the
provisions of the statute, I adopt and quote the summary statement
of the leading features of the original act contained in the first
annual report made to Congress by the Commission, as required by
the Act. It is as follows:
"All charges made for services by carriers subject to the act
must be reasonable and just. Every unjust and unreasonable charge
is prohibited, and declared to be unlawful."
"The direct or indirect charging, demanding, collecting, or
receiving for any service rendered a greater or less compensation
from any one or more persons than from any other for a like and
contemporaneous service, is declared to be unjust discrimination,
and is prohibited."
"The giving of any undue or unreasonable preferences, as between
persons or localities, or kinds of traffic, or the subjecting
Page 166 U. S. 362
any one of them to undue or unreasonable prejudice or
disadvantage, is declared to be unlawful."
"Reasonable, proper, and equal facilities for the interchange of
traffic between lines, and for the receiving, forwarding, and
delivering of passengers and property between connecting lines is
required, and discrimination in rates and charges as between
connecting lines is forbidden."
"It is made unlawful to charge or receive any greater
compensation in the aggregate for the transportation of passengers
or the like kind of property under substantially similar
circumstances and conditions for a shorter than for a longer
distance over the same line in the same direction, the shorter
being included within the longer distance."
"Contracts, agreements, or combinations for the pooling of
freights of different and competing railroads, or for dividing
between them the aggregate or net earnings of such railroads or any
portion thereof, are declared to be unlawful."
"All carriers subject to the law are required to print their
tariffs for the transportation of persons and property, and to keep
them for public inspection at every depot or station on their
roads. An advance in rates is not to be made until after ten days'
public notice, but a reduction in rates may be made to take effect
at once, the notice of the same being immediately and publicly
given. The rates publicly notified are to be the maximum, as well
as the minimum, charges which can be collected or received for the
services respectively for which they purport to be
established."
"Copies of all tariffs are required to be filed with the
Commission, which is also to be promptly notified of all changes
that shall be made in the same. The joint tariffs of connecting
roads are also required to be filed, and also copies of all
contracts, agreements, or arrangements between carriers in relation
to traffic affected by the Act."
"It is made unlawful for any carrier to enter into any
combination, contract, or agreement, expressed or implied, to
prevent, by change of time schedules, carriage in different cars,
or by other means or devices, the carriage of freights from being
continuous from the place of shipment to the place of destination.
"
Page 166 U. S. 363
These provisions substantially exist in the Act as now in force,
except that, by an amendment made March 2, 1889, it was provided
that rates should not be reduced by carriers except upon three
days' public notice of an intention so to do.
This summary of the Act, which omits reference to a number of
its provisions relating to the power of the Commission and the mode
in which these powers are to be exercised, will suffice for an
examination of the matter in hand.
Now, a consideration of the terms of the statute, I submit,
makes it clear that the contract here sought to be avoided as
illegal is either directly sanctioned or impliedly authorized
thereby. That the Act did not contemplate that the relations of the
carrier should be confined to his own line and to business going
over such line alone is conclusively shown by the fact that the Act
specifically provides for joint and continuous lines -- in other
words, for agreements between several roads to compose a joint
line. That these agreements are to arise from contract is also
shown by the fact that the law provides for the filing of such
contracts with the Commission. And it was also contemplated that
the agreements should cover joint rates, since it provides for the
making of such joint tariffs and for their publication and filing
with the Commission. The making of a tariff of this character
includes necessarily agreements for the classification of freight,
as the freight classification is the essential element in the
making up of a rate. That the interstate commerce rates, all of
which are controlled by the provisions as to reasonableness, were
not intended to fluctuate hourly and daily as competition might ebb
and flow results from the fact that the published rates could not
either be increased or reduced except after a specified time. It
follows, then, that agreements as to reasonable rates and against
their secret reduction conform exactly to the terms of the Act.
Indeed, the authority to make agreements on this subject not only
results from the terms of the Act just referred to, but from its
mandatory provisions forbidding discrimination against or
preference to persons and places. The argument that these
provisions referred to joint lines alone, and not to competitive
lines, is without force, since joint rates necessarily relate to
and
Page 166 U. S. 364
are influenced by the rates on competitive lines. To illustrate,
suppose three joint lines of railroads between Chicago and New
York, each made up of many roads. How could a joint rate be agreed
on by the roads composing one of these continuous lines without an
ascertainment of the rate existing on the other continuous line?
What contract could be made with safety for transportation over one
of the lines without taking into account the rate of all the
others? There certainly could be no prevention of unjust
discrimination as to the persons and places within a given
territory unless the rates of all competing lines within the
territory be considered, and the sudden change of the published
rates of all such lines be guarded against.
I do not further elaborate the reasons demonstrating that
classification is essential to ratemaking, and that a joint rate,
to be feasible, must consider the competitive rates in the same
territory, since these propositions are, to me, self-evident, and
their correctness is substantiated by statements found in the
reports of the Interstate Commerce Commission to Congress, of which
reports judicial notice may be taken.
Heath v. Wallace,
138 U. S. 573,
138 U. S.
584.
I excerpt from some of these reports of the Commission to
Congress statements bearing on these subjects, as well as other
statements indicating that agreements among carriers, competitive
as well as connecting, for the purpose of securing a uniform
classification and preventing the undercutting of rates,
underbilling, etc., existed prior to the Interstate Commerce Act,
were continued thereafter, and were deemed not to be forbidden by
law, but, on the contrary, were considered as instruments tending
to secure its successful evolution. While it is doubtless true
that, in a recent report, the Commission, as now constituted, has
said that agreements between competitors to prevent the
undercutting of rates may operate to cause carriers to disregard
the lawful orders of the Commission, this fact does not change the
legal inference to be deduced from the construction placed upon the
law by those charged with its administration in the period
immediately following its adoption and which was then reported to
Congress.
Page 166 U. S. 365
On the subject of relative rates, the Commission at page 39 of
their first annual report, said:
"Questions of rates on one line at one point cannot be
considered by themselves exclusively; a change in them must affect
rates in a considerable part of the country. . . . Just rates are
always relative. The Act itself provides for its being so when it
forbids unjust discrimination as between localities."
That is to say, if one continuous line made joint rates and
fixed and published them, and the other then made a different rate,
not only would the first joint rate be injurious to the interests
of the railroads making it, during the period in which it could not
be changed, but it would also be against the interests of the
public, and of those who had contracted to ship, since it would
create among shippers and the receivers that inequality which it
was the express purpose of the Act to prevent.
In the same report of the Commission at page 33, not only the
expediency, but the necessity, of contractual relations between
railroad companies is pointed out in the following language:
"To make railroads of the greatest possible service to the
country, contract relations would be essential, because there would
need to be joint tariffs, joint running arrangements, an
interchange of cars, and a giving of credit to a large extent, some
of which were obviously beyond the reach of compulsory legislation,
and, even if they were not, could be best settled and all the
incidents and qualifications fixed by the voluntary action of the
parties in control of the roads respectively."
Also at page 35, after referring to the fact that the former
railroad associations had been continued in existence since the
enactment of the interstate commerce law, though pooling had been
prohibited, among other objects, for the
"making of regulations for uninterrupted and harmonious railroad
communication and exchange of traffic within the territories
embraced by their workings,"
the Commission observed that "some regulations in addition to
those made by the law are almost, if not altogether,
indispensable."
On the same page, the fact is emphasized that classification had
not been taken, by the Act, out of the hands of the carriers,
Page 166 U. S. 366
and it was observed that classification was best made by the
joint action of the railroads themselves. In its second annual
report, the Commission, in commenting upon the evils arising from
the want of friendly business relations between railroads and the
injury that a short road might cause by simply abstaining from
extending accommodation that could not be lawfully forced from it,
said (page 28):
"The public has an interest in being protected against the
probable exercise of any such power. But its interest goes further
than this; it goes to the establishment of such relations among the
managers of roads as will lead to the extension of their traffic
arrangements with mutual responsibility, just as far as may be
possible, so that the public may have in the service performed all
the benefits and conveniences that might be expected to follow from
general federation. There is nothing in the existence of such
arrangements which is at all inconsistent with earnest competition.
They are of general convenience to the carriers, as well as to the
public, and their voluntary extension may be looked for until in
the strife between the roads the limits of competition are passed
and warfare is entered upon. But in order to form them, great
mutual concessions are often indispensable, and such concessions
are likely to be made when relations are friendly, but are not to
be looked for when hostile relations have been inaugurated."
At page 29 of the report, the existence of traffic arrangements
between railroads is called to the attention of Congress in the
following language:
"While the Commission is not at this time prepared to recommend
general legislation towards the establishment or promotion of
relations between the carriers that shall better subserve the
public interest than those which are now common, it must
nevertheless look forward to the possibility of something of that
nature becoming at some time imperative, unless a great improvement
in the existing condition of things is voluntarily
inaugurated."
So, also, the existence of traffic associations, between
competitive roads, for purposes recognized by the act as
lawful,
Page 166 U. S. 367
and their favorable tendency, seems to be conceded in the fourth
annual report of the Commissioners, where at page 29, it is
said:
"If the regulations which are established by the railroad
associations were uniformly, or even generally, observed by their
members, respectively, there would be little difficulty in
enforcing a rule of reasonable rates, for the competition between
the roads which even then would exist would be such as would
prevent the establishment of rates which are altogether
unreasonable, and the public would not be likely to complain if
they were satisfied that the rate sheets were observed."
The character of associations such as that under consideration
is alluded to at page 26 of the same report, where, in discussing
the subject of how best to secure a unity of railroad interests, it
was observed:
"Without legislation to favor it, little can be done beyond the
formation of consulting and advisory associations, and the work of
these is not only necessarily defective, but it is also limited to
a circumscribed territory."
The significance of the statement that, to obtain uniformity of
classification, a result most desirable for the best interests of
the public, agreements between the railroads themselves was
essential is apparent from the fact, frequently declared by the
Commission in its reports, that uniformity of classification is one
of the prerequisites of uniformity of rates. 1 Ann.Rep. 30, 35; 2
Ann.Rep. 40; 3 Ann.Rep. 51, 52; 4 Ann.Rep. 32. The very great
importance of uniform and stable rates has also frequently been
reiterated in the reports of the Commission. Thus at page 6 of the
first annual report, in reviewing the causes which led to the
adoption of the Interstate Commerce Act, it is said:
"Permanence of rates was also seen to be of very high importance
to every man engaged in business enterprises, since, without it,
business contracts were lottery ventures. It was also perceived
that the absolute sum of the money charges exacted for
transportation, if not clearly beyond the bounds of reason, was of
inferior importance in comparison with the obtaining of rates that
should be open, equal, relatively just
Page 166 U. S. 368
as between places, and as steady as, in the nature of things,
was practicable."
That unstable rates between competing carriers lead to injurious
discrimination, one of the evils sought to be remedied by the Act,
was mentioned in the same report at pages 36 and 37, in connection
with a discussion of the subject of reasonable charges, in the
following language:
"Among the reasons most frequently operating to cause complaints
of rates may be mentioned: the want of steadiness in rates, . . .
more often, perhaps, growing out of disagreements between competing
companies, which, when they become serious, may result in wars of
rates between them. Wars of rates, when mutual injury is the chief
purpose in view, as is sometimes the case, are not only mischievous
in their effects upon the parties to them, and upon the business
community whose calculations and plans must for a time be
disturbed, but they have a permanently injurious influence upon the
railroad service because of their effect upon the public mind."
The evil effects of shifting rates were also treated of at page
22 of the second annual report, where the Commission inserted a
letter received from a businessman of Kansas City not connected
with railroads, who said:
"The frequent and violent changes in railway rates which have
taken place during the past few years, and which seem likely to be
unabated, seems to me to call for new legislation in the way of
amendment of the interstate commerce bill. These changes are
ruinous to all businessmen, as well as the railways, and are the
cause of great discontent among shippers everywhere, and especially
to the farmers. What is needed is a fixed, permanent rate, which
shall be reasonable and which can be counted upon by any one
engaging in business."
So, also, in the fourth annual report, it was observed that
shifting, unstable rates, by competing roads, were contrary to the
purpose of the Interstate Commerce Act, and hampered the operations
of the Commission. It was said at page 21:
Page 166 U. S. 369
"In former reports, the Commission has referred to the undoubted
fact that competition for business between railroad companies is
often pushed to ruinous extremes, and the most serious difficulty
in the way of securing obedience to the law may be traced to this
fact. When competition degenerates to rate wars, they are as
unsettling to the business of the country as they are mischievous
to the carriers, and the spirit of existing law is against
them."
In addition to the text of the law heretofore commented on, the
section which forbids pooling adds cogency to the construction that
the law could not have been intended to forbid contracts between
carriers for the purpose of preventing the doing of those things
which the law forbade. For, as I have shown, it cannot be denied
that at the time of the passage of the Act, there existed
associations and contracts between carriers for other purposes than
the pooling of their earnings. While the exact scope of these
contracts is not shown, the fact that their existence was
considered by Congress results from the face of the Act, since it
requires that agreements and contracts between carriers shall be
filed with the Commission. Moreover, the earlier reports of the
Commission, as I have shown, refer to such traffic agreements, and
state that, after the passage of the Act, they continued to exist
as they had existed before, eliminating only the pooling
feature.
In view of these facts, when the Act expressly forbids contracts
and combinations between railroads for pooling, and makes no
mention of other contracts, it is clear that the continued
existence of such contracts was contemplated, and they are not
intended to be forbidden by the Act. The elementary rule of
expressio unius entirely justifies this implication.
And it is, I submit, no answer to this reasoning to say that the
record does not show the terms of these contracts, since judicial
notice may be taken of the reports made by the Commission to
Congress, from which reports the nature of the contracts is
sufficiently pointed out to authorize the conclusion to illustrate
that they were of the general character of the one here
assailed.
While the excerpts from the reports of the Commission which have
been heretofore made serve to elucidate the text
Page 166 U. S. 370
of the Act, they also, I submit, constitute a contemporaneous
construction of the provisions of the Act made by the officers
charged with its administration which is entitled to very great
weight.
Brown v. United States, 113
U. S. 571, and cases there cited.
The rule sustained by these authorities receives additional
sanction here from the fact that the construction at the time made
by the Commission was reported to Congress, and the Act was
subsequently amended by that body without any repudiation of such
construction.
It is, I submit, therefore not to be denied that the agreement
between the carriers, the validity of which is here drawn in
question, seeking to secure uniform classification and to prevent
the undercutting of the published rates, even though such
agreements be made with competing as well as joint lines, is in
accord with the plain text of the Interstate Commerce Act, and is
in harmony with the views of the purposes of that law
contemporaneously expressed to Congress by the body immediately
charged with its administration and tacitly approved by
Congress.
But, departing from a consideration of the mere text and looking
at the Interstate Commerce Act from a broader aspect, in order to
discover the intention of the lawmaker and to discern the evils
which it was intended to suppress and the remedies which it was
proposed to afford by its enactment, it seems to me very clear that
the contract in question is in accord with the Act, and should not
be avoided.
It cannot be questioned that the Interstate Commerce Act was
intended by Congress to inaugurate a new policy for the purpose of
reasonably controlling interstate commerce rates and the dealings
of carriers with reference to such rates. Two systems were
necessarily presented -- the one a prohibition against the exaction
of all unreasonable rates and, subject to this restriction,
allowing the hourly and daily play of untrammeled competition,
resulting in inequality and discrimination; the other imposing a
like duty as to reasonable rates, and, while allowing competition
subject to this limitation, preventing the injurious consequences
arising from a
Page 166 U. S. 371
constant and daily change of rates between connecting or
competing lines, thus avoiding discrimination and preference as to
persons and places.
The second of these systems is, I submit, plainly the one
embodied in the Interstate Commerce Act. At the outset, reasonable
rates are exacted and the power to strike down rates which are
unreasonable is provided. In the subsequent provisions,
discrimination against persons and against places to arise from
daily fluctuation in rates is guarded against by requiring
publication of rates and forbidding changes of the published rates,
whether by way of increase or reduction, during a limited time. To
hold, then, the contract under consideration to be invalid when it
simply provides for uniform classification, and seeks to prevent
secret or sudden changes in the published rates, would be to avoid
a contract covered by the law and embodied in its policy. It
cannot, I think, be correctly said that, while the avowed purpose
of the contract in question embraced only the foregoing objects,
its ulterior intent was to bring about results in conflict with the
interstate commerce law. The answers to the bill of complaint
specially denied the allegations as to the improper motives of the
parties to the contract, and also expressly averred their lawful
and innocent intention. As the case was heard upon bill and answer,
improper motives cannot therefore be imputed. Indeed, the opinion
of the court sustains this view, since it eliminates all
consideration of improper motives, and holds that the validity of
the contract must depend upon its face, and deduces, as a legal
conclusion from this premise, that the contract is invalid, because
even reasonable contracts are embraced within the purview of the
act of 1890. To my mind, the judicial declaration that carriers
cannot agree among themselves for the purpose of aiding in the
enforcement of the provisions of the interstate commerce law will
strike a blow at the beneficial results of that Act, and will have
a direct tendency to produce the preferences and discriminations
which it was one of the main objects of the Act to frustrate. The
great complexity of the subject, the numerous interests concerned
in it, the vast area over which it
Page 166 U. S. 372
operates, present difficulties enough without, it seems to me,
it being advisable to add to them by holding that a contract which
is supported by the text of the law is invalid because, although it
is reasonable and just, it must be considered as in restraint of
trade.
Nor do I think that the danger of these evil consequences is
avoided by the statement that, if the contract be annulled, these
dangers will not arise, because experience shows that contracts
such as that here in question, when entered into by railroads, are
never observed, and therefore it is just as though the contract did
not exist. How, may I ask, can judicial notice be taken of this
fact when it is said that judicial notice cannot be taken of the
fact that there are such contracts? How, moreover, may I ask, can
it be said on one branch of the case that the contract, although
reasonable, must be avoided, because it is a contract in restraint
of trade, and then, on the other branch, declare that contracts of
that character never do restrain trade, because they are never
carried out between the parties who enter into them?
There is another contention which, I submit, is also unsound.
That is the suggestion that it is impossible to say that there can
be such a thing as a reasonable contract between railroads seeking
to avoid sudden or secret changes in reasonable rates, because the
question of railroad rates is so complex, and is involved in so
much difficulty, that to say that a rate is reasonable is
equivalent to saying that it must be fixed by the railroads
themselves, as no mind outside of the officials of the particular
roads can determine whether a rate is reasonable or not. But this
proposition absolutely conflicts with the methods of dealing with
railroad rates adopted in England and expressly put in force by
Congress in the Interstate Commerce Act and by many of the states
of the Union. For years, the rule in England was reasonable rates
enforced by judicial power, and subsequently by enactment securing
such reasonable rates by administrative authority. The Interstate
Commerce Act especially provides for reasonable rates, and vests
primarily in the Commission, and then in the courts, the power to
enforce the provision, and like machinery is provided
Page 166 U. S. 373
in many of the states. Will it be said that Congress and other
legislative bodies have provided for reasonable rates, and created
the machinery to enforce them, when whether rates are reasonable or
not is impossible of ascertainment? If this proposition be correct,
what, may I ask, becomes of the judgment of this Court in
Cincinnati, New Orleans &c. Railway Co. v. Interstate
Commerce Commission, 162 U. S. 184,
where it is held that the order of the Commission finding certain
rates charged by a railroad to be unreasonable was correct?
In conclusion, I notice briefly the proposition that, though it
be admitted that contracts, when made by individuals or private
corporations, when reasonable, will not be considered as in
restraint of trade, yet such is not the case as to public
corporations, because any contract made by them in any measure in
restraint of trade, even when reasonable, is presumptively
injurious to the public interests, and therefore invalid. The
fallacy in this proposition consists in overlooking the distinction
between acts of a public corporation which are
ultra vires
and those which are not. I f the contract of such a corporation
which is assailed be
ultra vires, of course the question
of reasonableness becomes irrelevant, since the charter is the
reason of the being of the corporation. The doctrine is predicated
on the following expressions taken from the opinion of the court
expressed by Mr. Chief Justice Fuller in
Gibbs v. Baltimore Gas
Co., 130 U. S. 396,
130 U. S.
408:
"That, in the instance of business of such a character that it
presumably cannot be restrained to any extent whatever without
prejudice to the public interests, courts decline to enforce or
sustain contracts imposing such restraint, however partial, because
in contravention of public policy. This subject is much considered,
and the authorities cited, in
West Virginia Transportation Co.
v. Ohio River Pipe Line Co., 22 West Va. 600;
Chicago
&c. Gas Co. v. People's Gas Co., 121 Illinois 530;
Western Union Telegraph Co. v. American Union Telegraph
Co., 65 Georgia 160."
But, manifestly, this language must be construed with reference
to the facts of the case in which it was used. What the facts were
in that case is shown by the statement in the
Page 166 U. S. 374
opinion (page
130 U. S. 406)
that the contract there considered "was an agreement for the
abandonment by one of the companies of the discharge of its duties
to the public." It is also to be remembered that it was this
character of contract -- that is, one which was
ultra
vires -- which was held to be illegal in the West Virginia,
Illinois, and Georgia cases which were cited in the
Gibbs
case in support of the excerpt just quoted. That the language in
the
Gibbs case referred to conditions of fact like that
there passed upon -- that is, contracts
ultra vires -- is
shown by the subsequent case of
Chicago &c. Railway Co. v.
Pullman South Car Co., 139 U. S. 79, where
a contract of the railway company was assailed as in restraint of
trade, and the court held that, although, by the contract, the
company had restrained itself for a long period of years from using
other than certain drawing room and sleeping cars, the contract was
yet a valid and proper contract. Manifestly, this decision is
utterly irreconcilable with the view that, in the case of a
railroad company, every restraint imposed by contract upon its
freedom of action is necessarily injurious to the public interests,
and hence invalid. Indeed, the proposition that any restraint of
its conduct which a railroad may create by contract is invalid,
because such road is a public corporation, is demonstrated to be
erroneous by the Interstate Commerce Act, which, in the provisions
heretofore referred to, not only expressly authorizes, but in some
instances commands, agreements from which restraint of the action
of the corporation necessarily arises.
I am authorized to say that MR. JUSTICE FIELD, MR. JUSTICE GRAY,
and MR. JUSTICE SHIRAS concur in this dissent.
*
Match Co. v. Roeber, 106 N.Y. 473;
Leslie v.
Lorillard, 110 N.Y. 519, 533;
Beal v. Chase, 31
Michigan 490, 518;
National Benefit Co. v. Union Hospital
Co., 45 Minnesota 272;
Ellerman v. Chicago Junction
Railways &c. Co., 49 N.J.Eq. 215, 217;
Richards v Am.
Desk &c. Co., 87 Wisconsin 503, 514; note to 2 Parsons on
Contracts, p. 748; note to
Angier v. Webber 92 Am.Dec.
751; note to
Mitchel v. Reynolds, 1 Smith's Leading Cases
705, and supplemental note (9th Am.Ed.) 716 (1888); review of cases
by A. M. Eaton in 4 Harv.Law Review, p. 129 (1890); Patterson on
Restraint of Trade (1891).